HomeMy WebLinkAbout26-City Attorney
CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO - REQUEST FOR COUNCIL ACTION
From: JAMES F. PENMAN
City Attorney
Dept: CITY ATTORNEY
/l"t f""" , ~ 'HI
UUif;;.i<".d jl"tiJI..
Subject: Resolution Adopting Findings in
Support of the Council's Decision to Overturn
the Bureau of Franchises' Denial of the
Petition for a Franchise Permit for AAA
Inland Empire Cab Company
Date: August 30, 2002
Synopsis of Previous Council Action:
July 15,2002 -
Appeal Hearing - Bureau of Franchises - Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA
Inland Empire Cab Co., continued to August 5, 2002.
August 5, 2002 -
Appeal Hearing held, overturned Bureau of Franchises' denial of Petition, referred
matter back to Bureau, and directed City Attorney to prepare Findings (see Staff
Report for details).
August 19, 2002 -
Mayor and Common Council continued this matter at the request of both parties.
Recommended motion:
Adopt Resolution.
\
\
~?~
(/ Signature
Contact person: James F. Penman
Phone:
5255
Supporting data attached: Staff Report. Resolution
Ward: City-wide
FUNDING REQUIREMENTS:
Amount:
Source:
Finance:
Council Notes: OP.. . . J(,/"-I,,.,iJ;. ,.,a.
i ulnO.,; 7 ,_ JLlv "'" 'f
, f
S/slo::J u.).,' <is/IC;JoJ#;JS
}) ,
qjq)D;)"
Agenda Item No. ' J (p
'~~o~~rr', ~ - ;)<;8
STAFF REPORT
Council Meeting Date: September 9. 2002
TO: Mayor and Common Council
FROM: James F. Penman, City Attorney
DATE: August 30, 2002
AGENDA ITEM: RESOLUTION OF THE MAYOR AND COMMON COUNCIL OF THE
CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO ADOPTING FINDINGS IN SUPPORT OF
THE COUNCIL'S DECISION TO OVERTURN THE BUREAU OF
FRANCmSES' DENIAL OF THE PETITION FORA FRANCmSE PERMIT
FOR AAA INLAND EMPIRE CAB COMPANY.
On June 11,2002, the Bureau of Franchises denied a Petition for a Franchise Permit for AAA
Inland Empire Cab Company. On August 5, 2002, the Mayor and Common Council held a public
hearing on the appeal filed by AAA Inland Empire Cab Company. After receiving and considering
the documentary evidence, testimony and arguments presented by the interested parties and the
witnesses, the Council approved the following motions:
I. That the hearing be closed.
2. That the Mayor and Common Council overturn the Bureau of Franchises' denial of a Petition
for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate 25 taxicabs in the City.
3. That the matter be referred back to the Bureau of Franchises to determine whether the current
holder of the permit shall be allowed to increase the number of vehicles in the same
proportion that the total increase bears to the number of such vehicles theretofore operated
by the holder or to grant the permit to the applicant.
4. That the City Attorney be directed to prepare the necessary findings, and that the matter be
continued to August 19, 2002.
5. That the ordinance be referred back to Legislative Review Committee for review.
Pursuant to the Council's direction, attached is the proposed Resolution adopting Findings
in support ofthe Council's decision to overturn the Bureau of Franchises' denial of AAA Inland
Empire Cab Company's Petition for a Franchise Permit.
Recommended Motion: Adopt Resolution.
HE/js[AAA.RPT]
CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO - REQUEST FOR COUNCIL ACTION
From: Rachel Clark, City Clerk
C;"
; f
Subject:
Appeal of the Bureau of Franchises'
denial of a Petition for Franchise Permit
. ..
for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate
25 taxicabs in the City of San
Bernardino
MICC Meeting Date: 7/15/02
Dept: City Clerk
- . .
Date: July 8, 2002
Synopsis of Previous Council Action:
None
Recommended Motion:
Motion #1: That the hearing be closed, and the Mayor and Common Council uphold
the Bureau of Franchises' denial of a Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland
Empire Cab to operate 25 taxicabs in the City of San Bernardino.
Or
Motion #2: That the hearing be closed, and the Mayor and Common Council grant the
appeal for a Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate 25
taxicabs in the City of San Bernardino.
R~)f. CltuLfb
Signature ~~
Contact person:
Phnne:
Supporting data attached: Yes
Ward: All
FUNDING REQUIREMENTS: Amount: NIA
Source: (Acct. No.)
(A,...,...t n,:lr.c::t"'riptinn)
Finance:
Council Notes:
7/J51/)~
,
Agenda Item No. ~
~
CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO - REQUEST FOR COUNCIL ACTION
Staff Report
Subject:
Appeal of the Bureau of Franchises denial of a Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA
Inland Empire Cab to operate 25 taxicabs in the City of San Bernardino.
Applicant: J.K.S.O., Inc.
DBA, AAA Inland Empire Cab
3000 Date Street
Riverside, CA 92507
(909) 369-5581
Patrick Pashkam, Chief Executive Officer
Background:
A Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab was previously denied by the
Bureau of Franchises and a letter sent dated January 10, 2002 to the owners of AAA Inland
Empire Cab notifying them of that fact. AAA Inland Empire Cab did not fIle an appeal of
the decision but elected to re-submit their application based upon new information. On
April 3, 2002, a new application fee was paid by AAA Inland Empire Cab.
On June 11,2002, the Bureau of Franchises considered the new application submitted by
AAA Inland Empire Cab. After presentations by both AAA Inland Empire Cab,
BelllYellow Cab (existing taxi cab service), and discussion from the Board Members
regarding whether there exists a public convenience and necessity for additional cab
service, a motion to deny the Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab
carried on a 4-2 vote. Board Members Cole, Turner, Shultz and Carson voted in favor of
the motion to deny: Members Fernandez and Martindale voted against the motion.
Financial Impact:
None
Recommendation:
That the Mayor and Common Council uphold the Bureau of Franchises' denial of the
Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate 25 taxi cabs in the
City of San Bernardino.
Or
That the hearing be closed, and the mayor and Common Council grant the appeal for a
Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate 25 taxicabs in the
City of San Bernardino.
JUL-Uc:.-c:.UUc:. IU!:. V't'l;' r(l rULLc,I\lvn L.L:.l1mm 1:.1 nL.
..
1111\ l'V. VVV UVU v~ ~v
I' V.
LAW OF"rICE.~
FULLERTON, Lf:MANN, SCHAEFER & IiWV~[b.,en~EhK
ANNf'rTe: ge.e~\.\.\...t:.llll.I..E
THOM,Al.o w. nOMlf',IICK
wl~J'"nID c;. L.L."",^Nr..
E"'. LOPf"l. ~A
Mlc:~,.t:~ (~ !",CHAE:F"ER
1.I~Al(IIE. 'I'I1\.l1l'JN
2ISNCR'H1 D r;TREET, J"I~~T n.OOR
!lAN 85:RNARDINO. CAt..,F'DRNIA '9~~1.' 712
TF,LF.:.....ONE I~O.'l ".'!!J-3G91 ~ Jl-2
r"'c:OI....IL[ 101')?I eBo.:;j, I ~
F'mM WE:~SITC: WWW"INL.ANOEJU5INE~SLAW.COM
OF COUNOr';\"
RCLlf.RT V, rULLCRTON'
P 5 :1 a~""',:,;""o"''''l.. CClu'n~A,T'~"
""''''foII DEIilCRT Of"T,C;C
",,,,,...c r......T...n
??SG....A t:;OUN.TAV c~uu 0'(.
,"UIT'E: 1 50
II'Al..M Dl!.lilllll.'T. e.... ?:!2' 1
C'/(;O) ???''.J~?Z
FACSIMILE TRANSMISSION
Dale; J lily 2, 2002
Numhcr of Pagcs; 2
[lnc1ulling this Page)
Time:
~.. !)j)
A.M8
384-5302
File # 01-802
Destin~lioll Phone tI
Destination Fax 11384-5158
TO:
FROM:
RE:
Roger Davis
Sarah Adams
Bell Cab & Yellow Cab of San BernardiLlo
( )
( )
(X)
() Other:
Attached find request for eontimlance of the hearing set for July lS'h, A hard copy of the
document willl>e delivered via courier. If any further documenlation is needed, plcase conlDcl
me directly.
Please sign transmittcd documenls and retUl1l them by Fax.
For your infomlatioll.
In accordance wilh YOllr request.
Non,: It. YOU DID NOT REt:IiIVE ALL 01' Tim rAGES IN umBLE fORM, PI,[ASE CALL CINny AT (909) 889-
3691IMMF.nIATELY.
".-
"'fi"~
CONFIDENTIALITY NOTICE
"Ih,,' ui)Cunwnb acconlt';myin,; this tdccOplcr lfAX) t\':lns1Tli~~iun (;I)RIUilt confill,mL;al inCunlhilion bdnnsing to tllc sender which i5 Icgall)' privilcpt:J
I'he illrOIllMiol\ \S hU~"1'Irl~d only l'hr the use ofthc indIVidual or entity n~1Ucd .:I.hUve. Ifyo\l:lil"C nollh~ inwll&.d rttipicnl,)'Cu :1.l'C ll\'f..-:by nolit'icd Il\;J.t
Ufl) disclosllrc:. cop)"ing, distribution (lr the ukil"lJ of lIlIY t1ctiOll in rdillnce on lbc COl\ra1~ Of1his wlecopicd inrormalit)n is WifJJJl pmhihil~i:!.. If YllU
r,:C(:IV~d lhii tch:l.:up)' il1 errOT. p1c:l..~ immcdia\1l1y c31l tile s...'T\dcrroll..L'~ IQ i\rr:'IOSc for th~rel~lIl\ ofrllc tdccapkd dce~rmcm...
JUL-U~-~UU~ IUt Uq; j~ rn rULLtltlVI't Lr.nHl~l~ r.1 HL
,
rn^ nUt vuo uuo v11\J
I. vc....
~^W DFf'"ICE~.
F'ULLt:RTDN, LF;MANN, SCHAEFER & DOMINICK, LLP
^l'iNCTTE Dt."a,F:L LEF"LUI\..LE
T~C1MA!I';...., DUMIN1CK
WI1..r,..llU t:. l,.E:M........!'oI
MICtIACL. n. ll\CH1\tH':'R
CRAIO F- WIl..I.:.ON
Z 1:' "IQRTH 0 C"ff,(\:.C.T. FIRST FLOOQ
IiAN BCRNAROINC. CALIF"DRI'IIIA '312401.17' 2
Tf'l.E:j:l1 tUN;: 10DOl .A"-3ti91
"AC~II"Ul.l" 19091 UUY.511 !)
F'tRM WEBSITE:': WWW.INLANDBU5INEJ;.LAW.CDM
E-M:!.i1: blclnol.nn@jnlilnclbu.~iltc~..l~\\'.com
0" C~:".I"'.~el..
RQOt,;Hr v. 'UL..LEf<TQN'
.,. "HO' I.:==U:INA<.. CO""C"tA1Ig,,,
1-'.1.."" th:t:r"T n,.Flce
J.o.....c CC......CIll
7756"'-4. COUHl'tY Cl.....n OR,
SUITE I ~D
PALM O.c:!"II"'IIT. C-. 9.3::1: 11
17601 '1'7~'9S'l;':
July 2, 2002
VIA FACSIMILE & llANO DEUVERY
Mayor Judith Valles & Common Council
Office ofthc City Ckrk
City of San Bernardino
300 NOI1h "0" Slreet
San Bernardino, CA 92418
Re: Appeal oflhe Dceision of the Burcau of Franchises in rcgard to the Application of AAA
Inland Empire Cab
Dear Mayor Valles and Council Membcrs:
As you may be aware, our lirnl is counsel to Bell Cab & Yellow Cab of San Bernardino ill the above-
referenced maller.
This letter shall serve as our request for a conlinuance of the hearing set for July 15, 2002. Mr. SCOll
Schaffer, corporate representative for our clicnt, has a Public Utilities Commission matter and will be
unavailable on JUlie 15'h.
Mr. SchaIrer's palticipation is absolutcly necessary.
Accordingly, because of the unavailability of Mr. Schaffer, we request the matter be continued until
the next meeting date.
We look forward to hearing from you.
Very truly yours,
FULLERTON, LEMANN,
SCHAEFER & DOMINICK, LLP
wilmki:!
WCLsda
OFFICE OF THE CiTY CLERK
RACHEL G. CLARK, C.M.C. . CITY CLERK
300 North "D" Street- San Bernardino - CA 92418.0001
909.384.5002' Fax: 909.384.5158
www.ci.san-bernardino.ca.us
'"'
July 16, 2002
Patrick Pashkam, Chief Executive Officer
AAA Inland Empire Cab
3000 Date Street
Riverside, CA 92507
Dear Mr. Pashkam:
At the meeting of the Mayor and Common Council held on July 15, 2002, the
following action was taken regarding the appeal hearing relative to your Petition for
Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab:
The matter was continued to the Council meeting of August 5,2002, at
4:00 p.m.
If we can be of further assistance, please do not hesitate to contact this office.
Sincerely,
. !
--/' I
/,-- -...)>- <,.,
~,._' ~'.i"'
!i. i"
'/"
('Rachel G. Clark, CMC
,
City Clerk
RC:lh
cc: Business Registration Division
CiTY OF SAN BERNARDINO
A ."......TI'T.V'h ,",U ~ IH:n. v\ I Ill.''';:< Intporit\! . Arrnlmt~lhilitv . Resnect for Human Dignity. Honesty
AFFIDAVIT OF MARJORIE JAMESON
2
3
I, MaIjorie Jameson, could competently testify to the following having personal
4
knowledge thereof:
5
1.
On August 1,2002, at approximately 1:15 p.m., I called Bell Cab Company, at
6
7
(909) 808-1111, and requested that a taxicab pick me up at the Olive Garden Restaurant, on
8
Hospitality Lane, in the City of San Bernardino.
9
2.
At the time I called for a taxi, I had my twenty (20) month old son with me.
10
3.
At approximately 1 :45 p.m., Yellow Cab #262 arrived at the Olive Garden in
11
response to my request.
12
4. Before entering the taxicab, I inquired of the driver whether he had a child safety
13
14
seat for my son. The driver responded by saying, ''No.'' I then inquired whether any other Bell
15
Company cabs have child safety seats to which he replied, "No, none of the cabs have them" and
16
went on to state that it was my responsibility to provide a car seat. As I hesitated at the door, the
17
driver asked what my destination was. When I replied "Redlands" he stated, "You can just hold
18
him." After explaining that my child does not travel in a vehicle without a child safety seat or
19
proper restraints, the driver drove away.
20
21
I further certify under penalty of perjury under the laws of the State of California that the
22
foregoing is true and correct of my own knowledge.
23
24 Dated: 8/1/0fS-
25 Entered into Rat.... g/5/fJ2.
I;.., ',cillCmyOe,C..._
26 ~ f'~
'1\
27 ~a Item - lJ
re ""
28 ~~.J..J_ e.e~
City ClerldCOC See, 1
Cit' of San Bernlrdillo
OFFICE OF THE CITY CLERK
RACHEL G. CLARK, C.M.C. - CITY CLERK
300 North "0" SlIeet. San Bernardino. CA92418.000I
909.384.5002. Fax: 909.384.5158
www.ci.san-bernardino.ca.us
'"
August 7, 2002
Mr. Patrick Pashkam, Chief Executive Officer
AAA Inland Empire Cab
3000 Date Street
Riverside, CA 92507
Dear Mr. Pashkam:
At the meeting of the Mayor and Common Council held on August 5, 2002, the following
action was taken relative to the appeal hearing relative to your Petition for Franchise Permit
for AAA Inland Empire Cab:
That the hearing be closed; that the Mayor and Common Council overturn the
Bureau of Franchises' denial of a Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland
Empire Cab to operate 25 taxicabs in the City of San Bernardino; that the matter
be referred back to the Bureau of Franchises to determine whether the current
holder of the permit shall be allowed to increase the number of vehicles in the
same proportion that the total increase bears to the number of such vehicles
theretofore operated by the holder; or to grant the permit to the applicant; that
the City Attorney be directed to prepare the necessary fmdings, and that the
matter be continued to August 19, 2002; and that the ordinance be referred back
to the Legislative Review Committee for review.
If we can be of further assistance, please do not hesitate to contact this office.
Sincerely,
~h.~
Rachel G. Clark, CMC
City Clerk
RGC:ls
cc: Business Registration Division
CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
ADOPTED SHARED VALVES: Integrity. Accountability. Respect for Human Dignity. Honesty
JOHN K. MlRAU'
MARK C. EDWARDS
ROBERT W. CANNON!
STANLEY A. HARTER'
.MICHAEL J. LEWIN
. LA"Y_..OF,~I<E.ES OF
MIRAU, EDWARDS~J~ANNON, HARTER & LEWIN =~,,:'C= _
.. _...:.;t::-:;;,-,~-'>':':~
A P~C>FESSIC>NAL,.~C>RPC>RA.TION
j-f't
. Cenified Spco;.list. Taxation
Law, The Swe Bar of Cal;fomi~
Boanlllfl.epISp<<ialil<lliOfl
'CenifiedS~.li$l,Esllle
P1:uU1;ng,TrustandProbaIC
L1w,Thc:SweBarofCalifornia
BoudofLeplSp<<;aliwion
1806 Orange Tree Lane, Suite C
Redlands, CA 92374
telephone: (909) 793-0200
facsimile: (909) 79J,0790
medwards@mechlaw.com
August 14, 2002
A2066-001
Huston T. Carlyle, Jr., Esq.
Senior Assistant City Attorney
City of San Bernardino
300 North "D" Street. 6th Floor
San Bernardino CA 9240 I
Re: Proposed City Council Resolution re Appeal of AAA Inland Empire Cab
Company
Dear Mr. Carlyle:
We received and have reviewed the draft resolution which you faxed to our office
yesterday. AAA Inland Empire Cab Company has no objections to the resolution in the form
you faxed to us.
As I will be on the East Coast the first part of next week, I have requested that the Mayor
defer this matter until the next Council meeting which, I believe, will be held on September 2. I
have advised Craig Wilson, Mr. Lemann's associate, of that request. That would still permit the
matter to be heard by the Franchise Bureau on September 10th.
Please call if you have any questions regarding this matter.
Very Truly Yours,
MIRAU, EDWARDS, CANNON,
HARTER & LEWIN
A Professional Corporation,
Al2066/001/carlyI.002
Cc AAA Inland Empire Cab Company, attn Peter Withers
Craig Wilson. ,Esq.
LAW O~~ICE8
CONfiRMATION
COpy
FULLERTON, LEMANN, SCHAEF'ER & DOMINICK, LLP
ANNETTE OEBELLEFEUILLE
THOMAS W. DOMINICK
WILFRID C. LEMANN
MICHAEL R. SCHAEFER
CRAIG E. WILSON
215 NOFilTH D..sTREET, FIRST FLOOR .
BAN BERNARDINO, CALIF"CRNIA 924Cl-1712
TELEPHONE (909) SS9-3691
FACSIMII.E 1909l aSS-51 1 <;I
FIRM WEBS1TE: WWW.INLANOBUSINESSLAW.COM
E.Mail: cwilson@inlandbusincsslaw.com
OF COUNSEl.
ROBERT V. FULLERTON'
'A PROFESSIONAL CORPORATION
PAI.M DESERT O"FICE
PARC CENTe:R
77S64-A CCUNTRY CLUIS DR.
SUITE 1 50
PALM DESERT, CA 9221 1
(7601 779-9572
August 29, 2002
VIA FACSIMILE (909-384-5238)
AND FIRST CLASS MAIL
Huston T. Carlyle, Jr., Esq.
Senior Assistant City Attorney
City of San Bernardino
300 North "D" Street, 6th Floor
San Bernardino, CA 92401
Re: Proposed City Council Resolution/Appeal AAA Inland Empire Cab Company
Dear Mr. Carlyle:
We have had an opportunity to view the video of the city counsel hearing of August 6, 2002. We are
not recommending any changes to the Resolution as drafted.
Very truly yours,
FULLERTON, LEMANN,
SCHAEFER & DOMINICK, LLP
~.~.?-<
~raig E. Wilson
CEW:t1n
cc: Scott Schaffer
Mark C. Edwards, Esq.
1?0. ,~~ ,--~\ '\\,(i
(~..'-.::-/u Lf
.
1
RESOLUTION NO.
c
.
2 RESOLUTION OF THE MAYOR AND COMMON COUNCIL OF THE CITY OF
SAN BERNARDINO ADOPTING FINDINGS IN SUPPORT OF THE COUNCIL'S DECISION
3 TO OVERTURN THE BUREAU OF FRANCHISES' DENIAL OF THE PETITION FOR A
FRANCHISE PERMIT FOR AAA INLAND EMPIRE CAB COMPANY.
4
BE IT RESOLVED BY MAYOR AND COMMON COUNCIL OF THE CITY OF
5 SAN BERNARDINO AS FOLLOWS:
6 SECTION 1. WHEREAS, on June I 1, 2002, the Bureau of Franchises denied a Petition
for a Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab Company; and
7
WHEREAS, AAA Inland Empire Cab Company filed a timely appeal of the decision of the
8 Bureau of Franchises to the Council; and
9 WHEREAS, on August 5, 2002, the Mayor and Common Council held a public hearing on
the appeal filed by AAA Inland Empire Cab Company; and
10
WHEREAS, the Mayor and Common Council have received and considered the
n documentary evidence, testimony, and arguments presented by the interested parties and the witnesses;
o
12 SECTION 2. In accordance with San Bernardino Municipal Code Section 5.76.050, and
based upon the documentary evidence, testimony, and arguments presented by the interested parties
13 and the witnesses, the Common Council makes the following Findings in support of the Council's
reversal of the Bureau of Franchises' denial of the Petition for a Franchise Permit for AAA Inland
14 Empire Cab Company:
15 Further service in the nature proposed by AAA Inland Empire Cab Company is
required by the public convenience and necessity.
16
17
There exists a public demand for an additional 25 taxicabs and the taxicab
service currently being rendered is inadequate. Local economist John E. Husing
wrote that three groups of San Bernardino residents are disproportionately
dependent upon taxies: the elderly, the handicapped, and the poor. These three
groups depend upon readily accessible taxicabs. Although Bell CabIY ellow Cab
has a franchise to operate 45 taxicabs in the City of San Bernardino, Bell
CabIY ellow Cab had only 12 drivers with current business registrations as of the
August 5, 2002, Council hearing. Based upon the testimony at the public hearing
and the written statements submitted, Bell CabIY ellow Cab has produced slow
service on several occasions. The managers of the La Quinta Inn and the Hilton
Hotel both cited the delay in current response times for taxicabs under Bell
CabIY ell ow Cab. Disabled activists Robert Neves and John Anaya testified relative
to Bell CabIY ell ow Cab and its delays in service being especially detrimental to the
disabled who have few alternatives for transportation. Other persons provided
written statements citing slow service.
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
c
SECTION 3. The Council finds that further service in the nature of that proposed by AAA
25 Inland Empire Cab Company is required by the public convenience and necessity and therefore, the
Council overturns the Bureau of Franchises' denial of the Petition for a Franchise Permit for AAA
26 Inland Empire Cab Company. The Council refers this matter back to the Bureau of Franchises for its
determination, pursuant to San Bernardino Municipal Code Section 5.76.060(A), as to whether Bell
27 CabIYellow Cab should receive an increase of 25 taxicabs or whether AAA Inland Empire Cab
Company should be granted a permit for the 25 taxicabs it has requested.
28 III
HE/cj[burotTr2.res)
1
c
1 RESOLUTION OF THE MAYOR AND COMMON COUNCIL OF THE CITY OF
SAN BERNARDINO ADOPTING FINDINGS IN SUPPORT OF THE COUNCIL'S DECISION
2 TO OVERTURN THE BUREAU OF FRANCmSES' DENIAL OF THE PETITION FOR A
FRANCmSE PERMIT FOR AAA INLAND EMPIRE CAB COMPANY.
3
4 I HEREBY CERTIFY that the foregoing Resolution was duly adopted by the Mayor and
Common Council of the City of San Bernardino at a meeting thereof, held on the _day
5
of , 2002, by the following vote, to wit:
6
7 COUNCIL MEMBERS: AYES NAYS ABSTAIN ABSENT
8 ESTRADA
9 LIEN
10 MCGI1'<'NIS
11 DERRY
12 SUAREZ
13 ANDERSON
C 14 MC CAMMACK
15
16
Rachel Clark, City Clerk
17
18
The foregoing Resolution is hereby approved this _ day of
,2002.
19
20
JUDITH VALLES,
Mayor City of San Bernardino
21
22
23 Approved as to form
24 and legal content:
25 JAMES F. PENMAN
26 City Attorney
C /~ t .)
27 I~
()
28
HElcj[buroffr2.res]
2
LAW O~~ICES
CONFIRMATION
COpy
FULLERTON, LEMANN, SCHAEFER & DOMINICK, LLP
0, ANNETTE OEBELLEI"'EUILLE 2 15 NORTH 0 "STREET, I"'IAST FLOOA .
THOMAS w. OOMINIGK BAN BERNARDINO, CALIFORNIA 92401.1712
WILI"'AIO C. LEMANN TELEPHONE (9091 BB9-3691
MICHAEL R. SCHAEFER I"'AClIlMIL.E 19091 BSB-:S 119
CRAIG E. WILSON FIRM WEBSITE: WWW.INL.ANDBUSINESSLAW.COM
E~Mail: cwilson@inlandbusincsslaw.com
01'" COUNSE:L.
ROBERT V. I"'ULL.ERTON'
'A PROFE:SSIONAL CORPORATION
PAL.M DESERT OFFICE
PARC CENTER
77S64-A COUNTRY CLUB D~.
SUITE 150
PALM DE:S1ERT, CA 9221 1
(7601 779-9572
August 29, 2002
VIA FACSIMILE (909-384-5238)
AND FIRST CLASS MAIL
Huston T. Carlyle, Jr., Esq.
Senior Assistant City Attorney
City of San Bernardino
300 North "D" Street, 6th Floor
San Bernardino, CA 92401
c
Re: Proposed City Council Resolution/Appeal AAA Inland Empire Cab Company
Dear Mr. Carlyle:
We have had an opportunity to view the video of the city counsel hearing of August 6, 2002. We are
not recommending any changes to the Resolutiol1 as drafted.
Very truly yours,
FULLERTON, LEMANN,
SCHAEFER & DOMINICK, LLP
~ '..z=r -? - ~
~aig E. Wilson
CEW:tln
cc: Scott Schaffer
Mark C. Edwards, Esq.
c
JOHN K. MlRAU"
MARK C. EDWARDS
R.OBERT W. CANNON!
CNLEY A. HARTER"
CHAEL 1. LEWIN
. LA'1(,',OF..!ij,~;ES C>F
"\ ""I.j . ~
MIRAU, EDWARDS/.GANNON, HARTER & LEWlN~W\iX~
A. PRC>FESSIC>NAL',__~C>RPC>RA.TIC>N
~
'~
..'~'~cj~
~.!t
. CcnificdSp<<i;aJ;5I.TaQlion
law.TheSlaleBarofCalifomi.
80ud ortepl Spcciali~liOll
>('oIftifiedSpecialist,ElllIlC
PlaI\lIinio TtII$IiIlId1'robate
LIw, The Stale Bar of Calirnm;a
BoudotLcgalSpcciali:cllioR
1806 Orange Tree Lane, Suite C
Redlands, CA 92374
telephone: (909) 793.0200
facsimile: (909) 793-0790
medwards@mechlaw.com
August 14,2002
A2066-00 I
Huston T. Carlyle, Jr., Esq.
Senior Assistant City Attorney
City of San Bernardino
300 North "D" Street, 6th Floor
San Bernardino CA 92401
Re: Proposed City Council Resolution re Appeal of AAA Inland Empire Cab
Company
Dear Mr. Carlyle:
o
We received and have reviewed the draft resolution which you faxed to our office
yesterday. AAA Inland Empire Cab Company has no objections to the resolution in the form
you fa'(ed to us.
As I will be on the East Coast the first part of next week, I have requested that the Mayor
defer this matter until the next Council meeting which, I believe, will be held on September 2. I
have advised Craig Wilson, Mr. Lemann's associate, of that request. That would still permit the
matter to be heard by the Franchise Bureau on September 10th.
Please call if you have any questions regarding this matter.
Very Truly Yours,
MIRAU, EDWARDS, CANNON,
HARTER & LEWIN
A Professional Corporation,
c
Al2066/00 1/carly1.002
Cc AAA lnland Empire Cab Company, attn Peter Withers
Craig Wilson, ,Esq.
23
24 Dated: JIt/OfS-
Entered into.... II gli/fJ L M
25
Ll \r.lIlCmvDllYCms_
26 rrr~ CL,~
C !~
27 la Item -- 11
re .-\.'
28 Ck~
c'~J . L.
City ClerklCDC Seey 1
- - - __..a!__
c
9
10
11
12
13
C 14
15
16
17
18
AFFIDAVIT OF MARJORIE JAMESON
2
3
I, MaIjorie Jameson, could competently testify to the following having personal
4
knowledge thereof:
5
1.
On August 1,2002, at approximately 1:15 p.m., I called Bell Cab Company, at
6
7
(909) 808-1111, and requested that a taxicab pick me up at the Olive Garden Restaurant, on
8
Hospitality Lane, in the City of San Bernardino.
2. At the time I called for a taxi, I had my twenty (20) month old son with me.
3. At approximately 1:45 p.m., Yellow Cab #262 arrived at the Olive Garden in
response to my request.
4. Before entering the taxicab, I inquired of the driver whether he had a child safety
seat for my son. The driver responded by saying, "No." I then inquired whether any other Bell
Company cabs have child safety seats to which he replied, "No, none ofthe cabs have them" and
went on to state that it was my responsibility to provide a car seat. As I hesitated at the door, the
driver asked what my destination was. When I replied "Redlands" he stated, "You can just hold
him." After explaining that my child does not travel in a vehicle without a child safety seat or
19
proper restraints, the driver drove away.
20
I further certify under penalty of perjury under the laws of the State of California that the
21
22
foregoing is true and correct of my own knowledge.
~ =#~J ~fi9;':2-;
;(10
9Iq!o~
c
o
c
DATE:
TO:
FROM:
SUBJECT:
COPIES:
CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
INTEROFFICE MEMORANDUM
CITY CLERK'S OFFICE
July 12,2002
Mayor Judith Valles and Common Council
Cindy Buechter, Business Registration Supervisor
Appeal - AAA Inland Empire Cab Company
Mayor and Common Council Meeting, July 15, 2002
Fred Wilson, City Administrator; Jim Penman, City Attorney; Rachel
Clark, City Clerk; Roger Davis, Business License Inspector
Please find attached background information submitted by the City Clerk's Office,
Business Registration Division in regards to AAA Inland Empire Cab Company's appeal
to be heard at the July 15, 2002 Mayor and Common Council meeting.
=#;l.~
'tIt'! a 2...
c\
NOTICE OF APPEAL
AAA INLAND EMPIRE CAB COMPANY
BACKGROUND INFORMATION
SUBMITTED BY THE CITY CLERK'S OFFICE
BUSINESS REGISTRATION DIVISION
JULY 12, 2002
Following is a summary of the City's actions regarding the Petition for a Franchise
Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab and the action taken by the Bureau of Franchises.
Also included is background information on Bell Cab/Yellow Cab and information on
taxi drivers and the process required for the issuance of their business registration. In
addition, our office researched the history of taxi companies operating in the City, the
number of registered vehicles for each company (if known), ordinances pertaining to the
regulation and limit of taxi vehicles, and the history of the Bureau of Franchises.
Petition for Franchise Permit bv AAA Inland Empire Cab Companv
o
On January 8, 2002 the Bureau of Franchises considered the petition submitted by AAA
Inland Empire Cab to provide taxicab service in the City of San Bernardino. The Bureau
denied the Petition for a Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab by a vote of 5 to 1
(minutes attached as Exhibit A). AAA Inland Empire Cab did not file an appeal to this
decision. However, they subsequently submitted a new petition and paid the appropriate
filing fees for the operation of25 taxicabs. The Bureau of Franchises heard the new
Petition for Franchise Permit at their meeting on June 11,2002 (draft minutes attached as
Exhibit B). The Bureau again denied AAA's petition by a vote of 4 to 2 based on not
seeing a need for granting the Franchise. The Bureau was unable to approve the minutes
of the June 11,2002 meeting, as there was a lack ofa quorum for the July 9,2002
meeting.
AAA Inland Empire Cab Company filed a Notice of Appeal with the City Clerk's Office
on June 26,2002. The City Clerk's Office then placed the matter on the agenda for the
regularly scheduled meeting of the Mayor and Common Council to take place on July 15,
2002.
On July 2,2002, the City Clerk's Office received a facsimile letter from Wilfrid
C.Lemann of the Law Offices of Fullerton, Lemann, Schaefer & Dominick, counsel to
Bell Cab & Yellow Cab, requesting a continuance of the hearing set for July 15, 2002
because of the unavailability of Mr. Schaffer, representative of Bell CabIYellow Cab. On
July 10, 2002, the City Clerk's Office received a facsimile letter from Mark C. Edwards
of the Law Offices of Mirau, Edwards, Cannon, Harter & Lewin, counsel for AAA Inland
Empire Cab Company, stating their opposition to the request for continuance and further
asked that the appeal hearing be held as scheduled.
c
C Background - Bell CabN ellow Cab
Bell Cab Company submitted a Petition for Franchise Permit to the City Clerk's Office,
Business Registration Division, on February 17, 1998. Bell Cab Company paid the
required permit fee, plus the required fee for 36 vehicles.
At the time of Bell Cab's application, Yellow Cab Co., Inc. was the only taxi company
operating in the City of San Bernardino. In 1998, Yellow Cab was paying a business
registration fee to operate 35 vehicles. Research shows that a permit was originally issued
to Art Parlas of Red & White Taxi per Resolution No. 2528 on December 15, 1952.
Records indicate that Red & White Taxi was transferred to Yellow Cab Company on
August 4,1955.
The Bureau of Franchises considered Bell Cab's petition at their meeting held September
8,1998 (minutes attached at Exhibit C). The Bureau approved Bell Cab's Petition for a
Franchise Permit by a unanimous vote.
c
Bell Cab Company applied for the Business Registration Certificate on November 23,
1998 indicating a start date of October 15, 1998. Bell Cab paid the required business
registration fee for 36 vehicles. Business registration records show that Yellow Cab
Company closed their business and their business registration account was closed on
February 12,1999 per instructions of the Business Registration Supervisor. When Bell
Cab Company renewed their business registration for the year October 1, 1999 through
September 30, 2000, they paid the required registration fee for 45 vehicles. Their
application indicates the business name as Yellow - Bell Cab. Business registration
computer records indicate that the payment reflects 34 vehicles for Yellow Cab & II
vehicles for Bell Cab. Bell CabN ellow Cab has since continued to pay an annual
business registration fee for 45 vehicles. Bell Cab Company's current business
registration expires on September 30, 2002.
Historv of Taxi Cab Ordinance
The earliest record our research found was Ordinance No. 1454, "An ordinance
regulating the operation of motor vehicles transporting passengers for hire within the City
of San Bernardino", adopted December 15, 1930. The Ordinance set forth that a permit
was required for the operation of taxicabs and the City Clerk and Police Department
granted that approval. This Ordinance did not contain provisions as to limiting the
number of taxicabs allowed.
Ordinance No. 1809, adopted December 31, 1947 amended Ordinance 1454 and set forth
driver regulations. Ordinance No. 1894 adopted September 5, 1950 amended the original
ordinance and added sections pertaining to taxi meters. Ordinance No. 1936 adopted
February 18, 1952 amended Ordinance 1454 by adding sections regarding driver
regulations.
c
2
c
o
c
On July 6,1953, Ordinance No. 1987 was adopted and repealed Ordinance No. 1454.
This Ordinance created the Bureau of Franchises. Although this Ordinance did not set a
limit as to the number of taxicabs allowed to operate, it did set forth that "Such permit
shall be for a specified number of vehicles which shall only be increased by authority of
the Bureau. Such permit may, at the pleasure of the Bureau, be for a prescribed period or
for an indefinite period.
Ordinance No. 2401, adopted November 27,1961, amending Ordinance No. 1987 was
the first time a limit was set for the number of taxicabs. This Ordinance set forth that
"One (I) taxicab shall be permitted for each 2,500 residents of the City of San
Bernardino, or major portion thereof."
Ordinance No. 3002, adopted July 14,1969, amended Ordinance No. 1987 and changed
the taxicab limit to "Not more than one (I) taxicab...for each 2,000 residents of the City
of San Bernardino..."
Municipal Code Section 5.76.060B currently allows for "Not more than one
taxicab.. .permitted for each two thousand five hundred residents of the City, or major
portion thereof."
History of Franchises
December 15, 1952 - Resolution No. 2528 granted an application for a permit to Red &
White Cab! Art Parlas to engage in the taxicab business.
September 8, 1998 - Bureau of Franchises approves Petition for a Franchise Permit for
Bell Cab Company for 36 vehicles.
Historv of Taxi Companies from Business Registration Records
The Business Registration Division researched the history of taxicab companies through
the business registration files. Attached Exhibits D & E show each of the companies
found, how they merged and evolved, any reference to the number of vehicles they
operated and a time line as to their operation.
As recently as 1994, the City had three taxi companies operating. They consisted of
Airline Taxi of San Bernardino operating 16 vehicles, Yellow Cab Co. Inc. operating 25
vehicles, and Checker Cab Company operating 15 vehicles. In 1994, Edward Parlas
owned all three companies. In 1995, business registration records show that both Airline
Taxi and Checker Cab closed their business and indicated that all their cabs were now
registered under Yellow Cab. Yellow Cab's business registration application in January,
1995 shows an increase in the number of paid vehicles from 25 to 35. Yellow Cab
continued to pay a business registration fee for 35 vehicles through 1998; their business
registration account was closed February 12, 1999.
3
C Taxi Drivers - Business Registration Procedures
Per Municipal Code Section 5.76.280C, (Exhibit F) "A person authorized to operate
under carrier's permit by arrangement, contract or lease shall be deemed to be an
independent contractor and shall obtain a City business license." In addition, per SBMC
Section 5.76.290 (Exhibit G), all taxi drivers are subject to a background investigation by
the Chief of Police. The Chief of Police will then forward a report to the secretary of the
Bureau with their findings.
Business Registration Division procedure is that the taxi drivers are sent to the Police
Department, I.D. Bureau, for the processing of the background investigation. When the
investigation is complete, the I.D. Bureau notifies the Business Registration Division of
their recommendation (Exhibit H). If the Police Department recommends the approval of
the driver, the division then notifies the driver by letter that they may obtain their
business registration. A background investigation is also required annually at the time of
the business registration renewal.
o
Business registration records indicate there are 17 drivers with Bell Cab/Y ellow Cab with
current business registrations. Two drivers are in a delinquent status. A check with PD's
Records Division indicates that two new drivers have recently submitted their papers for
an investigation, however it is unclear if the two drivers in delinquent status have
contacted the PD.
c
4
c
MINUTES
BUREAU OF FRANCHISES
FOR THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
REGULAR MEETING
January 8, 2002
The regular meeting of the Bureau of Franchises was called to or-
der by Chairman Dennis Cole at 2:15 p.m., Tuesday, January 8,2002 in
the Management Information Conference Room located on the 6th floor of
City Hall, 300 North "D" Street, San Bernardino.
c
ROLL CALL
Roll call was taken by Chairman Cole with the following being pre-
sent: Board Members Payne, Fernandez, Turner, Shultz, Wilcoxen and
Secretary Lee Gagnon. Also present: Deputy City Attorney Henry Em-
peno, Guy A. Harrell with AAA Inland Empire Cab, Frank McFadden with
AAA Inland Empire Cab, Kevin King with AAA Inland Empire Cab, Peter
Withers consultant for AAA Inland Empire Cab, Jeff Navidi with AAA In-
land Empire Cab, Vanike Zadurian with Bell Cab/Yellow Cab, Scott
Shaffer with Bell Cab/Yellow Cab, Greg Goumaskyan with Bell
Cab/Yellow Cab, Javier Alba with Bell Cab/Yellow Cab, and Rusty Dea-
ton with Bell Cab/Yellow Cab. Absent: Board Members Martindale and
Enciso.
APPROVAL OF MINUTES
Board Member Turner made a motion seconded by Board Member
Payne, and unanimously carried, that the minutes of the following
meeting of the Bureau of Franchises be approved as submitted in their
type written form: May 8, 2001
c
NEW BUSINESS
Chairman Cole opened discussion to consider the request by AAA
Inland Empire Cab to provide taxicab service in the City of San
Bernardino. Deputy City Attorney Henry Empeno opened discussion by
indicating he had passed out a copy of Municipal Code Chapter 5.76
governing the operation of taxicab service in the City of San Bernardino.
Mr. Empeno read Municipal Code Section 5.76.050 and emphasized the
need for the applicant to establish the existence of public convenience
and necessity. Mr. Empeno also added that no permit shall be issued
unless there has been an affirmative showing of the existence of such
public convenience and necessity.
,.. I.L., A
c
o
c
Mr. Empeno then referred to Municipal Code Section 5.76.060 subsec-
tion B and indicated that not more than one taxicab, excluding dial-a-
ride taxicab, shall be permitted for each two thousand five hundred resi-
dents of the City or major portion thereof.
The population of the City is now 190,232. If you divide 190,232 by
two thousand five hundred you come up with a figure of 76 taxicabs now
permitted in the City of San Bernardino. Mr. Empeno indicated Bell Cab
was approved for 36 cabs in 1998. Therefore, there is the possibility that
there could be an additional 40 taxicabs approved.
Mr. Peter Withers indicated that the addition of another taxicab
company would provide competition and that the standard of service
would rise. He indicated that the primary users of taxicab service are the
elderly, low income and disabled and that service should be a prime con-
sideration. Board Member Payne asked if there had been any complaints
received about taxicab service. Secretary Lee Gagnon indicated that no
complaints had been received since 1992. Further discussion ensured
concerning the current level of service.
Non-emergency medical transportation will not be offered by AM
Inland Empire taxicab under this Franchise.
Board Member Fernandez asked if cab drivers would be employees
of AM Inland Empire Cab or if AM would contract with the drivers?
Mr. McFadden answered by saying that drivers would be independent
contractors because they sign a lease agreement. Drivers are drug tested
to make sure they are drug free. Further discussion regarding service en-
sued.
Scott Schaffer made presentation for Bell Cab/Yellow Cab. Mr.
Schaffer stated that they do from 160 to 170 cab trips a day in the City of
San Bernardino or 5000 trips per year, Fourteen months ago they did
8,000 or 9,000 trips per year. Mr. Schaffer said there had been no com-
plaints regarding taxicab service to indicate that there was a need for
more. Mr. Schaffer also indicated that if you put additional cabs in the
City of San Bernardino the drivers will have to drive sixteen hours a day
to make any money. Further discussion ensued relative to Bell
Cab/Yellow Cab current service levels and the impact of additional cabs.
Mr. Schaffer requested that the petition for Franchise Permit be
denied. Further discussion ensued with respect to the market for further
cab service. Chairman Cole indicated that the decision of the board
should be based upon the public need and necessity for additional taxi-
cabs and has the applicant substantiated that need.
Board Member Payne made a motion seconded by Board Member
Shultz that the Petition for Franchise Permit submitted by AM Inland
Empire Cab be denied, carried by the following vote: Ayes, Board Mem-
bers Payne, Fernandez, Turner, Shultz and Cole; Nayes, Board Member
Wilcoxen.
c
o
c
Election of Officers
Chairman Cole opened discussion relative to the election of officers for
the 2002 calendar year. Chairman Cole indicated that a Chairman and
Vice Chairman needed to be selected. Board Member Payne made a mo-
tion that Dennis Cole be nominated as chairman for a second term and
the motion was seconded be Board Member Turner. The motion carried
unanimously. Board Member Shultz made a motion that Dr. Louis Fer-
nandez be nominated as Vice Chairman and the motion was seconded by
Board Member Payne. The motion carried unanimously.
ADJOURNMENT
At 3.33 p.m., Chairman Cole adjourned the regular meeting of the
Bureau of Franchises to Tuesday, February 12,2002, at City Hall, 300 N
"D" Street, San Bernardino, California.
\
''] .1
. ;; ~ - .~
Lee Gagnon, Secretary to
Bureau of Franchises
\
~- ~
-'\-.._--~"--
c
c
c
~ ~ ~
MINUTES
BUREAU OF FRANCHISES
FOR THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
REGULAR MEETING
June 11, 2002
The regular meeting of the Bureau of Franchises was called to order by Chairman
Dennis Cole at 2:00 p.m., Tuesday, June 11,2002 in the Management Information
Conference Room located on the 6th floor of City Hall, 300 North "D" Street, San
Bernardino.
Roll Call
Chairman Cole took roll call with the following being present: Board Members
Shultz, Turner, Carson, Martindale, Fernandez, and Secretary Lee Gagnon. Also present:
Deputy City Attorney Henry Empeno, Greg Goumashyan - Bell CablY ellow Cab, Steve
Lee - Bell CablY ellow Cab, Pat McGuire - Bell CablY ellow Cab, Kareen Gates - Bell
CablYellow Cab, Frank Wu - Bell CablYellow Cab, Yanik Zadurian - Bell CablYellow
Cab, Scott Schaffer - Bell CablY ellow Cab, Peter Withers - AAA Inland Empire Cab,
Mark Edwards - Attorney for AAA Inland Empire Cab, Rusty Deaton - Bell CablY ellow
Cab, Frank McFadden - AAA Inland Empire Cab, Wilfred Lemann - Attorney for Bell
CablY ellow Cab, Alex Acuna - AAA Inland Empire Cab, Houan Hkann - AAA Inland
Empire Cab, JeffNauidi - AAA Inland Empire Cab, Khachik Pashkam - AAA Inland
Empire Cab. Absent Board Member: Enciso.
Approval of Minutes
Chairman Cole opened discussion regarding approval of two previous agenda
items and indicated that Deputy City Attorney Henry Empeno wanted to comment on the
action needed by the Bureau on these agenda items. Mr. Empeno indicated that the
agenda for the last meeting was not posted and therefore the minutes for the February 12,
2002 meeting would have to be re-approved and the Petition for Franchise Permit
submitted by Inland Medical Transportation would also have to be re-approved. Mr.
Empeno indicated nothing had changed with these items and that he recommended
approvaL
Board Member Turner made a motion seconded by Board Member Shultz, and
unanimously carried, that the minutes of the following meeting of the Bureau of
Franchises be re-approved as submitted in their type written form: February 12,2002.
Board Member Turner made a motion seconded by Board Member Carson, and
unanimously carried, that the minutes ofthe following meeting of the Bureau of
Franchises be approved as submitted in their type written form: May 14,2002.
,J., ~
c
c
c
Old Business
Board Member Shultz made a motion seconded by Board Member Carson and
unanimously carried, that the Petition for Franchise Permit submitted by Inland Medical
Transportation to provide non emergency medical transportation be re-approved.
Chairman Cole opened discussion to consider AAA Inland Empire Cab Petition
for Franchise Permit submitted by AAA Inland Empire Cab. Mr. Empeno indicated that
the Petition for Franchise permit had been previously denied and a letter was sent dated
January 10, 2002 to owners of AAA Inland Empire Cab notifying them of that fact.
AAA Inland Empire cab did not file an appeal of the decision but elected to re-submit
their application based upon new information. A new application fee was paid by AAA
Inland Empire Cab on April 3, 2002 by the applicant. Mr. Empeno advised the Board to
consider this as a new application and that such a motion be considered before the Board
considered that matter. Board Member Carson made a motion seconded by Board
Member Fernandez, and unanimously carried, that the Petition for Franchise Permit
submitted by AAA Inland Empire cab to operate 25 taxi cabs in the City of San
Bernardino be considered by the Board as a new application.
Chairman Cole asked AAA Inland Empire Cab to make their opening statement.
Mark Edwards, Attorney for AAA Inland Empire made a presentation to the Bureau from
a six page cover document entitled, "Presentation of Mark C. Edwards, Attorney for
AAA Inland Empire Cab Co. To The City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau, June 11,
2002." Mr. Edwards indicated that they were charged with demonstrating and the Bureau
was charged with determining if, "the public convenience and necessity" is served by
pemlitting a second taxi cab company to operate in the City of San Bernardino. Mr.
Edwards further indicated that AAA Inland Empire Cab is presenting material indicating
that "a lot of agencies and individuals in the community who are not happy with the
current taxi service and that Bell CablY ellow Cab is providing materials indicating that
individuals think the service if fine." Mr. Edwards also indicated that there was no
mechanism in place for consumers to complain to the Bureau regarding service.
Mr. Edwards presented independent studies which he described "clearly
demonstrate tl1at quality of service increases, cost of service decreases, and ridership
increases if you have competition in the taxi cab industry." Mr. Edwards continued to
give a summary of the independent studies. In addition, Mr. Edwards referenced San
Bernardino Municipal Code Section 5.76.060 that, based on the limits set forth in the
Code, allows for a total of74 cabs to be licensed to operate and currently Bell
CablY ellow Cab has licenses for 36 cabs. Mr. Edwards also referred to a study by local
economist John Husing, showing California cities with populations of 180,000 - 450,000,
only two (Riverside and San Bernardino) have a single licensed taxi cab company. Every
other city of this size had at least three licensed companies. Mr. Edwards also discussed
that competition would have a positive affect on taxi cab drivers. "That what was hurting
drivers, was the lack of competition."
Mr. Edwards concluded by stating that the literature provided, "amply
demonstrates the public necessity and convenience will be served by competition and will
continue to be harmed if Bell Cab/Yellow Cab's monopoly in maintained."
2
c
o
c
Chairman Cole called for any questions regarding AAA's presentation. Chairman
Cole asked for clarification regarding statements made about the customer complaint
process. Secondly, Chairman Cole asked for clarification of the status of AAA's
application with the City of Riverside.
Chairman Cole asked Mr. Shaffer of Bell CablYellow Cab to present their
response. Mr. Shaffer indicated that he would first like to answer some of the issues that
were raised by Mr. Edwards. Mr. Shaffer commented that the issue before the Bureau
was not whether there was a monopoly, but whether there was a demand and a need for
more taxi cab service. Mr. Shaffer reviewed some of the comments made by Mr.
Edwards that he felt were taken out of context.
Mr. Shaffer then commented on AAA's presentation in regards to independent
studies. Mr. Shaffer indicated that all the studies that he has say that "it is a horrible
thing to license cabs with no justification. It leads to market cost going up, drivers
quitting, migrating to other businesses, insurance costs going up, taxi cabs not being
repaired, and the company providing no insurance for their cabs because they can't afford
to pay for the insurance." Also, Mr. Shaffer commented on John Husing's study
indicating that many of the other cities noted provide millions of dollars in subsidized
taxi cab business to do their ADA transfer work, which is what Omnitrans is doing here
in the City of San Bernardino. Mr. Shaffer went on to say that you could argue both
decisions, but that it is a policy decision that this Board will need to decide on. Mr.
Shaffer also summarized the Price Waterhouse study.
Mr. Shaffer submitted to the Secretary the information that gives the opposite side
ofMr. Edwards's studies. Mr. Shaffer stated further the each city has its own specific
characteristics and that what worked in another city, does not mean that it will work in
San Bernardino.
Mr. Lemann, attorney for Bell Cab/Yellow Cab, cited the San Bernardino
Municipal Code and what is required. Mr. Lemann covered several issues that he
believed the Code required including that it must be found that there is a public demand
for the service, there needs to be some challenge about the adequacy of the current
service, and the impact of service on traffic.
Taxi cab driver, Careem Gates gave a brief statement saying that the addition of
more cabs would be "destructive on the part of the cab business to bring on more cabs."
Further discussion ensued regarding response times, where cabs are stationed,
how many cabs are available at any given time, and the number of drivers. Mr. Empeno
gave clarification that 76 cabs would be allowed in the City per the Municipal Code and
current population figures. Mr. Empeno also clarified that with Bell Cab's application in
1998, a total of36 cabs were approved. However, since that time, Bell Cab has
purchased Yellow Cab and a total of 45 cabs are permitted to Bell CablYellow Cab.
Chairman Cole asked for a motion to approve or deny the petition made by AAA
Inland Empire Cab. Chairman Cole reminded the members "that what we are voting on
is just that, public convenience and necessity." In addition, Chairman Cole indicated that
"As I read the regulations and the ordinances, what we are being asked to vote on is not
an issue of competition, although that may play some into the public convenience and
necessity."
3
c
c
c
Board Member Shultz made a motion seconded by Board Member Turner, that
based on not seeing a need, that the applicant's petition be denied. Motion carried by a
vote of 4 to 2 to deny. Members opposed: Martindale and Fernandez.
Chairman Cole summarized the appeal process per Municipal Code Section
2.64.030 indicating that a written notice of appeal would need to be filed with the City
Clerk directed to the Mayor and Common Council. The appeal must be filed within a 15-
day period. The appeal would need to be received by the City Clerk's Office by 5:30
p.m., Wednesday, June 26,2002.
Adjournment
Prior to adjournment, Chairman Cole recognized departing member John Schultz
and his many years of service to the Bureau. in addition, Chairman Cole indicated that
he would be gone for most of the month of July.
At 3:40 p.m., Chairman Cole adjourned the regular meeting of the Bureau of
Franchises to Tuesday, July 9, 2002, at City Hall 300 N. "D" Street, San Bernardino,
California.
4
c
MINUTES
BUREAU OF FRANCHISES
FOR THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
REGULAR MEETING
SEPTEMBER 8,1998
The regular meeting of the Bureau of Franchises was called to order by
Chairman Bill Payne at 2:03 p.m., Tuesday, September 8, 1998 in the Management
Information Conference Room located on the 61h floor of City Hall, 300 North "D" Street,
San Bemardino, California.
ROLL CALL
Roll call was taken by Chairman Payne with the following being present: Board
Members Enciso, Cole, Turner, Shultz, Wilcoxen, Riccio, McCammack, Secretary Lee
Gagnon. Also present: Scott Schaffer, Executive Vice President of Bell Cab Company,
Rusty Deaton, Marketing Director of Bell Cab Company, Bob Simmons, Senior Deputy
City Attorney for the City of San Bernardino, Absent: Board Member Fernandez.
o
APPROVAL OF MINUTES
Board Member Turner made a motion, seconded by Board Member
McCammack, and unanimously carried, that the minutes of the following meeting of the
Bureau of Franchises be approved as submitted in their typewritten form: July 14, 1998.
NEW BUSINESS
<
Chairman Payne opened discussion relative to the public hearing to consider
application for taxicab service submitted by Scott Schaffer with Bell Cab Company of
Ontario, California. Scott Schaffer made a presentation indicating that he runs about
300 taxicabs between Los Angeles County, Riverside County and San Bernardino
County. During his presentation, Mr. Schaffer amended the number of taxicabs to be
operated within the City of San Bernardino from 36 to 40 which would be allowable
under Municipal code Section 5.76.060 subsection B. This subsection states that, "not
more than one taxicab, excluding dial-a-ride taxicabs shall be permitted for each two
thousand five hundred residents of the City, or major portion thereof."
Mr. Schaffer said that Metrolink ridership is increasing and therefore the need for
taxicabs will increase. He also indicated that Bell Cab is the largest provider of
wheelchair accessible taxicabs in Los Angeles County and in San Bemardino County.
Mr. Schaffer also stated that the current provider in the City of San Bemardino does not
provide this service.
c
Rusty Deaton, Director of Marketing with Bell Cab indicated that their drivers
wear uniforms with ties. Taxicabs are clean and air-conditioned. Drivers are drug tested
by the San Bernardino County Sheriff's Department. Rusty indicated that they work with
senior citizens because they have special needs. They also transport handicapped
children to and from schools and provide car seats for children.
,.. dL. t..:.L ('
c
o
c
Board Member McCammack asked Mr. Schaffer if there would be a dispatch
facility in the City of San Bernardino and he responded by saying yes. Mr. McCammack
also asked if $1,000,000.00 was the correct amount of insurance and Chairman Payne
responded by indicating that the $1,000,000.00 met the City of San Bernardino code
requirement. Discussion ensued regarding the need for additional taxicabs. Board
Member Wilcoxen made a motion seconded by Board Member Enciso that Bell Cab
Company be approved for a franchise to operate 40 taxicabs in the City of San
Bernardino, carried unanimously.
ADJOURNMENT
At 2:55 p.m., Chairman Payne adjourned the regular meeting of the Bureau of
Franchises to Tuesday, October 13, 1998 at City Hall, 300 North "0" Street, San
Bernardino, California.
. " (i~'
. I
) .
\ L.( /,~ .7'!.."
Lee Gagnon, cretary
To Bureau of Franchises
---'
~~~ ~-<:~>:;;;:t:~ -~"Tl("l;;cl'- Vi>>n- =>-o-l:;!C- -;::0 <;:t:>O >0 '>O-<:>-l...,O z>
~~a~r-~g C\ t:l (3 ~ (\I ~ >-("l0f11 ~-"~Cll;:l ~o~ ~ r1l 0. n ~n <~_~;r1l 0-
r1l 3 ~ <~3J:~& z:=83 =8~g. ~- ~ r"" .;:l ~ 0'"
~f!! _~~ 0<. . 0
~l g. 8..1:""r;;~r~q ~>>(\I~~ = I:"" c -g I "Tl S. 3 ?5g.~~ ~O" =5r"':-~3 0-
IO-lZ-l~ ~2a;;n ;;':2 -~;-l . ;;:-...
_. 0" N' - --=lcr
- . . :IE"''''''' - _:=:=2.,;;t-..I :=~ ~~- ;: g ~ ~ S' 30: 02
0-" ~~u....o 3 :- p~~2n~
;:;;'~t...l W ~-lm~po n t;l...; 0 'O;-l III ~:=; 3 52...; . ~~ ",.- Vi ~ 0 - = na._ ' '"'
~ 0:-" ::l.1':) >n:!..- .... = ~"- ~-ll:.o-g .... :-. N , >:> ~-;-i....::;>0'- 0.;
C ~ > 0 X > n' $ ~>-c :':-0 2~ Rooa>:> . 0- g r3 ::; . '" "'~~?~~ ~ >
n . - Vl :=l"In-o ~"'.- o ",3 0 :a -<'" < '"
0 0->:> =~-c:l~VI "tI:= Ul~,f::I. o. . . . .. n "
0-' .
C o >:> !:): :I: r.n o' r-' "tI:::r o' 2- ~:=; ~ - !:"l.. .? '" -0- 0- -: >~ ,'"
3 ~ .. ~ 0> "':1::S > > > -';:l ~O l'> ~ o _
S 00 F"O &: 00 .."" o~ l'_ """ ,;- 2 - z-
'" [ m~es[ -a ~ '"' " .2
.., . l""::oo 0:= 0 3 '"'
". c.l ;:;0 c:l s: ('i' > ,r ~ 2> :IE" ~ .
0 ::; Roo 2
~ m !!:. '" . ~ :;!2 _ r
n ~ ~ ~ ;; n ';2 '" ,
~ . "- ~ >- ~ ;;
2 ~ 0.
. '"'
0
~=~~
r-'t;l;;:~
"Roo;;>"
o "A
~~2.:"
n::;::;>~
>";0 v.
.. '" 3
I"'lI"'lH
0>
;::'"
"I"'l
>0
2.
"'?
VI'"C::tlo
e:> ~..
;If!!'"
:::;.>~
"-"':IE
'" -
- -
@ -
o .;
- '"
I"'l
>
S!'
>
'"
.;
C;:t:O::=
tJ ~ g l:"l
::s 0 n t;l
!ii2"3~
" :-.cr
~ g ~ ~
_. Z;; =
.... 0 ~ -
~i-.,:o;t
=~~
"~
n.
.
0"
0"
~
3
~
."nn'" ~~~ "'-'!:"l'1"l(',;:t:'- o(>n- ~=~o -;~ -~O ~;::> ",zz o0oi,,-10 Zt-..l~::tl
~ i5' 0 (\I l.nt;la:::r~~ tlfJg3;;g ~l:"l" , c "'0. ~ ~ 'g. I:"l~o >l:"ltln o ~ g l:"l
.... g: 3 ~ -< ~ 2 . 0
<~3~~c "'~.. o . o~~ ..30 )(t:l1;l~
ifa.-g ii :-' 0 'J! . N -'0- 0..... III Q
'" ~ . '"' .. '" ~.:1 I:"" c '0 I " .. '1"10.3 "'''-''' ..0. -000In"3 ~ ~.:1 .;
_..:1 => . O~~n 9' ~-J 00-
" -.:1 =>0 _. 0" _. A ... o~ g
- - _:=~g,;t-..I 5!g~ ag-:.. ~~v:~
~ ~- _ N ~ U ~ o' -"':IE :IE~
I"'l.o . - .. n ,
_. :::l N ..'" I':) Cl -l 0" ~-J n~::1~ I"'l", ~>:> [J'Ja - ~a-o I"'l% 0._ 0 $>.-
. -- ,,- .... -~" - "-I"'l ::r>$ ... __N . _. VI "';::;>0- 0 -.;
C fl ~:o t"I~..o t"l;..... :=:1.:1 >~~~ "'2 . c. g " >~ ~o:.. ~ ~~
(Jln-o :n~~~DI.:l ooo~ 0 0
>;" [~ "'CI ~.V1 =t-..IIII~ 3 >:> =~ -~~
"'CI ,,~:-.l:. 0-' ~ '" ?: 00
0 >0 :: > "';oO.g I"'l 0 '" '">0 '" ~ ~~t-..I ".
Cl n _0 p ~ ~ 0.., '" 0
. c :;. c tIl >- :;. "'~ 0
. ;; "'", ..
'\l ~ f!! e, 2 ~ .. "';;'
a- n 2> 0
0 c > ~ r> . ';2 .."
0 ~ . . :IE .....;
3 ~ tIl ii ;; :< O~
" ~ ~ 2 I"'l :IE;:
.
. >
'"> .. ?
~..,~ ~t:if:iO~F u:a~;- =1':)>(')::; nOC"H">~C" v:~~ -n>""::l-l'- O""::l-l:S;: >zo
~ 0 ~:cnooo O~=O~Ql::S Y1>~!2.;=- 0"2tl~ <o~
. 3 . ~ -r-;:l -<~::S2 ~t"l83V1 - n -<=..;~~~ ll.l~::s,<
nr"Omr(\l& t:::oo!'f1::-eg~ 0<. -.0
~l ~ . 0 "Tl2.. 3 n '" ~ 0- ~ tl> r"'"
a.l""r;j('") ~~ ~>~~ ns:::]: I z>(')"'O>>r;>-J ~1':)"'CIgry.
I O-lr:-i~ >~a!:in _. 0" = ~ .,.,- .,,500oi
.; 2 i:i >:l ~ . ~~~ _0>...<'\1_ o. _
'" ~ ~ lJ':EiT'llTl:tCllOC -€l;-N ~ =1-0 fi ~
;:;;':='l\Jol n ?:l:;tl m~. p ,,~ s ~ ~ 2~ ':<=:=2=0.:::0 ",. - n:::~~o.;-;: I"'l .'"
~ ;;"~.... .... I':) m n n" - "'CI":" _t'"'l -<~~$ :-:-.t-..I ~"'CI> ::;>V\ :0: ~~ " -
:i->o>>~;g ~>~$ Zl':)t:;~c 2::tl1':):'.""=" a o . " . I"'l
n '''' - 0_ oo>r.n 0 '" 0
oo-~ CllCC_c:ltce;.VI .. f!!~. A o>-",n- 1':)2>~.3 -'<> 2~ 3 '" .- ?
c: 0>0 !:) : Z en c' .. 0- , . >=("'}n.. 0 '" ':<i r
o ~ .. ~ a:t 'Tl::::l >>8 o ~~ €l . = .. ~ I"'l ~
- . ~ m > ;:c:l-. Stll~ noroos 21"'l ~ >
'" "I:l III _0.. I"'l .. g
, go ;:t:~~~ 0 '" n 2:1: :0: r.= . I"'l n
~ > a 0 n
'" ~ 0.. '"' '" n
~ '" ~ 2 ~ > " I"'l " P '"'
n 0 0 :0: '"'
m ~ "- 2 I"'l
0" 2 '"
. '" >
. q '"
. ..
11\ e.~~~~~ ~;;-~..;o=~~ ~.." "''''..
C\rrJ!:l c . '"
-< g.r-'(\I~ -< 8 ::l $: ~ c-1J.9. ~ ",..3 r3~r"'"
X. rrJS:::~2~r-q3 !:"l- -. ~ 3 r"'"
l:"l (\Ir-'~~ . -
:: .... oe. :c a 'J)" n Cll 0- ::Cl':)o 00"'1i
:::t- ?5 ;-'~Cll~ -~n~IJJ>=-'~ -> . ....,~)>-
I:"" ::; l:g~ QNo >=g-J p= "'rlooCC
- ~ 8"'" 2 _.' ~:.~
\1C l:"l -O=ifg 000>0 C1C"'l~::; t'"'l("';
00 ..ot"lll.l -J~ OC\O "'0 g.;go
." I l"":=' "I:l 0' 0 >-:: n 00 :I: ;:;;'003:
'"'F =: ~r""'g S [ ;~~ .. a ..
Q "2 I':)~ > . >
n > 0 '" "'2 2 ~ 2
~=~ ..", '" ~ '"
o ~ :a ~
, . >:> "
{...) ~ ~ 00
.0 ~
.,
c - ;;o;;o;;o-<>OOtD
- (1) CD CD CD =i" ~ ~ CD
- a.a.a.=r--CD=
-
- l/O-I-I~ :i"-I~
-
- :EOO Q)~.~
-
-
- :T l/O
- ""
- CD -<
-
- ~
-
- ~
-
-
-
=;;0 -I
=CD Ql
.-:J _..,)=0. .-:J ~.
=-1
-0 0
~u ~
=
~ = -I
lO - Ql
-l>o - ~.
-
.... -
-
-
-
- ~
-
- ~
-
~ - r-
- :i"
lO -
- -;
Ul - CD
N - lO
~~ >< =!
-.
;;0 ~~ 0 3
~ DI CD
lO ~ ~"C C"
Ul l/O'-:J~l/O c:
'" 0
~ ~~ 0 ~
ffi' ~~ 3 CD
0
C ~ ~~~ 'C -
lO 0 DI 0
Ul ~~'Ul :T ~ ~
Ul CD .... iii' DI
0
s: " C"
CD ~ CD III
ci3 ~ 0
~ CD ~ ~ 0
lO 0. ~~ 3
lO ~. ~ ~ iii
-l>o Ul '" 'C
:T s: s: ::r. DI
-< ~~ CD CD 0 ~
~ ~ ci3 ~
co -.
~ ~ CD CD III CD
lO "'~~ 0. 0. 2: III
lO ~ ~. ~.
'" .,. Ul~ :T :T 'C
::. III
lO ~ -< -<
Ul ~ ~
~ Ul ~ ~ 0
lO tD ~~ :;:
lO'" ~ ~
lO'" N N
0 0 (;) -
'"
Ql 0 ~ ~
C" - -
(II ~ ~
CD lO lO
N 0. lO lO
0 Ql .,. .,.
0'"
NUl ::J
0.
3
CD
~
co
tl\ CD
0.
~.
X :T
we tD
~
0
Ql
... C"
"f
,
, ~:. 'l
c
the rates or fares established and authorized by the Bureau (Ord 1987 918 1953 i
5.76.260 Rates to be displayed.
Every vehicle used or operated under this Chapter shall. at all times. have
displayed therein. in a location and manner approved by the Bureau the rates to be
charged for such service. and which rates shall always be visible (Ord. 2078 (part)
1955.0rd 1987919 1953)
5.76.270 Refusal to pay fare.
It IS unlawful for any person to refuse to pay the authOrized fare of any of the
vehicles mentioned ILl this Chapter after having employed the same. and it is unlawful
for any person to hire any vehicle defined in Section 5.76.020 with intent to defraud
the person from whom it IS hired or engaged, of the value of such service (Ord. 1987
920, 1953)
5.76.280 Drivers.
A
c
c
Vehicles covered by this Chapter shall be operated only by the carrier. if a
person, or by a person employed by the carrier, or by a person authorized by
lease, contract or other arrangement, with a carrier to operate a vehicle
undersuch carrier's permit; each such authorized person shall be subject to
and comply with all the applicable provisions of this Chapter, and no carrier
shall impose upon such person any contractual terms or conditions
inconsistent with those set forth in this Chapter. If the applicant is not an
employee, the proposed arrangement; contract; or lease under which such
authority IS to be exercised shall be submitted in writing to the secretary of the
Bureau. The secretary of the Bureau shall. after he has conducted or caused
to be conducted such review and investigation as he deems necessary,
approve or reject the proposed arrangement, contract or lease and shall
communicate his decision to the applicant within ten days after the proposed
arrangement. contract. or lease has been submitted If the secretary of the
Bureau fails to communicate an adverse decision to the applicant within ten
days after the proposed arrangement. contract. or lease has been submitted,
it shall be deemed rejected If the secretary of the Bureau rejects the proposed
arrangement, contract, or lease. the applicant may request in writing a hearing
before the Bureau The request for a hearing shall be submitted to the
secretary of the Bureau within five days after the decision of the secretary of
the Bureau has been communicated to the applicant. The secretary of the
Bureau shall promptly notify the applicant of the time and place of the hearing
which shall not be more than thirty days after the request for hearing has been
submitted The hearing shall be conducted informally pursuant to rules of the
Bureau. The decision of the Bureau shall be final. No arrangement. contract
or lease shall be approved if any of the terms thereof are not In conformity with
the provISions of this Chapter.
B
Such approval may be withdrawn by the Bureau by the mailing of a ten-day
notice of intention to the carrier and the driver. subject to the right to request
a hearing under the same procedures and standards for the original approval.
This provision permitting the withdrawal of approval shall he deemed to be a
part of each such arrangement; contract or lease when so approved and
5-126
[Rev October 10. 2001]
".J .1 ,,"t:
c
neither the carrier nor the driver shall have any legal recourse or right of action
arising out of such withdrawal of approvai
/
( C /
......---
A person authorized to operate under carrier's permit by arrangement. contract
or lease shall be deemed to be an independent contractor and shall obtain a
City business license
3877 S1 1979 Ord 3585 (part) 1976.0rd 2154 (part), 1957 Ord 1987 S21, 1953.)
(Ord
5.76.290 Investigation of drivers.
A. The Chief of Police shall conduct an investigation concerning the background,
conduct. behavior, and character of any applicant io drive a vehicle under a
carrier's permit or of any driver while operating a vehicle under a carrier's
permit in order to present facts or information to aid the secretary in
determining whether the prospective or cO[ltinued operation of a vehicle by a
driver would be detrimental to the health, safety, peace, general welfare, good
morals or con'lenience of the public.
B. The investigation report shall be forwarded to the secretary of the Bureau, and
he may utilize the report to determine whether to approve or reject an
arrangement, contract or lease relating to an applicant or whether such
approval should be withdrawn pursuant to Section 5.75280.
(Ord 3877 S2,1979: Ord. 3585 (part). 1976, Ord. 1987 S22, 1953)
No permit shall be granted to any carrier to operate any vehicle covered by this
Chapter whose color scheme, name. trade name, monogram or insignia shall be in
conflict with, or in imitation of. any color scheme, name, trade name, monogram or
insignia used by any other carrier as defined in Section 5.76020, and which shall be
of such character and nature as to be misleading or deceptive to the public. (Ord 1987
S26 1953)
5.76.310 Identity lights.
1~~W
c
5.76.300 Identification of vehicles.
Every taxicab shall be equipped with an identity light attached to the top of
such taxicab. The identity light shall be constructed in one unit consisting of an
illuminated plate or cylinder upon which is printed the words "For Hire," or as approved
by the Bureau. The overall dimensions of such identity light shall not exceed six inches
in height by twenty inches in length The lights of the identity light unit shall be
operated manually to illuminate the identity light when the taximeter is not in operation,
indicating the cab is vacant and for hire, and to extinguish the identity light when the
taximeter is in operation It is unlawful to drive or operate any taxicab with such identity
light illuminated while carrying passengers for compensation, and it is unlawful to
drive, operate or be in charge of, any taxicab unless such identity light is illuminated
when such taxicab ;5 for hire None of the foregOing provisions requiring the identity
light to be illuminated shall apply during daylight hours (Ord. 2154 (part). 1957; Ord.
1987 S27, 1953.)
c
5.76.320 Route - Passenger limit in taxicabs.
A. Every driver of a taxicab who is engaged to carry passengers shall take the
most direct route possible that will carry the passengers safely and
[Rev October 10, 2001]
5-127
c
neither the carrier nor the driver shall have any legal recourse or right of action
arising out of such withdrawal of approval
C
A person authorized to operate under carrier's permit by arrangement, contract
or lease shall be deemed to be an independent contractor and shall obtain a
City business license.
3877 911979: Ord. 3585 (part). 1976. Ord 2154 (part), 1957: Ord 1987921,1953)
(Ord
5.76.290 Investigation of drivers.
A The Chief of Police shall conduct an investigation concerning the background,
conduct. behavior, and character of any applicant \0 drive a vehicle under a
. carrier's permit or of any driver while operating a vehicle under a carrier's
permit in order to present facts or information to aid the secretary in
determining whether the prospective or cOfltinued operation of a vehicle by a
driver would be detrimental to the health, safety, peace, general welfare, good
morals or con'lenience of the public.
B. The investigation report shall be forwarded to the secretary of the Bureau, and
he may utilize the report to determine whether to approve or reject an
arrangement, contract or lease relating to an applicant or whether such
approval should be withdrawn pursuant to Section 5.76.280.
(Ord. 3877 92,1979: Ord. 3585 (part), 1976: Ord. 1987922,1953.)
c
5.76.300 Identification of vehicles.
No permit shall be granted to any carrier to operate any vehicle covered by this
Chapter whose color scheme, .name. trade name, monogram or insignia shall be in
conflict with, or in imitation of. any color scheme, name, trade name, monogram or
insignia used by any other carrier as defined in Section 5.76.020. and which shall be
of such character and nature as to be misleading or deceptive to the public. (Ord. 1987
926,1953.)
5.76.310 Identity lights.
Every taxicab shall be equipped with an identity light attached to the top of
such taxicab. The identity light shall be constructed in one unit consisting of an
illuminated plate or cylinder upon which is printed the words "For Hire," or as approved
by the Bureau. The overall dimensions of such identity light shall not exceed six inches
in height by twenty inches in length. The lights of the identity light unit shall be
operated manually to illuminate the identity light when the taximeter is not in operation,
indicating the cab is vacant and for hire, and to extinguish the identity light when the
taximeter IS in operation. It is unlawful to drive or operate any taxicab with such identity
light illuminated while carrying passengers for compensation, and it is unlawful to
drive, operate or be in charge of, any taxicab unless such identity light is illuminated
when such taxicab ;l, for hire None of the foregoing provisions requiring the identity
light to be illuminated shall apply during daylight hours. (Ord. 2154 (part), 1957: Ord.
1987927,1953.)
c
5.76.320 Route - Passenger limit in taxicabs.
A. Every driver of a taxicab who is engaged to carry passengers shall take the
most direct route possible that will carry the passengers safely and
[Rev October 10, 2001]
5-127
-
, .1 ..
:f::rl:-p
/1..
c
c
c
To:
From:
Subject:
Date:
Copies:
City of San Bernardino
San Bernardino Police Department
Interoffice Memorandum
Lee Gagnon, Business Registration Supervisor
Robert 1. Goss, ID Bureau Supervisor
".,.J
1":1,
Taxi Cab Permit Application For: DOMINQUEZ, Andres
January 31, 2000
The Police Department has completed an investigation concerning the background, conduct,
behavior, and character of the above applicant.
x
The Department does not recommend the application be rejected or previous
temporary approval be withdrawn.
The Department recommends the applicant be rejected,
The Department recommends the previous approval be withdrawn.
The Department recommends the previous temporary approval be withdrawn.
THE SBPD IS COM1\ImED TO PROVIDING:
PROGRESSIVE QUALm' POLICE SERVICE;
A SAFE ENVlRONMENTTO IMPROVE THE QUALITY OF LIFE;
A REDUCTION IN CRIME THROUGH PROBLEM RECOGNITION ..'ND PROBLEM SOLVING
,
J . J . L U-
C CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO - REQUEST FOR COUNCIL ACTION
o
c
From: Rachel Clark, City Clerk
Subject:
Appeal of the Bureau of Franchises'
denial of a Petition for Franchise Permit
for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate
25 taxicabs in the City of San
Bemardino
MICC Meeting Date: 7/15/02
Dept: City Clerk
Date: July 8, 2002
Synopsis of Previous Council Action:
None
Recommended Motion:
Motion #1: That the hearing be closed, and the Mayor and Common Council uphold
the Bureau of Franchises' denial of a Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland
Empire Cab to operate 25 taxicabs in the City of San Bemardino.
Or
Motion #2: That the hearing be closed, and the Mayor and Common Council grant the
appeal for a Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate 25
taxicabs in the City of San Bernardino.
'ae~>If. Cl~
Signature
Contact person:
Phnne:
Supporting data attached: Yes
Ward: All
FUNDING REQUIREMENTS: Amount: N/A
Source: (Acct. No.)
(A,..,..t np.~rriptinn)
Finance:
Council Notes:
g/f9/0J-
d.~
Agenda Item No. _
c
c
c
CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO - REQUEST FOR COUNCIL ACTION
Staff Report
Subject:
Appeal of the Bureau of Franchises denial of a Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA
Inland Empire Cab to operate 2S taxicabs in the City of San Bernardino.
Applicant: J.K.S.O., Inc.
DBA, AAA Inland Empire Cab
3000 Date Street
Riverside, CA 92507
(909) 369-5581
Patrick Pashkam, Chief Executive Officer
Background:
A Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab was previously denied by the
Bureau of Franchises and a letter sent dated January 10, 2002 to the owners of AAA Inland
Empire Cab notifying them of that fact. AAA Inland Empire Cab did not file an appeal of
the decision but elected to re-submit their application based upon new information. On
April 3, 2002, a new application fee was paid by AAA Inland Empire Cab.
On June 11, 2002, the Bureau of Franchises considered the new application submitted by
AAA Inland Empire Cab. After presentations by both AAA Inland Empire Cab,
BelllYellow Cab (existing taxi cab service), and discussion from the Board Members
regarding whether there exists a public convenience and necessity for additional cab
service, a motion to deny the Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab
carried on a 4-2 vote. Board Members Cole, Turner, Shultz and Carson voted in favor of
the motion to deny; Members Fernandez and Martindale voted against the motion.
Financial Impact:
None
c
c
c
Recommendation:
That the Mayor and Common Council uphold the Bureau of Franchises' denialofthe
Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate 25 taxi cabs in the
City of San Bernardino.
Or
That the hearing be closed, and the mayor and Common Council grant the appeal for a
Petition for Franchise Permit for AAA Inland Empire Cab to operate 25 taxicabs in the
City of San Bernardino.
c
c
o
,JUL-U.c::.-t::,UUc:. IUC. U'i'l" rll rUL.LCl\lvn 1..1,;.1101111 1:.1 m..
Illn l\V. vvv UUU V~l\'/
L^w Q,.rl:::E':O
FULLERTON, ~EMANN, St:HAEFER 05< Iii~V~l6en4L~Ff'K
ANNtrT': g~el!\.\.Li-LU!\.LE
T~IOM^~ w. nn,..INICK
WI~;nll:;) c;:, ,""1..""1!\.Nr..
G:~l LtJPfl. .JA
""11::~,.t:1.. (< !".~HA.l!:nLI'l:
1.'~AIIS IE. WI\....HJN
215NOR'1f1 D :;':TREET. ,.,JO:IiiT n.QCR
~AN I56.RNA.ADINC. CAI-,f"CRNtA ~a~1.1712
TF.l r:,....ONlE f'\il~')l ""l:J-3ti' 1 W' Jl-2
rAce'''''L!: 101]1)1 ..tI..~ I 1 ?
F'IAM wE~SITC: WWW.INLANODUSINE~SLAW.COM
Of" cou..:;;r;..
RDUf.RT V. "Ul..~t:ftru:-.:
P 5 :, [1"..'::.;:.:.'0....... !;:O"'.I'l....,.,~..
po....... DIEDelllT Or-r.ce:
_..lie r.,.""T,."
??SG4.A l.;:OUNTAV CLUJ.: e,l.
"UlTt 1 SO
......."" DIlIlE"T. CA .,:2' 1
1'/(;0) 77?-'j!:l7Z
FACSIMILE TRANSMISSION
Date; J lily 2, 2002
Numher of Pages; 2
[Including this Page]
Time:
~."~
File /I 01-802
A.M@
Destination Phone 1t 384-5302
Destination Fax # 384-5158
TO:
Roger Davis
Sarah Adams
Bell Cab & Yellow Cab of San Bcrnardhlo
() Please sign transmitted documents and retulll them by l'ax.
() for your information.
(X) In accordance with YOllr request.
() Other:
Attached find request for eontinllanee ofthe hearing set for July IS\h A hard copy of the
document will be delivered via courier. If any further documentation is needed, please contact
Ill" directly.
FROM:
RE:
Non.: It" YOU DID NOT RF.t:lilvt AJ.L Of TilE rAGES IN U:G1BU: fORM, PI.EASt.: CALL CINDV AT (9091 889-
3691IMMF.DIATELV.
..... .----
...:. ---- ..... -.-
CONFIDENTIALITY NOTICE
Thl.:' lkK;Urtll.~nb 'DC'i'<.'ln"t'i'tnyinQ thi:l tclCl:;Op1Cr If'AX) tr~n$rni:ij:ic)n c;.:lftlllin conri,!..:mitll inrUnlhilil)n b\:kmsin@'lv tlse sender which is Icg:.all)' privilc~cJ
riu: inrolnt\\iOll \$ j"lcrukd only filf l~ use ofthc lnchvidual urenlilY a~nlCd ahuvt:. lfyou are flot'~ inMld..::d recTicn!.,)'Qu :ue hct\iby nolitil.~ ~l
ilTI) clisclOlilTrc;. cap)"ing;. dD1rl\'outioll (II' tho: bkinl of allY o.ctiOl1 ill rdi:sncc on tbo CC'lnrenPl Of1hi$ ~lctopic~ jnformluion is ~ftjf.1l,)i pmbilUu;cl. If)'t.)\\
M.~I~I\'..:d Ihii tcl,,",uPY ill error. rlc~l.~ imrrwcJi<&\ely call1hc s..:nd..:r t2lli,;.'CJ 10 iUron~.c fnr the: n:l\ll\l of rIle t~h:copil,.-d cWt~lmCnl-..
o
c
c
JUL-U~-~UU~ JUt Uq; j~ rn rULLtI\JUl't Ltntmt~ t, HL
rnr:. !'tv. VUV UUO .J! 1"
i..^W OFF1CE~
F"ULI.I::RTON, LEMANN, SCHAEf"ER & DOMINICK, LLP
MoINCTTE o,:IIF.ll.[~\"wl\..I..E
T...CTMo1I.~..... OUt.1IN.1C~
Wl1..rl~'U t,;. ~t:""'I"~""N
M1CIIA.EL. n. SC,",^c."l:.A
Cr:lAIO F: W':...",OI'O
4: ,::. tlCRTI-l 0 C.ff-cI.:.L:.1'. FIRn r'-OD~
SAN 8CRNAROINC. CALIFORNIA .,2401.1712
TCLI!:PIU,JNE (OOtll .A"'3c;.P,
"AC:l'Jw\n.1" {?IJ'ill UUl;f.~' llJ
F"IRM YlE!5SITE: WWW.INLANOBU9IN.G:~.LAW.eOM
c-M:ail: blC:l'l~nll@jnlanclbul'iltC.~"bw,com
July 2, 2002
VIA FACSIMILE & llAND DEI.IVERY
Mayor Judilh Valles & Common Council
Office of the City Ckrk
City of San Bernardino
300 NOl1h "D" Slreet
Sanllernardino, CA 92418
1. Vl...
0.. Cl.:U.....-:C..
ROI,h.Jo,Ir v. 'UL.LEr..ro"'l'
.~ "'(C1.t.:~IC.U'~ e~"Ilo"'f"l,g..
"""'L'" Ct:e;c..,. n""tec
~",.(1 cc:......c.
'7'75601-1\. COUNIICY C\.un O.
t\'JITC 1 ~D
pM,.... DC:~".T, C... 92:11
I'7GOI """'9S'/~
Re: Appeal oflhe Decision of the Bureau of Franchises in regard to the Application of AAA
Itlland Empire Cab
Dear Mayor Valles and Council Members:
As you may be aware, our liml is counsel to Bell Cab & Yellow Cab of San Bernardino in tllc above-
referenccd matter.
This leller shall serve as our request for a conlinuance of the hearing set for July IS, 2002. Mr. ScOll
Schaffer, corporato representative for our c1icnt, has a Publie Utilities Commission matter and will be
ull~vailablc on June 151h.
tv! r. SchaIrer's pal1icipation is absolutely necessary.
Accordingly, because of the unavailability of Mr. Schaffer, we requcst the matter be continued unlil
the next meeling date.
We look forward to hearing from you.
Very truly yours,
FULLERTON, LEMANN,
SCHAEFER & DOMINICK, LLP
Wilmtt2
WCL:sda
07/10/2002 12:39 FAX 7930790
lIEeR
ItWVVJ.
c)
IOllN K. MlIlAI1-
MARK C. E!)WAADS
ROIiIiJlT w, CANNON+
STANLEY ^' HAllTEk'
MlCIlA&.J. Lf:WIN
Law Offices of
Mirau, Edwards, Cannon,
Harter & Lewin
A Professio1l41 COlpOration
Temeeula Office
41690 EnlCrpri..
Cln:le
Suitc214
TcmecuJa, CA 92590
. Cenlft$t s,.iaIi1l.. T..ooo
Law. tMS,*oIC11ifam.
BoInIofl.fplSpeclal.bulon
0"",,","_-
~ 'tNG 0IId'10111~
t-. The $we..... oro.liimli~
BoanlofLeplSpecia6aricm
1806 Onnge Tree Lane, Suite C
Redlands, CA 92374
(909) 793-0200
(909) 793-0790 (Fax)
Rlverilde omce
3880 1.mlon AvtI1ue
Suite 430
RivenidlC. CA 92501
File No. A2066-00l
~ :;g
m
("')
rn
~ <:
j"r'1
u
- i
(;) Q
-I
"'0 -.::
- n
r-
~ m
x
:T.
FACSIMILE COVER LETTER
DATE;
July 10, 2002
FROM;
Mark C. Edwards, Esq.
PLEASE DELIVER THE FOLLOWING PAGES TO:
NAME:
Cindy Buechter
c
FIRM:
San Bernardino City Clerk - Business Registration
CITY, STATE:
FAX NUMBER:
San Bernardino, CA
OFFICE NUMBER:
(909) 384-5158
(909) 384-5159
ITEM(S) SENT:
7/10/02 correspondence re: AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
Appeal
TOTAL NUMBER OF PAGES (Including Cover Letter): 3
PLEASE PHONE (909) 793-0200 IF YOU DO NOT RECEIVE ALL OF THE PAGES.48 SOON AS
POSSIBLE.
TBIS MiSSAGE IS INTENDED ONt Y FOR THE USE OF THE INDIVIDUAL OR ENTITY TO WHICH IT
IS ADDRESSED, AND MAY CONTAIN INFORMATION THAT IS PRIVILEGED, CONl'lDENTIAL AND
EXEMPT FROM DISCLOSmu: UNDER APPLICABLE LAw. IF THE READER OJ' THIS MESSAGE IS
NOT THE INTENDED RECIPIENT, OR THE EMPLOYEE OR AGENT RESPONSIBLE FOR
DEUVl:RING THE Ml:SSAGE TO THE INTENDED RECIPIENT, YOU ARE HEREBY NOJulIW THAT
ANY DISSEMINATION, DJSTRlBUTlON OR COPYING OF THIS COMMUNICATION IS STRICTLY
PROHIBITl:D. IF YOU BAYt: RECEIVED THIS COMMUNICATION IN ERROR, I'LEASE NOTIFY US
IMMEDIATELY BY TELEPHONE, AND RETURN THE ORIGINAL MESSAGE TO US VIA AIR MAlL.
THANK YOU.
c
lIo.2Q
7/75"1 DO-
07/10/2002 12:40 FAX 79J0790
Mt.....J1
't!:lVV_
, JOlIN K. MIRAU"
MARK C. EOWIJUlS
R.oBERT Ill. CANNONT
STANUY A, HARTER'
OCIIA~J.l LEWIN
.ClrUJ'"oe.I~..,l'aItIon
1.-.T1w:"-Dv.tCofi~
,..,..tt.....~
'l'Cl:l.ur_SpoD.I....~
~TI\IIIl_'''''''''
lA>ot'DoS-..."fOllIRlr....
....."rl"'Pr5torc~..........
'. lA~!d:i~'F1c:;:1!S. c::)F
" .' <.~" :,:.,..~.,-- l~~:rJ~ ~
'MIRAU, EDWAIIDSif;ANNON, HARrER II LEwIN i~-;;~ bzl!.'Z
, '..' -',' "",,\\/!
A PRCIlFeS.s..o.;:";"_~:t _CORPOR.AYION
',.,
t 806 Orange l'rcc: tane. Suit~ C
Redlands. CA 9237'
wleph....: (909) 79H1200
facsimile: (909) 793.o790
mcdwazdt@m<eh1a>v,com
July 10, 2002
A2066-001
Delivered via FaesimiJe and U.S. Mail
Honorable Mayor Judith Valles
Members of the Common Council
City of San Bernardino
c/o Cindy Buechter
Office ofthe City Clerk
300 North "D" Street
SaIJ Bernardino CA 92401
c
Re: Appeal of AAA Inland Empire Cab Company; Request for Hearing Delay
Dear Mayor Valles and Members ofthe Council:
The undersigned represents AAA Inland Empire Cab Compauy. The City kindly
provided, yesterday, a copy of the faxed correspondence from Bill Lemann. attorney for Bell
Cab/Yellow Cab requesting a delay in the appeal hearing set for next Monday, July 15th,
AAA Inland Empire Cab company respectfully disagrees with Mr. Lemann's conclusion
that a delay is appropriate. We do so for two reasons. First, Bell CablYellow Cab is not a party
to this appeal. Pursuant to City Code section 2.64.070, the party to present any opposition to
AM Inland Empire Cab Company's appeal is the "department, agency, City officer, official or
department head whose action is being considered..."
While we are sure that Bell Cab/Y ellow Cab will want to comment on the appeal, if Mr.
Schaffer is unable to attend, Mr. Lemann is an extremely articulate and informed representative
for his client and was present at the Franchise Bureau meeting where the appealed froUl action
was taken.
Additionally, Mr. Lemann's letter cites a conflict with a Public Utilities Commission
matter as the reason for Mr. Schaffer's unavailability. We note that the PUC meeting for the
month is not scheduled until July 17th, two days after the appeal hearing.
c
c'
c
c
07/10/2002 12:40 FAX 79J0790
lIEeK
'Wuu""
July to, 2002
Page 2
AM Inland Empire Cab Company respectfully requests that the appeal hearing be held
as scheduled. In the event, however, that the Mayor and Council detennine that additional time
is necessary before the hearing, we will of course be prepared to present our appeal at the next
regularly scheduled Council meeting.
Very truly yours,
MIRAU. EDWARDS, CANNON,
HARTER & LEWIN
A Professional Corporation,
Al20491C011_lloIIcr.OOl
Inland Empire Cab Company
~
C1
c
c
Statement of AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
To The City of San Bernardino Common Council
in Appeal of the Decision of the San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
July 15,2002
Introduction
This is an appeal from the action of the City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
denying, by a 4-2 vote, a franchise for AAA Inland Empire Cab Company to operate as the
second taxicab company in the City. The appeal is on two grounds. First, AAA Inland Empire
Cab Company believes that the decision of the Franchise Bureau was based on false and
misleading information provided to the Bureau by the current City monopoly operator, Bell
Cab/Y ellow Cab. Second, AAA Inland Empire Cab Company believes that in making its
decision, the Franchise Bureau applied the wrong standard in determining whether "public
convenience and necessity" required issuing a permit to AAA Inland Empire Cab Company.
In a less legalistic sense, however, this appeal is about a more fundamental issue. This
appeal is about the right of the residents of, and visitors to, the City of San Bernardino to have
better and less expensive taxicab service. The alternative is to continue to be stuck with a single
monopolistic cab company, which "serves" the City with a fraction of the cabs permitted by City
code and its franchise, keeping service quality low and prices high. There is an alternative:
competition. Competition is at the very heart of our economic system for a simple reason, It
works. It allows the market to assure that quality is high and cost is low. As an immediate
example of the benefits of competition, AAA Inland Empire Cab Company is specifically
undertaking, if its franchise request is granted, that it be approved for rates lower than those
currently charged in San Bernardino.
San Bernardino Taxi Service
To put the current appeal in perspective, a short history oftaxi service in San Bernardino
is in order. For years, San Bernardino was served by a number of taxicab companies, many of
whom were small operators who, in order to compete, would provide high levels of personal
service. Over the years, these small operators were swallowed by the ''big fish" in the pond,
Yellow Cab Company. In September of 1998, a new taxicab company came to San Bernardino,
Bell Cab Company, and applied for a franchise. In its presentation to the City, Bell Cab touted
the advantages of competition, and cited the need for expanded taxicab service. In response, the
City Franchise Bureau granted Bell Cab its requested franchise. Within a few short months, Bell
Cab eliminated the very competition it promised the City by buying Yellow Cab. Since that
time, the combined Bell Cab/Y ellow Cab has enjoyed a monopoly in the City of San Bernardino
while, as will be shown below, operating an extremely limited number of taxis in the City. In
other words, while the City was promised competition and a higher level of service, what it was
given was a monopoly, with a lowered level of service.
The Current Level of Service-False Information Presented to Bureau
As you will see from the transcript of AAA Inland Empire Cab Company's presentation
to the Franchise Bureau, at Exhibit "A," one assertion of AAA Inland Empire Cab Company was
that, despite the City Code permitting the operation of 74 taxicabs in the City and despite the fact
that the current monopoly holder, Bell Cab/Y ellow Cab, has a franchise to operate 45 taxicabs in
.:It ~5"
?J /rri/6 2-
~
o
c
c'
City of San Bernardino Common Council
Page 2
San Bernardino, Bell CabNellow Cab can operate no more than 12 total cabs (averaging less
than 5 at anyone time). This is because only 19 persons are licensed to operate taxicabs in the
City, and of those 19,7 no longer work for Bell CabNellow Cab (five currently work for AAA
Inland Empire Cab Company in other cities. At the Franchise Bureau meeting, Bell CabN ellow
Cab specifically denied that assertion (despite the fact that the number of licensed drivers came
from the City Clerk's records). In response to a series of questions which followed from Bureau
members, specifically asking how many taxis Bell CabN ellow Cab ran in the City of San
Bernardino, representatives of Bell Cab/ Yellow Cab specifically stated that it had mnning, in the
City of San Bernardino, no less than 30 and up to 45 cabs during the day, and between 25 and 30
cabs at night. That assertion, material, we believe, to the determination of the Franchise Bureau,
was untrue. Indeed, the number of licensed drivers working for Bell CabN ellow Cab as
presented to the Franchise Bureau by AAA Inland Empire Cab Company was correct. At
Exhibit "B" you will find a copy of the City Clerk's print-out, showing each and every person
licensed to operate taxis in the City. Only those licensees who have no date in the colunm
marked "close date" have a current license (those are highlighted). You will see from counting
that there are, despite the denials by Bell CabN ellow Cab, only 19 licensed taxicab drivers in the
City. Additionally, of those 19, seven (those marked with a red asterisk) no longer work for Bell
CabNellow Cab. In other words, despite Bell CabNellow Cab's representations to the
Franchise Bureau, if Bell CabN ellow Cab had every one of its drivers working at the same time,
it could place only 12 cabs on the street at anyone time, not the 45 it represented to the Bureau.
What is even more shocking is that if Bell CabNellow Cab's drivers work five eight hour work
days, Bell CabN ellow Cab can, on the average dispatch fewer than jive cabs to riders in the City
of San Bernardino at anyone time!
This current situation is unacceptable because it results, as the studies described below
prove, in poor service and higher cost. Additionally, it is exactly the opposite of what the City
was promised when Bell Cab was granted its franchise in 1998: better and expanded service.
And lest you think that this low level of service is an aberration, we invite you to look at
Exhibit "C" where, once again based on the City Clerk's records, we have counted the number of
licensed taxi drivers at each January 1 st and June 1st through the period that Bell CabN ellow Cab
has held its monopoly. You will see that the current number is not only not an aberration, but is
actually an historic high! On an average, since the purchase of Yellow Cab by Bell Cab
eliminated the positive effects of competition, the combined Bell CabN ellow Cab has had fewer
than 12 drivers it could dispatch in the City.
Who does this lack of competition hurt? Those who have no choice but to use a taxi for
transportation. In a city like San Bernardino, where tourism is not a large industry, that means
the poor, the elderly, and the disabled. One can hardly think of groups more deserving of the
simple assistance this Council can provide by introducing competition back into the taxicab
industry.
o
c
c
City of San Bernardino Common Council
Page 3
Erroneous Legal Standard
The City Code contains a number of factors to consider in making the determination
whether the 'public necessity and convenience" dictate granting a franchise. Those factors, at
section 5.76.050 of the City Code are: "the public demand for such service, the adequacy or
inadequacy of service being offered by other carriers, the effect of such service upon traffic, the
financial responsibility of the applicant, the amount of wages to be paid to employees, the
character of equipment proposed to be furnished, and any other facts which the Bureau may
deem relevant."
Statements made by the members of the Franchise Bureau, when discussion was held and
a vote was taken on the application of AAA Inland Empire Cab Company, indicate that the
Bureau members focused on and believed that they needed, in order to grant the franchise, to
find one thing: that a second taxicab company in the City was indispensable; that, in essence,
taxi users in San Bernardino could not obtain service from the single franchise holder. In
making its determination, therefore, we believe the Franchise Bureau too narrowly considered
the factors set forth in the City Code and applied too strict a standard in making its finding.
"Public necessity and convenience" is a common standard applied, throughout California
and the country, in granting franchises. For that reason, the courts have interpreted the standard,
and have found that the standard is far less strict than the Franchise Bureau seems to have
concluded. In San Diego & Coronado Ferry Company v. Railroad Commission of California the
California Supreme Court described the standard of "public necessity and convenience" as
follows:
''Necessity must be taken in a relative sense....The word necessity is not
used in its lexicographical sense of 'indispensably requisite." If it were, no
certificate of public necessity or convenience could ever be granted. . . .Any
improvement which is highly important to the public convenience and desirable
for the public welfare may be regarded as necessary."
Our 2nd District Court of Appeals, in Luxor Cab Company v. Cahill described the
standard as follows:
"Public convenience and necessity has been defined as a public matter,
without which the public is inconvenienced to the extent of being handicapped in
the practice of business or wholesome pleasure or both, . .. Public necessity does
not mean indispensable to the public, but an urgency less pressing."
In our presentation to the Franchise Bureau (reproduced at Exhibit "A") AAA Inland
Empire Cab Company demonstrated that the factors set forth in the City Code are served by
granting a franchise. We showed that competition will produce a higher level of service, lower
cost of service, increased driver earnings, and increased ridership. This is not the bare assertion
of AAA Inland Empire Cab Company, but the finding of study after study after study by other
cities, by universities, and by independent think-tanks. Due to the volume, we have not
c
c
c
City of San Bernardino Common Council
Page 4
reproduced all of the studies presented at the Franchise Bureau meeting for each member of this
Council, but have instead provided a single copy of those studies to the City Clerk for reference
by the Council Members, should they desire to read them. A list of those studies is included as
Exhibit "D," as is a copy of the single study focusing on taxi service in the Inland Empire, that
of respected local economist John Husing.
We have also shown that the results of a monopoly predicted in those studies, poor
service at high costs, are being experienced in San Bernardino. We have included as Exhibit "E"
some of the written statements of members of the San Bernardino community who have first-
hand knowledge of the fact that the current monopoly is producing poor taxi service, at high cost.
San Bernardino taxi users, especially the poor, disabled and elderly, are suffering poor
service at high cost as a result of the current monopoly. Remedying that situation by the re-
introduction of competition is a matter of public necessity and convenience which warrants this
Council acting to grant the requested franchise.
The City deserves what Bell Cab promised in 1998, competition and a higher level of
service. To quote Scott Schaeffer of Bell Cab/Y ellow Cab:
''Bell Cab Company is not a supporter of market deregulation but strongly
opposes monopolies that result in lower levels of service, minimal marketing
and lead to hostage pricing by service companies and taxicab operators.
Reasonable levels of competition lead to higher levels of service, stable consumer
prices, better accessibility to taxicabs and availability at all times of day."
(emphasis added)
Lower Cost for Riders
In 1998 Bell Cab promised the benefits of competition, then eliminated that competition.
AAA Inland Empire cab Company intends to see that the benefits of competition actua1ly come
to the residents of San Bernardino. Therefore, AAA Inland Empire Cab Company will, if
granted the requested franchise, charge a rate that is 10 tents lower per flag drop and 10 cents
lower per mile than the current maximum rate permitted in the City and is charged by the current
franchise holder. Additionally, AAA Inland Empire Cab Company will offer a 15% discount to
seniors and to the disabled.
hiefExecutive Officer
AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
o
o
o
JOHN K. MlRAU'
- MARK C. EDWARDS
ROBERT W. CANNON!
~~y A. HARTER'
~L J. LEWIN
.Ct:rtifiDdSpcc....lUIlion
L..w,TbeSl*BarotCalifomiro
lbldofLeplSpccia/iulian
tQo1lf"lIdSpecialilt,1!aIe
~TnIIlIlldProbMe
Law,Tbe State Bar ofCalifornja
BoIrdofLepl~iZlIlion
1806 Orange Tree Lane, Suite C
Redlands. CA 92374
telephone: (909) 793-0200
facsimile: (909) 793-0790
medwards@mechlaw.com
Presentation of Mark C. Edwards
Attorney for AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
To The City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
June 11,2002
Today, I am charged with demonstrating, and you are charged with determining, if ''the
public convenience and necessity" is serYed by permitting a second taxi cab company to operate
in the City of San Bernardino. The alternative is to permit the current monopoly to continue.
c
At first blush, neither of us has an easy job. Look what has happened so far. My client,
AAA Cab, has presented to this Bureau a stack of statements from individuals and businesses
citing the poor quality of the current serYice. The holder of the current monopoly, Bell
Cab/Y ellow Cab, in response, has presented its own statements, asserting that service is fine.
Who do you believe? Is it enough for your finding that we have demonstrated a significant
portion of the population is dissatisfied with the current level and quality of service?
Bell Cab/Y ellow Cab, on the other hand, would have you believe that you should look at
the lack of complaints to this Bureau. Were there a formal mechanism for riders to make such a
complaint, as there is in other cities, we might agree. However, if you get into a BelllY ellow
cab, there is NO sign or other indication as to how to contact this Bureau or any other person or
agency of the City. Further, in the City telephone listing, this Bureau is not listed, nor is there
any listing under taxi or taxi regulation. Call City Hall, and the operators have no idea who is
responsible for taxi service regulation. The only indication, in a BelllY ellow cab, as to who to
complain about bad taxi serYice is in small letters at the bottom of a 4 inch by 4 inch rate sticker
which says "Inquiries or complaints should be addressed to Yellow Cab at (909) 884-6100." So
we really don't know how many complaints there are, and the fact is, as things now stand, it
doesn't really matter. As long as BelllYellow Cab remains the only game in town, riders have
no choice but to accept the level of serYice offered (or not use taxi service) and BelllY ellow Cab
has no incentive to address riders' complaints.
c
So we have competing citizen statements and no way to know how many complaints
there are. How do you make the determination you are charged with making? Fortunately, we
have two other things. First, we have study after study after study demonstrating that quality of
serYice decreases, and the cost of serYice increases, when there is no competition. Conversely,
.
c
c
G
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 2
these studies clearly demonstrate that the quality of service increases, the cost of services
decreases, and ridership increases when there is competition in the taxicab market. These are
not the competing positions of AAA Cab and BelVY ellow cab, these are independent studies by
governmental agencies, universities, and think tanks throughout the nation that concluded one
thing: If you want better taxi service, introduce competition. I have included a number of those
studies in the materials I've given you today, and I will refer to them throughout my
presentation. I've also included a study by local economist John Husing, who points out the
advantages of competition in the taxicab industry specifically in the Cities of San Bernardino and
Riverside. That study is located at Tab 1.
Second, we have our common sense. I could bring you reams of economic treatises
proving, through mathematical models, that competition lowers costs and increases the quality of
service. But you already know that. Common sense tells us that. And it is a fundamental
principal of the entire American economic system. If you don't like the lunch salad you get at
T.G.I. Fridays today, you can go to Chili's tomorrow. And after a fair number of Friday's
customers do that, Fridays is going to improve their food. If they don't, they won't survive. If,
however, through some bizarre regulation, there were only one place you could go to get lunch,
what incentive would that restaurant have to improve food or service?
So let us turn to the independent studies. These are located at tabs two (2) through
thirteen (13) of the materials I've provided to you.
BelVY ellow Cab would have you believe, from the materials they have submitted to you
that the current system of regulating entry into the taxi-cab business was born of a need to
protect the quality of service. That is untrue. In fact, the Federal Trade Commission found that
the genesis of these restrictions came in the great Depression, when out of work individuals
turned to operating their cars as taxis to survive. As a result, the large cab companies sought to
protect their monopolies. The FTC found that the drive for regulation had nothing to do with
public interest but plenty to do with protecting monopolies.
The Institute for Justice's study of Boston's closed taxi cab system described the
historical basis for restrictions of the taxicab industry in this way:
"Entry restrictions did not even pretend to protect the ''public interest," and were
often couched in explicitly anti-competitive terms. Improved safety or reduced
congestion and pollution were occasionally given as reasons, but only after-the-
fact rationalizations. In reality, regulators wanted to. ...enable the organized cab
fleets and transit companies to increase their profits" (Tab No.2, Page No.2)
The folly of these historical restrictions is amply demonstrated in both the literature, and
in practice in the increasing number of cities which have opened their taxi markets to
competition. This trend is simply explained by the Oregon based Cascade Institute, which
concluded:
c
c
c
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 3
"The argument for opening taxicab markets rests on the principle that government
should not protect for-profit cab companies from competition to the detriment of
the riding public..." (Tab No.3, Page No.2)
So lets talk about quality of service and costs. Without a single supporting authority, Bell
Cab/Yellow Cab asserts (and in fact makes it the heading of its written materials) that ''More
Competition Won't Improve Taxi Service." That is not what experience and the independent
studies have found.
As the Cato hlstitute concluded in a study authored by the Mayor of Indianapolis:
"Because the local (taxi) industry was protected from competition, the near
universal judgment was that service was poor, expensive and highly selective. If
you happened to live in a neighborhood that the dominant providers did not want
to serve, namely, low income and high crime areas, you were out ofluck." (Tab
No.4, Page No.5)
The hlstitute for Justice, in studying Baltimore's closed taxicab systern found:
"Baltimore's restrictive system of taxicab regulation has deteriorated working
conditions for the drivers and has produced poor results for consumers." (Tab
No.5, Page No.8)
And who is most adversely affected by the results of a monopoly in the taxicab industry?
The poor and minorities, those who most need the service, especially here in San Bernardino. As
the Consumer Policy Institute in Toronto found:
"Taxicab regulation discriminates against single mothers, low and fixed-income
wage eamers and the physically disadvantaged by reducing supply in their
neighborhoods and making the product uncompetitive and unaffordable." (Tab
No.6, Page No.2)
Perhaps the best description of the effect of the taxi-cab monopoly in San Bernardino is
found in the Toronto study, where the results of a closed systern were described as producing:
"a network of inefficient taxicab operators who use the taxi stand as an opportunity
to sit in their vehicles and wait for the business to come to them." (Tab No.6,
Page No.7)
Does that bring to your mind, as it does to mine, the current situation in San Bernardino,
with cabs lined up at the bus depot, and nowhere else?
What is happening in San Bernardino? City Code, at section 5.76.060, limits the number
of taxicabs to one for every 2,500 residents. With a population of 185,401 (according to the
2000 census) this means that San Bernardino may legally have up to 74 taxis. Bell/Yellow has a
o
c
c
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 4
permit to operate 36 cabs, slightly less than half of the code authorized number. However, a
review of the City Clerk's records reveals that there are only 19 drivers licensed to operate in
San Bernardino for Bell/Yellow. If these drivers were to work 8 hour shifts with two days off,
this means that the average number of cabs on the road at anyone time would be less than 5
(4.52 to be exact). But even if Bell/Yellow got all ofits drivers working at one time, it can still
only serve San Bernardino with Y. of the authorized number of cabs. Why is BelJ/Y ellow
keeping so few cabs operating in San Bernardino? Because without competition, public service
is not a factor they need to consider. Lowered costs and maximizing profit are the only factors
the market requires them to consider.
Now, Bell Cab/Y ellow Cab would have you believe that all sorts of social ills will result
from putting more cabs on the streets. But that's not the reality. First, if AAA is granted the
license it seeks, it will operate 25 cabs in San Bernardino. 25 additional automobiles spread
throughout the City will have no adverse impact on traffic and, in fact, as ridership increases (as
I will speak about in a moment) it could have the effect of reducing traffic by taking private
vehicles off the road.
Bell/Y ellow Cab will have you believe that additional cabs will reduce per taxi usage,
and decrease earnings by drivers. In fact, again without citing any basis for the staternent,
BelJ/Y ellow Cabs states, in their materials to this Bureau, that: "Even though the number of
taxis increases in an area, the number of trips in that area stays the same, or even decreases."
That statement is simply not true. The independent studies reveal just the opposite. As
competition increases the availability of cabs, reduces the wait time, and increases the quality of
service, ridership actually increases. In fact, the Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutious,
in studying taxicab regulations in Ohio, responded to just the argument that Bell/Y ellow Cab is
making, and soundly rejected that argument stating:
"If this (ridership levels remaining flat) were true, cities that deregulate would not
experience a significant increase in the number of cabs operating in their cities.
The demand would be insufficient to sustain a larger number of cabs and cab
companies. They would quickly go out of business. The fact that almost all cities
that deregulate their local taxicab market experience an increase in the number of
taxis in operation suggests that substantial unrnet demand exists for these
services." (Tab No.7, Page No.9)
If this Bureau permits competition in the taxicab industry in San Bernardino, what you
will no longer have is a single company with its cars lined up at the bus station, and a phone
listing waiting for the customers to corne to them, because they have no other choice. What you
will have is two ( or more) companies competing for the business, by increasing the quality of
service, reducing wait times, and corning up with innovative new ways to serve the public.
This clear and well documented advantage is the reason that study after study after study
supports competition in the taxicab industry, and city after city after city is abolishing the old
monopolies, in favor of a competitive taxicab market. As Jolm Husing's study points out, in
California cities with a population of 180,000 to 450,000, only two, Riverside and San
c
c
c
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 5
Bernardino, have a single licensed taxi company enjoying a monopoly. Every other such city
has at least 3 licensed companies. And that study is about to become outdated. Last month,
Riverside's Transportation Committee voted to end BelllYellow's monopoly and recommended
a license for AAA Cab to also operate in the City of Riverside.
Finally, let me address the drivers, as BelllY ellow will have you believe that competition
will hurt them. But again, that is not the case. In fact what is hurting the drivers is the lack of
competition. Currently, BelllY ellow Cab charges a driver, in San Bernardino, more than
$300.00 per week MORE to lease a cab than AAA Inland Empire cabs charges its drivers. Now
in fairness, I should note that AAA will, shortly be increasing its weekly lease rate by $100.00.
However, even after that increase, a driver working for AAA Cab would, without working a
single extra hour or taking a single extra rider, earn over $800.00 more a month than he would
earn with Bell CabN ellow cab. But he can't. Why, because there is only one employer for taxi
drivers in San Bernardino and that monopoly allows that employer to continue to charge
exorbitant lease rates to its drivers. The single company monopoly doesn't protect drivers, it
hurts them. Competition will help them. If another cab company is permitted to operate in San
Bernardino, BelllY ellow Cab will be forced to reduce its lease rates in order to keep the best
drivers.
So who do you believe? I think that even the most cursory review of the literature,
including the studies I've provided to you, arnply demonstrate that public necessity and
convenience will be served by competition, and will continue to be harmed ifBelllYellow Cab's
monopoly is continued. But if you still don't know who to believe, then I suggest you listen to
Bell CabNellow Cab. Yes, that's correct, listen to Bell CabNellow Cab. But not the
statements made in the submittals to you, but the statements made outside of their efforts to
preserve their monopoly.
In Bell Cab Company's February 12, 1998 application for a permit to operate in the City
of San Dimas, it said the following:
"Bell Cab Company is not a supporter of market deregulation but strongly
opposes monopolies that result in lower levels of service, minimal marketing
and lead to hostage pricing by service companies and taxicab operators.
Reasonable levels of competition lead to higher levels of service, stable consumer
prices, better accessibility to taxicabs and availability at all times of day." (Tab
No. 14, Page No.8)
That statement was signed by Scott Schaeffer of BelllY ellow Cab. And lest you think
that was an isolated position, you need look no further than the July 11, 1997 San Bernardino
County Sun wherein the following appears:
"Vanik Zadurian, General Manager of Bell's Ontario office, said choice is critical
for consumers. (quoting Mr. Zandurian) 'To have a monopoly is not right. When
there's no competition, the level of service goes down.'" (Tab No. 15, Page I)
c
c
c
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 6
These statements, and a number of similar statements made by BelllY eHow cab in the
newspaper are set forth at tabs 14 and 15 of the materials I've given to you.
We assert, and BelllYellow Cab agrees (in their statements outside this room), that public
necessity and convenience are served by reasonable competition in the taxi industry, and are
harmed by the current monopoly. We respectfully request, therefore, that this Bureau approve
the introduction of such competition into the San Bernardino market.
Respectfully Submitted
Mark C. Edwards
Mirau, Edwards, Cannon, Harter
& Lewin, a professional corporation
Attorneys for AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
o
o
o
(ST
1-"
(::~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
00
........
.l:$~
~'d!
1)~
'I
00
tot;
o
X,ll"
....
~+
N(I'I
"'....
p:~
00
~',...
ttlttl
VI (1'1
'ttlN
P....
00
~~
-i)-i)
~p
P....
.~
~'~.
VI VI
~:'~
0.0
:E:E
VI&>
."-i -i
'XI
(1'1(1'1
-i~
pp
VI VI
P....
00
:E:E
(}1(}1
-i-i
,II
IJlIJl
-i-i
~
GH..,
...m
0"'1
m~l
0,
Z '0,:
::0
Cl4
r;&.
:-<'C
l,
.tli'".',. ",
~.
i
,-,(1'1
Df'll
<::0
HGl
f'll....
::00
D"O
rf'll
to::O
Df'll
o
....
D
I I
:I::I:
....#.
"".,.
(11,'(1j
.0'0
(}1,'f)
"
<olO
....>4J
"
>4l-i)
<ol'l
-i)-i)
~~
I I I
Q)ttl
ttlttl
';'lt~~
ttlp
-i)p .
'IP
NP
I
1
I
I
,
i
I
-i)
o
-i)
I
(1)
ttl ,lb.p
~ ""NI
I I I II'
:::pZ;g:
.... 0..,.1
p p .... (1) I
I I
! i
I i
, I
I ~
~......
pp
00
~..,.
NN
(}10
..,.'.1
....P
(}1(}1
pp
00
:E:E
(}1(}1
-i-i
II
IJlIJl
-i-i
'-'1Jl
OD
IJlr
f'll<
D
::00
o
1Jl::O
H
f'll1Jl
::OD
::OZ
D.o
I
f'll
N
I I I I
l~tt~~
~,~"....'
00
.'1;!.,<>>,'
':O-~
',.,~'
'~~,'c~
,J1I VI
.........
0'0
,:E:E
{j,..w
'i'{':;(
.r:x:
.{J) (f>
-i-i
~
:raW
i~~
,&l:;i
'~lt
,r<i(~
fb'li<
,;l~'
1,':11,
i "3>
''''t
.-i
.m
411::0
N(1l
o
Z
~ il il !l
il~~~~~il
00
pp
(1)0'
0'(1)
'.I-i)
-i)'.I
00
........
(/lW
(1)<>>
N,lb.
..,...,.
00
....P
....w
0(1)
O',lb.
ww
....N
(}1,lb.
....0'
o
:E
:E
(11
(}1-i
-iI
I
IJl
1Jl-i
-i
~
N
W
........
(}1(}1
........
00
:E:E
(}1(11
-i-i
II
IJlIJl
-i-i
........
(]1(}1
~..
00
:E:E
(11(}1
-i-i
I:I:
UlIJl
-i-i
Gl.o
f'llr
::0....
D"I1
r-i
00
Z
-i
If'll
OC
3Gl
Df'll
UlZ
f'll
D
o
D
H
::0
*
3::0
HD
.or
I"O
DI
f'll
rD
oto
HC
Z::O
I11Z
f'll
-i
-i
0"'1l
0::0-
Zl>'
;!>Z
r"
'1:1
(f>
.oil>
C
::I.o
.of'll
00
CJ>
~'-'
-<::0
j: I I I. I I I I I
~o
00.
'i
o
N
-i)-i)
00
-i)-i)
I I
0000
0000
..,...,.
I I
0'0'
........
00
00
-i)
o
-i)
I
(1)
00
,...
I
....
....
....
....
I
~
"
~
I
II
P....
,...,...
(11(11
I:I:
........
.,...,.
(]1(n
<:>0
.....'~
'I\lN
.~~
"''.I
'ON
,...
'OW
...
to"
~/Jl'l
(fI""
)00";.0..(
'II
....
NIJl
-i
~
....
-~
N
gq
;ii
it?
z
r
Of'll
;t:o
i!lZ
;
::0
-<
I I
II
14'~
"",lb.
'(Jl(}1
-i)
o
-i);.o
1,1
0000
3i~
I II
~~
I
,
~
Z
I
-i)
....0
OP
....(11
..,.....
....(11
(110
..,.N
-i)""
(11-i)
'.I
f'll
:E
W
::ow
0::0
o
Ul
-iD
<
~111
"
....
0'
::03 DIJl
DD Z-i
r::o -iD
"0" I.o
I 0-<
Z Z
D -<r
D H
tolJl DZ
CI toO
::O-i DO
ZO rc
I11Z OH
GlIJl
C-i
I
II~II
...........................
"""!l>..,...
(11 (11 P'(11(}1
00000
oo....NO'(11
"'"
W....NOW
....01O)N..
,'r---"
-i)-i)~-i)-i)
WOIAl-i)(}1
) -i)
O~O
-i) -i)
I I I
oorooo
oom(1)
OO.\:1l-i)
~ ~'I ,0
N (11
N ,...
o -i)
,-....
~ t)1 ~
t=l f:i ~ ~ ~ 0; ~ Cl
I I I I
00
........
,...00
WW
-i)0'
0'0'
"0"0
00
toto
00
XX
WW
00'.1
'.10
W,...
rGl
111111
::OZ
Of'll
-<::0
l>
tor
l>
"O::I
-i
H"I1
1Jl....
-i1Jl
111 I
111
::0
00
....P
N(}1
0,...
WO'
-i)0
NN
""0'
00'.1
N
(}1111
f'llN
(1)
N-i
ZI
o
IJl
1Jl-i
-i
0....
....0
(110
-i)01
,...'.1
....,...
"0....
(}1
00'
....
to
O:E
X
N
N....
WUl
,...-i
IJl
-i
1,1\''''(.> ~ :::'0
"0
l>l>
.o<
I....
HO
H::O
N
f'llUl
Ol>
Glr
eGl
D
o
o
I I
00
........
WO
'.I....
O'-i)
0'''''
"0"0
00
toto
00
XX
NN
"'0
""(}1
..,.
03
l>l>
<C
....::0
OH
.o
"0111
f'll
::0111
"
....0
Z;J>
1Jl<
H
(1'1
PO
0....
~o
O-i)
""0'
W(1)
pp
W....
....(1)
....
111
:E
p
(1)P
-i'.l
I-i
I
Ul
-i1Jl
-i
.
~ =.':..".+!~~
0....
....0
(11p
'.I..,.
-i)(1)
W..,.
........
WN
....0'
f'llf'll
pp
0'0'
-i-i
II
IJlIJl
-I-i
f'll'-'
ro
....1Jl
Nf'll
it~
f'll
-ir
I
(f>
3-i
HD
.o::o
I"
f'llf'll
rlJl
r
f'll
IJl
.o
o
-i
-I
"O:E
l>H
-ir
::or
....H
.ol>
,,::I
:EI
o
.-f:E
e:l>
f'll::O
ro
to
D
"
111
::0
::00
H'l>
Gl<
0....
toO
f'll
::03
.-f
0::0
....
.o<
Df'll
(1'1::0
.-fl>
H
r
r
o
II
I
i
I
I
I
~~~I ~~
(}101 (}1(11
,
I
00 00 ....0...00 00
PO' P'.l N>-'OWP ....(}1
" " "'" "
PW~PN W..-WNP WO
(110 (11P ....(11...(1)(}1 ....-i)
" " "'" "
-i)o-i) -i)-i) -i)-i)-(j0-i) -i)0
W 0(1) worNOi 0'0
~k>~~ ~~~' i ~~~
-4>-i) -4>-4> -i)jO-i)
I I I I I I I II I
W(1) '.100 ooalW
ooal -4>00 NlllOO
""P 0'0 ,....,.,...
~,1J, J,,0,0 ~i!.6
(}1p PPN~ w...,...
-4>00 NO N...,...
(}1-4> ~N (}1Noo
i
i
II
P....
,...,...
(11(}1
OP
0'0
"
OW
(11....
"
0-4>
PN
II
PP
,...,...
(11(11
'~it ~ ~ f' ~ ~
...:411\:>>.:, I" .. ,... ,.' ,...,...
(fI'!11~(}101 01(}1
I
000
) (}1 N
,r---,
....~N
,... 00
, ,
':.' .-.()
~ I,t. W
00 P 0.0
~~~ ~ '~~
....pw W "'N
-4>'~' 0 (fI-4>
k-i:O~r ~ ~,~
C1''i(1) W ON
I
~~~i~~~
[00 00 00 (X, 00
000000 OOaiF.
\j:;-l>l> l>(11
E' I I I I I I
....P....P(11V!
....Pp....,...,...
P.... pOO
r........ ....moo
. I
I !
II
P....
,...,...
(11(}1
II
PP
,...,...
(}1(J1
PO
OP
ON
O'-i)
-i)'.I
Pl>
PO'
(J1(J1
-i)""
(J1
:E
:E
P
pO
P-I
-iI
I
IJl
1Jl-l
.-f
J>.o
rl>
to::O
f'llr
::00
.-f1Jl
"O.o
f'llD
zto
J>::O
111
::0
l>
I
II~I
PP
,...,...
(J1(J1
OO~
'.I....
"
NP
p(J1
~~ltl
00 Or
I
n
~~
'.Ij,O
~~
~
~
II
~
to
r
"11
3
IJl
.-f
.
"11 .'
C
r
r
IJl
.-f
::0
111
f'll
-I
l>
o
o
::0
f'll
Ul
IJl
r
H
IJl
.-f
H
Z
Gl
::0
111
"0
o
::0
.-f
to
r::
(I)
...
;j
(l)
(I)
(I)
l>
0.
0.
"i
(l)
00
(I)
I
I
I
i
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
o
.~
;j
(l)
"i
Z
ll>
3
(l)
P
,...
W
W
P
..,.
o
0'
I
P
W
I
o
N
.o
...
ll>
(I)
(I)
.o
...
o
(I)
(l)
"0
J>
Gl
111
P
to
r::
(I)
...
JI
--I
,
c
o
:J
"-,- ..-----.."...-...-.,...-
., ^ '.
~ ., . .,j ..; . ..J
~ :: ~.., '" = ~ = ~ . ~ ~ -
'. ~ .... .
0, ~ g:-~ ~ l.<1 tll g: <t & . ~ . t ~ . ~ . ~ lsi ~ ~ ~ ~ r(.) ~ ~ ~ ;~1 ~.
-, ., ~,- ~ ~ ~ 0 . :.nc.l ~ o. l!l =
00
........
0'01
1\)'01
w....
00'
00 .....0
"""J---I' 0)-10
0'0' ....0
'01.... 0>0'
01-e '4:>1\)
01 01 (}I. W
'011\) NN
~ ~ (;; ~...re.
OOW, W'W
h .
00 on
1Tll> l>l>
zr rr;
-l.... .
::O"Tl
l>0
r::o
z
l>....
<l>
ITl
01
-l
....00
0.......
.I>- '01 O.
-e01N
0>'''
00"
::; 0; tJ."
O1OOW
1\)01"
::1' }
eo " Zt
z -< ';;z; .i
"rol'4."T1'.
ITlITl 1Tl"~
;0 . Q.
l> '($'0
I < .';fQ
....1Tl
r
r
\)
r
00
........
row
.l>-W
1\)0
....W
1\)1\)
0'0'
1\)1\)
0000
0000
roro
f'Tlf'Tl
::0;0
-l-i
........
f'Tlf'Tl
rr
zz
OOcOO
....,. ...'f-"........,.
I\) r-., W01w
0' -1,', (J<:C-
ow -e<..
0.1>- oo-e
1\)1\) 1\)1\)
W.... 0'0'
WO ........
(X) WI\)
Z 011\)
Z
co f'Tlf'Tl
co I'll
tlflTl" ro ro
,tlf;(} l> l>
l'1Z' 01 01
:X.!: f'Tlf'Tl
..g.....O,.. rr
'0' ........
'0 zz
o f'Tl1'Tl
.~
W
....
(X)
o
....
(X)
'01
W
I\)
1\)#
01"'"
-el\)
0101
'01
I'Tl
ro
l>
01
I'Tl
r
tHo
Z
f'Tl
01
-i
OEOO
.....-~....
(X) 1\)'01
o 00....
".J ,-e I\)
". '0 W '01
00
........
00.1>-
.1>-0
.1>-....
1\)1\)
00
,.-.,.....:
.0....
Wo
I7-w
...w'J
. . D- JI.l
&:i
'r~
'/~:~..rrf
-,.t. '
, \::r 'C.
~~:.
. 'IIi
'.1", -l
l
'-I>
00
........
0'0'
-el\)
'01.1>-
.1>-.1>-
\)1)
00
roro
00
xx
-e-e
-ew
wo
I\)
"Tl
e
r
r
01
-i
ro ;0
c ITl
00 ITl
.... -i
"
CD l>
00 0
00 0
::0
l> I'Tl
0- 01
0- 01
4
CD r
00 ....
00 01
-l
....
Z
m
;0
ITl
1)
0
;0
-i
........
I\)-e
0.1>-
.1>-.1>-
00
or
rl>
0;0
::0"
l>
03:
00
e
l>Z
<-i
1Tll>
....
Z
::0
o
II\)
101
....-e
o./>.
(J11\)
~.'.~
.. 0;~~
0'01
....0
....'01
'010
.1>-.1>-
00
o
..CD :2 l>
f'Tl !:J> i l>::O
"';:0 ,'. :J> ;0 0
ro ;,'... 10 ::0 I
l> ;f;).'. 10 0 ....
01 /':(l,o 0 !: ro
f'Tl '.(.'!: ,- l>
~:~;;it e b
Z .', J>i; I\)
f'Tl ,*6' l>
.... <
O1./>.l> f'Tl
-i 0<
-ef'Tl
0101
-i-i
~
(X)
~
'01
./>.
t~.,
:J>../Tl
<""l;
....m'
O~
-fX
lYli
.... .
.'itl
.1"*
.rt!
. oz
g]j;$
::00
018
I .
~H
f'Tl
I
,
"Tlhm:3
~~;ra:i
o ....r.".......:!:..........
f'Tl ...:J>;:J>
::03:rt!
.... . r
o 3:
" .' ..l>
il>. ..
YJ ~...~~
l>:J>~
<7 :J::r
".. l> f'Tl
o r01
~I
00
Ol>
Z<
l>....
ro
o
-i
roI
....0
r3:
rl>
elJ>
1)
01
rm
I'TlITl
01;0
rl>
....r
1'Tl0
3:0
e
oz
l>Z
;0
;0
....
r
r
o
l><
z....
00
;o-i
f'Tl0
!:;o
om
ro;o
l>l>
::oz
....
r
r
o
OLl '-<0""0 :3
:rJ> 1'Tl0 if'Tle 0
l>-< ::oe <l> :r
;0 'Om....z l>
rm('~ .:r- Zrn 3:
(}'-~ l>rol ~
1>l> r::o
u-<ro "Tl.... l>
co z.rt! ::0 0 ro
1'Tl< f'TlGl 0
,'1 ITl 0 f'Tl f'Tl
N mr (Jl' r
~ ~ I ~
-< ~ I ~
Z
I
H
3:
l>
-<
l>
;o:J:
....l>
O!:
Ie
l>"
;00
o
:J:
mlTl
Z
\)IJ>
Ol>
!:I
I'Tl
r
r
'-< I~'
Ol>
:r;o
Z<
ITl
m-<
o
O1-l
01;0
l>l>
;001
O-l
ITl
;0
:0
~
I
,
I
!
I
I
I
I
I
I
I I I
, I
Z
l>>
3
CD
...
.I>-
W
W
...
./>.
0
.a-
'1..
~.; ~
, 0 W
f ..... ,
f l>> 0
, 00 N.
, 00
1 0
f ....
1 0
f 00
1 CD
I 1)
f l>
f m
f'T1
,
I
I
1
,. I\)
.1
I ro
I c
I 00
, ....
I "
I CD
f 00
I 00
I
I
I
II~II
,,-....,. ........,.
.I>-./>. ./>..1>-
0101 0101
:r I ~:Jic:r
....... . -:'.-^..J.~.,~.;
.1>-.1>- """"".
01 01 onn
~
II
........
.1>-.1>- .
0101
... 0 ~"'.'..'O .......;;},.....".'...
o 01 ,'N*
" .,.,
I\) W'II;)o>"'
....,. }-J.P:'\o."",,
""""
-e -e '>Q.-e
OOWN./>.
II
........
.I>-./>.
0101
.I :r
. j,ooIo. -to-' ~
..1>-
0101
II
........
./>../>.
0101
~~I ~
./>../>. .I>-
(}I01 01
I
...
.I>-
01
I;c
........
.~.'
O1Oi
00.
W(J<
"
W....
....0
"
-e-e
1\)'01
~.
"
o
-e
"
-e
./>.
o
01
,
W
....
,
-e
o
....0
....0'
"
WW
00
"
-e-e
1\)01
00
I\)W
"
I\)W
-e....
""
-e-e
1\)1\)
00 0
01... W
" ,
WW W
........ ....
" ,
~~I ~
00
......
'"
t--'.~
0101
"
-e-e
"'0
....
....
,
W
o
,
-e
I\)
....0 0.0
....,.(1\ .~^~
'" "'"
WW 'I:;"...
00 .(11 01
" .",
-e-e <0'-1>
1\)1\) 0.0
.~. -e
,..ta ~
.~f<l>
;1 ~
. ~: I f
~. ....
"". (X)
~; ~
I
I
I
I
.'-1>.'''.
:o;():
>Q' >&r
',',,', ,
.JI-.w
'N; If:'
'~"'-
t'.~I"S"f'
.ww
. . <0.1>-
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
-e -I), -e. (X)
o '00 0
-e <o-e 0
I I I. I I I
(X) w-e W
(X) 001\) .I>-
o .l>-W 0
, I I , f I
... ....0' (X)
0' ....0' I\)
-e ....... -e
0' ....(}I ./>.
-e-e
00
-e-e
I I I
0000
0'0'
1\)1\)
I I
0101
1\)1\)
0'0'
0000,
I
,
I
,
,
I
I
,
,
I
,
i
-e-e
00
-e-e
I I I
0000
1\)'01
ow
I f I
O./>.
-...100
1\)0
....~
~I
(X)
It-
l\)
1
I\)
(X)
.l>-
I\)
-e
o
-e
I
(X)
0'
I\)
I
01
....
W
W
-e
o
-e
,
.l>-
I\)
01
I
I\)
I\)
(X)
N
-e -e-e -e
o 00 0
-e -e-e -e
I , I I ,
.I>- '01 (X) I W
I\) -eoo 01
!~I !!I !
01 (11 ...,. I ..()
... 1\)...1....
(JJ It-... (X)
. I
! I
I I
! ,
, ,
~
i
,
,
I
_:~-;~:;_=~J~"iz\,ff:.Gf~:
'<2 ,".' ,...~
lii
. --.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
A..
.
..
a
-
-
o
.
~ g 5: ~ f3 f~
~ g it
}.~
I.'~'~'
i.1
$..6}
~~
I J
,...:-
0''''
"",0
:-0
c
.
.
"'0
0'"
...:-
11'0/)
11''J
'JW
3:C
H(")
(,,):I:
:I:fTl
J>(")
fTl:I:
rc
;:<;
(I)~
-l0
fTl
<fTl
fTl'-<
ZH
3:
:00
H"Tl
(")0
J>:O
:0
o
... I-'
WO
1-''-1
O/)W
~~
OZ
J>O
;:<;:0
~~
00
00
00
OJ>
:0<
fTl
""
N
00
:I::I:
1-'1-'
:-:-
(11(11
00
1-':-
"
1-'1-'
O~
"
00/)
N~
-D
o
-D
I
00
00
~
I
I-'
I-'
I-'
I-'
c
. . .
o ~ ~
:I::I:
1-'1-'
:-~
(Jl(Jl
00
I-'(Jl
"
01-'
~(11
"
-D-D
I1'N
-D-D
00
-D-D
I I
0000
0000
WN
I I
NI-'
O-li>
'J(Jl
NW
.
.
"
i\\ t ~
O-l
OH
:03:
00
-l-l
:I::I:
-<-<
J>Z
~3:
J>H
-lr
(l)r
OfTl
Z:O
00
1-'1-'
oow
W'J
'J11'
(Jl-li>
-li>-li>
1-'1-'
'J~
11'-D
3:3:
00
CC
ZZ
-l-l
J>J>
HH
ZZ
00
:0:0
t
0/) -D
o 0
-iJ -D
I I
W 00
<l) 00
I-' ~
I I
-D I-'
-Ii> I-'
wI I-'
NI I-'
I
i
I
I
.
. .
~ ~
1-'0
01-'
OW
11''-1
0011'
-D-D
'-IN
-iJ-li>
I1'w
-Ii>
Z
3:
H3:
OfTl
:I::O
CH
:00
(l)H
-iJ>
Z
o
:OJ>
<
fTl
""
...
I-'
N
'-<fTl
00
:I:~
ZJ>
:0
fTlO
1):0
J>
Gl(l)
fTl1)
J>
Z
Z
fTl
;0
:I: I
1-'1-'
:-:-
(Jl(Jl
01-'
:-N
"
I-'W
001-'
"
O-D
0:-
'"
.
.
o
".'
.
.,
c
"'"',..'
'..~",..
-.
(I
~ ~ ~ ~
~ w
m ~
(.l (.l r...l (.;'1""WT~ I l\) I l\) 1i"n.-'-'"J;) .. --rr:::iTo.> ~ ....... ~ = ;-;:; ....
./> W 1\:1 ....L~.L!:!:!....l....L!:!!...~I.J>; f.~3:l..... ~ '" ...'
- ,--- I"
00
..........
00
"'-I
':-'11'
(J>I-'
..._~
'-1<11
11'.1-'
OO<l)
3:~
J>
-1""3:
'r J>
0'"'
:OZ
-<0
r
(j)H
-lJ>
J>
<
fTl
00
1-'1-'
11'11'
'-IW
0(Jl
WI-'
I-'(Jl
~O
W'-I
W(J>
fTlZ
rr
-<C
ZGl
~O
o
OJ>
0<
fTl
o
:0
""
W
;0;0
J>O
z-<
~J>
rfij
;0
'-<-<
m
....
...
M
:0
-<
rn
J>-<
;oZ
;O-l
-<I
H
3:J>
H
(")(")
:I::O
J>O
fTl(j)
r(j)
00
J>
;:<;
fTl
;0
:I::I:
1-'1-'
-li>:-
(11(Jl
:I: I
1-'1-'
:--li>
(Jl(Jl
00
OO(Jl
"
WW
1-'1-'
"
-D-D
W(Jl
-D
o
-D
I
00
00
:-
I
I-'
I-'
I-'
I-'
f
i
.
..
01-'
'0" O.
w....
IV,,,",,
"".11"
(11'J
...:-
':<;1(;1,
,.'''4~
'~Q
:~i-
'. ,0.
',-4:
~(j).
.ITf'-,,\
'(")
-i
1-'0
0...
1-':-
'-l-D
(]I 00
'-J-D
NN
11'-li>
11''-l
(Jl
...
r,
fTlN
:0
OZ
-<
r
(/)fTl
-iZ
o
;0
fTl
J>
<
fTl
01-'
...0
N:-
(11W
wo
11'(11
...00
N(Jl
11'-1>
(]I 00
;:<;;:<;
fTlJ>
ZH
O(j)
J>fTl
r:o
r
J>
0<
;0
""
(Jl
I-'
I-'
N
..,-t
1
'.', ;<f
.1!!..
::r>
3:r,
e
~i'
~,""'t
,~...
:;;.'
'-~4'- -
:z
'0
Z
O(/)
fTl-l
ZfTl
H1)
(/):I:
fTlfTl
Z
:I:
C3:
ZH
-in
:I:
J>
fTl
r
<
fTl
(/)
-i
00
NJ>
J><
H
HO
;:<;
(fJ"Tl
:I:r
~fTl
J>3:
;:<;...
cz
Gl
:rJ:
'-:P:"~
...:-
(Jl(]l
J::I:
1-'...
-l>-Ii>
(Jl(Jl
IJ:
1-'...
-1>:-
(Jl(Jl
"'g
~-~
'O~'
',,,,
~o/)
W-D
00
'-l'"
"
W'"
"'0
"
>DO
N(Jl NN
~>D
o
-D
I
00
00
'-l
I I
0'
N
00
11'
>D
o
>D
I I
'J
W
N
I
OVl 00
0/)"1 00
VI-I> 11'
VI'-l~W
I
I
I
.
. ---
Gl;O
:OJ>
J>r
H1)
:OJ:
tor
J>fTl
Gl~
'OH
J>(/)
Gl
J>:O
;00
-<(I)
J>J>
zz
o
<
J>
J:J:
"'1-'
-l>-Ii>
(Jl(Jl
~-D-D
00
-D>D
I I I
(JlOO
~~~
I I I
OO-li>
I-'(Jl
I-'N
(Jl-li>
,
,
a
o
I-'
,
I-'
o
,
o
N
o
-Ii>
,
N
-Ii>
,
o
o
-D
o
-D
I
00
00
-Ii>
I
I-'
...
I-'
...
00
1-'...
WO
wO'
......
WI1'
............ .-.t-A
N'J IV'-l
1-''-1 0:-
(Jl0' (Jl
m
J:t: Z
"'0 Gl
rJ: Gl:O
rHy;oO
-<Gl~-Ho<
I<fTl
<r fTl
HJ>,
(/)Z (fJ
-i0 -l
J>
J> :It-
to< fTl
rfTl
'-<
J>
(")
J>
:0
J>
Z
o
J>
J>
<
fTl
1)
:0
H
-<
H
,-<r
J>fTl
(")(1)
;:<;-l
fTl
;0;0
H
(")to
J:O
J>C
:00
0;0
fTl
"TlJ>
;OC
J>X
;:<;
fTl
(/)
o
t:
J>
;:<;
~
I I I I I
J:
...
~
(Jl
J:J:
1-'...
-li>-li>
(J>(Jl
00
00...
"
......
'-l(Jl
"
>D >D.
000
>D-D
00
>D>D
I I
0000
0000
W'-l
I I
11'(Jl
>D-li>
N-D
'-l-li>
u.
.
<;:<;
'Hm
(")z
-lZ
om
:O-l
J:
to
CJ:
-lm
r::r>
Mal
';o1Ji
-i
m
o
-i
J:J:
.....:~
-li>'~
(Jl(Jl
0'"
...0
"
"'W
(Jl'"
"
.~.;S
-D>D
00
-Do/)
I I I
''-l<l)
-D'-l
N-I>
I I I
000
(J>(Jl
(]I'"
W'-l
.
00
"'1-'
.0<>>
-Dill
,ow
00....
\
-..J
t!~I::::i~
~ !-:;T.... 1:7.: <.Ill",,: .....j", ' ..."\
00
1-'...
...w
OO(Jl
WN
11''-l
N...
(11,0
(11...
IllW
Z~
GlGl
rH
mr
Zto
~fTl
0;0
O-l
1>0
<:: (/)
mJ>-l
t~
0010...
.......... ......0
I1'Ill wo
(11'<.1 WI1'
1>>,<11 I-' 0
<11<1' 'J'J
~e!oe
ww ~
ooW ,0
O~ III
ow 00
NOO,'J#
>D-li> (JlJ>
(Jl'-l N
(Jl (Jl
'-<
'-<J>
J>3:
3:fTl
m(]l
(fJ
-i(fJ
O-l
t:
Z
o
;u
.N,....
;aj....
:J\J, IV
.1\,)11'
zz
',al'al
J>
-;U<ll
. -0 -l
ro
:z
J>
.(1'-
-l
'J'"
o (]I
11'00
0(11
fTlfTl
rr
3:r
t:(I)
O~
00
o;u
-l
;UJ:
o
~
J>
-<
NJ>lll'-4..
fTlrt::tTtl
r"Tl 'D H"11"
J>;U or "11'
rfTl i r
fTlO Hll
3: 1);0
;0""
-i (fl'Z
H t: "ll*'
rH r
J>r mm
J:r 00'
CH 11
ZJ> J>
3: ;u
(]I N
J>
J>J>
rz
to-l
fTlJ:
;uo
-lZ
-<
;:<;
3:
Gl
:00
J>~
-<fTl
Z
(/)
!'
I
!
I
I
I
, r
I I I
J: J: f:I: J:. ..~ J: J: I
~...... . .....H ............
~~ ~~. ~-li>
(]I(Jl <1101 (11(Jl
00 00 00
~t-Io ......(1l ...........
" " "
w...... ......1\): ......J\)
J-Io(]1 01..... (]1......
" " "
,o>D -D,o -D-D
NO ow 000
0/)
o
>D
I I
00
'J
-Ii>
I
N
11'
W
11'
,0
o
>D
I I
00
00
'J
I
III
11'
...
o
-D
o
,0
~~
f;,
~~
.
;:;0
.
In
r
...
3:
(]I
-l
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
J
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
,
I
,
I
I
,
,
I
I
I
I
I
\.
r
r
I.
I
J
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
,
I
I
I
I
I
I
"
,f;l:,
J
I
I.
I
I
I
I
I
,
I
,
I
I
,
I
I
I
I
I.
,.
I.
l~<,
I
\
I
I
I
I
I
I'
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
,
u_ ~_,..1
.'
In
C
III
....
::l
()
III
III
J>
a.
a.
...
()
III
III
"Tl
C
r
r
(/)
-i
;U
fTl
fTl
-i
J>
o
o
;U
fTl
(fJ
(fJ
r
...
(I)
-l
H
Z
Gl
;0
fTl
1)
o
;U
-i
o
.~
::l
()
...
Z
III
3
()
...
-Ii>
W
W
(")
,.....
III
III
III
(")
,....
o
III
()
I-'
-Ii>
o
11'
.'.,
....
W
I
o
N
1)
J>
Gl
fTl
W
In
C
III
....
::l
(J)
III
III
,
(:
~ ~ m ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ $ & ~ ~ ~ t e ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
NO
0'"
WN
..0
..,,,
<1>0'
o
ON
..,w
o.N
(J),o
......t:
.....H
(J)r
...r
<1>0
o.t:
o
;U
~:'~~.
-I> ,.~.;lIO<.
(11 ."Q$:~
..0
o
..0
I
(X)
0'
N
,
0'
(X)
...
0'
,o\Q
0'0
..0...0
I I
(X) (X)
~";:!I
I I
~':~
..."
....01
... ",
i
o
...
...
"
(X)
N
OO~
ON
ON
0'
nlO'
t:
J>
(11
I
H
Z
GJ
-l
o
Z
(11
-l
.00
...,.to'-
'-1>1\.>.
J~fi"
ail.
i4
.(I),
co
H
r
r
'-<
J>
-<
co
;U
-<
J>
Z
-I
I
...
-I>
(11
o
...
,
W
...
,
..0
N
..0
o
..0
,
-I>
N
N
,
...
..0
o
o
Onl
J>(fl
Znl
HO
nlC
rH
nl
zr
'-<
<J>
J>H
r3:
nlnl
Z
0'-"
H(fl
J>O
;U
nl
nl
Z
II
......
-1>-1>
(11(]1
..0..0
00
..0..0
, ,
0000
0000
ttl
......
......
......
... -1>1
"'0
0...
WW
OOW
ON
N-I>
......
0'00
"W
..00'
...w
<<
HJ>
rr
rr
J>nl
GJ-<
nl
CO
rr
Z
~
-I>
(X)
N
00
t--o'-......
O'W
'NW
.j>(1I
WN
....'-1
N-I>
,(I)'W
....,..0
<<
J>J>'
r:-r
, .m:t>
Z';U
'0.""
H'J>
J>
,0
J>.;o
<
nl
E"TI
]);U
;U])
;UZ
m()
Z[1l
(Jl
J>
r.,-j
<:0
mr-
;Or-
rtIm
N-t
-l
...
...
'--'
XI
~H
-I>.j>
(]l(1l
0,,- ~ -""'NT;;;,". I' ". I "r~J N_;;o.,., ~,...,..,.IT'" ~ -.,"
N _.." ~L~L~....I.."'-..L~._.'i\ ,,,....J. w ..N. ..., r-- .. -~ ~.~. ~ N
0... 00 0 00 00
.....0 .....~ ~~...............
(I)... WW 0(11 WO' "'0
NN -I>W ~~ W(1I (X)(]l
"'00 oo~ ~(11 (]1,o ~...
~(]l 0 N'-I 00 ~O
NN...... O'Nl!"'J N" NW
\/)()) w..... ~J).iCL.. :...")....Q)(Jl (n;J:l.
:N ~; ~~r' ~g~o ~~
(Jl (X) (]1 nl (11
(Jl (fl ;U;U (11 t: ~ ;U
-I(Jl I(Jl CO, ;U ;ulii"J>
>>H ~.~ ~X 1M ~HOln~
-I m ;U ;U -I CO ' . 0 H l> ,: t. z
m;u OJ> HC m J>r rm
;U Z-I O;U ;U r.., J>O
(flJ> 0 -<., -l0 Zt:
-l OGJ r V> 0 0
t: -lJ> ZO -I J> Ulr
J> ;U J>< Z
-<;U <nl CO
o ITl r
1> ""
~ '#;'-.1 #.
I" (]l 0' I
(]l
~ -~
. ~
-l1)
OJ>
3:C
3:r
-<1Tl
-I
'-<-l
HITl
3:
;U
IO
J>O
3:;U
HITl
rGJ
-l0
OC
Z(Jl
........,
""0-
N,o-
N"'"
....
'{f}
"
',,~
",~~
;0....
.J>%
GJ
<'
''''J>
<A'e
,'-1Pl
J>
1)
^
t:
-<
:t.:l.
I , , I
II
......
-1>-1>
(]1(]1
I,I
~',~
.",,-.1>
(]1(]1
00 00 00
-1>00 "-I> o-tv
" " "
WW N... '0'"
~ ~ ~ ~~..t:: ~
~ -() ..0..0 '-.(1-.(1
(]10' 00-1>"-1>
~~~~~~l~
ii' , Ill, , ,
~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~.. :~ .~ I
00-1> -1>0' -1>00
, , I , I , I."
:::J~r:::~N:::~1
-I>N ...NJq....O'
WOO.... oof.... 0'1
, 1
I I i
I I
....
N
,
o
(]1
,
..0
"
'-<I
OJ>
(fl;U
1Tl0
1)r
IO
ro
(flaJ
-l0
J>O
;UZ
AITl
ITl
(fl
'-<
;U
o
~
W
~
J>O<:;O;U
3:HHJ>O
J>O\l:;uz
oz ;UJ>
0.... or
;U(fl ro
H r
3:0 J>
1)
;UO ....GJ
CJ> A;U
H;U 1TlJ>
NJ> -<
ID
~r
II~II
......... ....~
-1>-1> -1>-1>
(]1(]1 (]1(]1
0....
..0....
"
WN
ON
"
~O
NO
I
;g ;g II
..0..0
, 'I
(X) -1>1
00..0
00'
~~I'
0....
"....
0"
II
........
-1>-1>
(]1(]1
XI
......
-1>.-1>
(]1(]1
I
I
..0 ..0 I ..0
00 0
..0..0 ..0
I I ,
....,00 m
0000 N
00-1> 0
'I ,
m.... 0
....... N
..0.... "
'-I.... -I>
o
....
,
...
(]1
,
..0
o
.......
00
"
WN
.......
"
..0..0
WOO
..00'
0'"
..0..0
I , ,
mN
~-I>
~O
, , ,
N'"
W....
000'
-1>"
0....
....0
-1>0
0'(]1
00"
~(]1
........
..."
0(]1
~N
(]1
Z
1)
1)H
OZ
(flm
-I
IJl
(fl-l
-I
""
o
:~f;5 I <0
00
......
~$
"w
0'1\)
N...
0"
(1\'"
(,).""
lZZ
1)'1:1
ITltn
;U;lJ
1Jl(Jl
IX
""'H
ZZ
f:i)!j)
J>:l>
<<:
ITlm
rI
....1Tl
(fl;U
mID
-lnl
-l;U
nl-l
3:3:
o
Z1)
0;0
3>H
00
J>m
;U:r (fl'-<Ir1'-<t:'c'DO
1Tll>l>-Im 1Tl....",'-.J>
X;U;ol>;U ;url-icz
I-<HZO 03: r....
rl>or3: 3:J> JT1
ITlITl m ~rl
(fll> -< r'
-l ;U J>J> l>nl
;U.... 0. z.Z
o ;u 9. l) A m ".(;f) co
Z .... "';0 H .(Jl.:;:o-
GJ aJ 0.... 0 '-1:'-<
m....z 0 3>."
GJ Z
r-l
nl
, I
, /,
~ ~ ~,'.~'..~
(]1(]1~(]1(1l
I
"'0 00 00 00
NO' O'(]1(1)'" N-I>
" " " "
OW WN W... "'N
"0 0..0 "'(11 ,,-I>
" " " "
..0..0 ..00 ,o~ ..00
mw WN WO -1>0
I
..0..0 ..0..0
00 00
mm "m
"m ..00'
-1>-1> O'-I>~
' , I I I , ,
"'O'gwO'
0'''' OOO~
NO ...m
NO mw
I i
I I !
~ ~ ~ ~};
-1>-1> .....
(]1(]1 (il(]l
I
..0
o
..0
I ,
W
(X)
...
I
"
(1l
m
m
, I
00
..."
"
W.I\)
..."
"
~.~
(]1m
co .... OlIUl
00
......
(]1'"
"..0
..."
NO'
N-I>
00'
"'N
(1l
(Jl
1)
1)J>
nl<
ZH
ZJ>
(Jl
-<t:
rJ>
<-<
J>
Z
H
J>
l>
<
ITl
"TI;U
;UO
J>CO
Znl
A;U
r-l
H
ZO
OIJl
3:
3:....
H-l
OI
I
J>H
nl....
r
(Jl
o
Z
II
... ...
-1>-1>
(]1(]1
..0
o
..0
I
m
m
0'
I
o
W
..0
m
00
(]1'"
"
0'"
0'(]1
"
..0..0
"0
..0..0
00
..0..0
, ,
mw
m(]1
00'"
, ,
Nm
ON
"...
"m
:J
"",~ 1.:1 ....
I
ID
r
"TI
i'!
-I
,
I.
I
I
I
I
,
,
I
I
I
I
1
,
I
t
I
,
I
I
I
,
,
1
1
"
,
f
1
,.
I
I
.1
1
~t .
,1
I
,
f
,
I
I
I
,
,
I
,
,
,
I
1
I
-t
..1
.f"
Fe
I.
I
f
I
t
t
I
I
I
I
I
,
I
1
I
I
I
I
I
,
"
';-,;
,.-
,
I
I
I
o
.~
='
G)
..,
Z
III
3
<I>
<
.
'.
CO
t:
(J)
.....
='
<I>
(J)
lIJ
J>
a.
a.
..,
<I>
(J)
(J)
"TI
C
r
r
IJl
-I
;U
nl
nl
-l
l>
o
o
;U
m
(]1
IJl
r
H
IJl
-l
....
Z
GJ
;U
nl
1)
o
;U
-I
...
~
W
W
(')
>-
III
(J)
(J)
o
......
o
(J)
<I>
...
-I>
o
0'
.,.
""
W
1
o
N
1)
J>
GJ
nl
-I>
ID
t:
(J)
.....
='
G)
lIJ
(J)
c
o
I
, 0'
I i
,
,
!
I
!
j
c
City of San Bernardino
Number of Licensed Taxicab Drivers
06/01/02
19
01/01/02
17
06/01/01
14
01/01/01
13
06/01/00
9
c
01/01/00
8
06/01/99
8
01/01/99
8
c
o
o
I
I
I
10
I
I
j
c
c
c
Economics & Politics, Inc.
3142 Cutn. Clrde
Hlgbland, CA 92346-1739
(909) 425-8952 Pbone
lobnllillobnbustn..com
www.lobnbustn..eom
Taxi Service Market Considerations
Cities of San Bernardino & Riverside
by John E. Husing, Ph.D.
In considering whether to open their taxicab markets to some competition, the cities of San
Bernardino and Riverside would be well served to address a single question:
. Which is more likely to enhance the quality of taxi service provided to citizens of
their communities: monopoly taxi service or competitive taxi service?
This question arises as each city considers whether "public convenience and necessity" will
allow the permitting of a second company. Certainly, neither community is inundated with
excess taxicab service. In San Bernardino's case, there is only one legal cab per 5,284 residents.
In Riverside, it is one legal cab per 7,181 residents.
Monopoly Service. The <lI1estion of "monopoly vs. competitive" taxi service is posed as the two
cities are unique among the 13 rnid-sized California communities of 190,000-450,000 people in
that each is only served by'a single taxicab company (Exhibit 1).
Exhibit 1,-Number of Taxi Companies, 2002
California Cities, 190,000 to 450,000
1
27
'~/
,.il>
~
,,~
,/ <1"./ / ,,~~
,,~ .f'
</
/
"'~ .,?
"",'" ".
... ,,~
:J#o$> ,j> <1'''>
~ ,,-sf' I>
'/
~
I S01U"CC: Cities I
~.
Elderly. Handicapped. PQor. In addition, the question is important as the ultimate purpose of a
municipal goyernment is >"to ensure that its citizens are well served and protected. In San
Bernardino and Riverside, this standard is important with regards to taxi service because unlike
huge cities such as Los Angeles, San Francisco and San Diego, taxi service is needed for local
residents not business or tourist travelers. In particular, three groups of city residents are
disproportionately dependent upon taxis:
Taxi Service
1
Economics & Politics, tnc.
c
c
c
1. Elderly. Many elderly persons can no longer drive. It is also difficult for them to reach
fix line bus stops. In addition, older persons often fear exposure to danger on the streets,
a fear exacerbated in the evenings when they might need medical services. The elderly
would thus prefer increased access to door to door taxi service.
2. Handicapped. The handicapped are in similar positions to senior citizens. Many cannot
drive. It is difficult for them to reach bus stops. At night, should they need access to
doctors or to be picked up from a medical facility, they are almost completely dependent
upon taxi service.
3. Poor. The poor often cannot afford automobiles. In addition, they are most likely to live
in neighborhoods that, given a choice of other customers, taxi drivers would prefer to
avoid. If they cannot get taxi service, the only alternative for the poor is fix route bus
service.
In both cities, the total of persons in these groups is quite large. In San Bernardino, for instance,
the San Bernardino County Social Services Department indicates that some 59,083 city residents
were on public assistance,or 31.4% of the city's population in 2000. In Riverside, the Census
2000 Supplementary Survey indicated that 17.0% of residents were below the pational poverty
level.
Population Per Lee:al Taxicab. In asking whether the existing companies are providing a high
level of service to the puqlic, a question that arises is whether there are objective measures of
taxi service quality. A re"ljew of the literature on such service indicates that two standards are
most frequently applied. The first is the population per legal taxicabs. On this measure, data are
available for II of California's 13 mid-sized cities (Exhibit 2). They break into two groups:
. Four cities had; over 5,000 residents per cab with Modesto the highest (8,836) and
both Riverside (7.181) and San Bernardino (5,284) in this category.
. Seven cities had well under 3,000 residents per taxi with Glendale the highest (2,653).
Significantly, the four cities with the highest number of persons per taxi also were the four with
the least amount of competition. As indicated, Riverside and San Bernardino were the only
monopoly situations (Exhibit 1). Stockton and Modesto each had only three companies.
Exhibit 2.-Populatiol1 Per LCgill Cabs. 2002
California Cities, 190,000 to 450.000
8,836
#
,,/
~e'b
~:"
#~
~
~<>
".sf'
<>..i'
j'~
~l
o
J#~
~
./~
Note: Data not available for Huntington Beach &: Santa Ana
Source: Oties
Tul Service
2
Economics & ponu.., Inc.
c
c
c
Square Miles Per Le2al Taxicab. A second objective measure used to determine the quality of
taxi service is the number of square miles covered per legal taxicab. Data were also available
from 11 of the 13 cities in the 190,000-450,000 range (Exhibit 3). Here, seven cities had less
than one square mile per taxicab and four had more than one square mile per cab. The city with
the most area to cover per taxi was Riverside (2.09 miles). The next highest was San Beruardino
(1.65 miles). The least was Oakland (0.17). Again, the four with the most area per legal cab
were the same four that had the fewest number of companies.
ExllllJlt ') '--;("I,Ilt' r.1i1" , P\'1 l~lXICJb
Cellfolllle C,IIl'S 190 UUU to 450,000
0.17
/~//,,/~// /,,////
if ."
I Note: Dllanoc=c~ti~Beach I
Summary. Looking at the data, the cities of San Bernardino and Riverside are shown to be the
only cities of California's 13 communities with 190,000 to 450,000 people that confine their taxi
service to monopoly providers. They are two of four cities in this group with over 5,000
residents per legal taxicab. And, they ranked highest in terms of the square miles per taxi. In
each case, the cities with the least competition scored the poorest on these objective measures of
quality.
Given that San Bernardino'has a very high percentage of residents on public assistance (31.4%)
and Riverside has a large number of citizens living below the federal poverty level (17. O%), they
are communities in which the elderly, handicapped and poor appear to have a major need for taxi
service. These facts argue'. strongly that the introduction of competition into the taxi markets of
Riverside and San Bernardino is in the public interest on the grounds of both convenience and
necessity.
Why Cities Have Transitioned From
Monopoly to Competitive Taxi Service
Looking beyond objective measures of service quality, there is another dimension to the issue of
regulated monopoly versuS competitive suppliers for taxi service. That is the question of why
many cities are now transitioning towards the competitive model. This is an important
consideration since that is 'Yhat both Riverside and San Beruardino are being asked to do.
Whv Re2ulated MonoDolies? The use of regulated monopolies to supply taxicab service was
founded on the depressioncera notion that taxi companies are similar to such public utilities as
telephone, electricity, natural gas companies. As such, the public is best accommodated by
having one regulated organization supply this service as opposed to several companies in
competition. The historic logic for such monopolies was fivefold:
Taxi Service
3
Economics & PoUtlcs, Inc.
c
c
c
. Lar2e Investments. Cities once believed that there was a need to protect certain firms
from marketplace competition due to the huge financial investments that they needed to
make in order to commence operations. This rationale was applied to taxi companies
since in the early days, it was very expensive to set up two-way radio systems and
acquire fleets of cars. Like other utilities, they were thus given protection from
competitors so that they would have a chance to recoup their investments.
However, this logic no longer applies as the costs of establishing taxi service is not
extremely expensive. Compared to incomes, vehicles cost a fraction of what they did in
the Depression. Meanwhile, wireless communications is inexpensive in today's world.
As a result, the cost of entering the taxi business no longer justifies protecting firms from
competition.
. Unnecessary DUDUcation. In some sectors, cities believed that it would be a burden on
their infrastructure to have more than one company supplying services. This was obvious
with regards to telephone lines and power poles. The logic was extended to taxicabs out
of fear that too many competitive companies might clog city streets.
However, with so many people driving automobiles and so few taxicabs, this fear is now
unfounded. Even if the number of taxicabs tripled in the two communities, Riverside
would have just III legal cabs and San Bernardino would have just 108. These would
not be operating 24,hours a day and the number on the streets at anyone time would be a
minute fraction of the fleet of private vehicles on city streets.
. Oualitv. Cities once identified certain services like telephones and electricity as essential
to their citizens. They believed that the best way to ensure a high level of service was
through a single tightly regulated company. In the early days, many people did not have
automobiles. Taxi service was thus seen as a necessity to be provided by a single utility
with city regulation guaranteeing quality.
However, over the years, Americans have come to realize that competition is the most
efficient method cif ensuring that companies deliver services at the quality levels
demanded by their customers. Where competition exists, those companies ~at do not
perform well find ~ernselves losing clients. In fact, the benefits of competition are so
well established that govermnents now work hard to encourage more, not less of it. It is
thus an historical anomaly that consumers are not given the power of choice with regards
to taxi service. hnagine the outcry if cities decided that only a single municipally
regulated food or oil firm were allowed to provide these essential items to the public!
For cities like Riverside and San Bernardino, the issue of quality has taken on a new
dimension in recent times. As indicated, with so many people driving, the groups most
dependent upon tmri service are now the elderly, the handicapped and the poor. Quality
of service can thus be defined as having taxicabs readily accessible to these three groups.
Increasingly, cities' are finding that the best way to achieve this result is to foster
competition among taxi companies so that they each have an upside interest in adding to
their customer base.
. Goulrlnl!. On occasion, cities have tried to keep the prices of necessities low by allowing
only a single supplier of a service and tightly regulating their prices. This was applied to
taxi service in the ~elief that it was a necessity and that this was the way to keep down
the price. Here, it must be remembered that price gouging is a natural symptom of
,
Taxi Service
4
Economies & Politics, Ine.
c
c
c
markets dominated by sole providers as lack of competition allows the monopoly to
charge whatever prices they feel will maximize their profits. Where strong competition
exists, prices tend to be lower as firms compete for customers.
When a city permits a single taxicab company to operate as a monopoly, it is imperative
that fares be regulated to keep prices down. Even where a small amount of competition
is allowed, it is necessary to have some price regulation. However in this case, many
cities are finding that it is in the public interest to establish orice maximums and allow
companies to set prices below that level if they feel it is in their competitive interest.
. Public Safety. Cities always have had sectors whose activities impacted public safety.
These sectors are tightly regulated to ensure that unscrupulous operators do not harm the
public. As taxi service involves passengers entering a vehicle alone, the strategy for
protecting public sarety was to have all drivers work for a single tightly regulated firm.
However, today, cities regulate numerous activities with an eye towards public safety
without resorting to the establishment of monopoly providers.
Conclusion. The cities 'of San Bernardino and Riverside are unique among California's
communities of 190,000-450,000 in still using regulated monopolies to provide taxi service.
Further, it has been shown'that they, together with Stockton and Modesto, have the least amount
of competition and the highest number of persons and most area to cover per legal taxicab. In
addition, both cities haveJarge numbers of elderly, handicapped and poor persons who need
ready access to cabs.
Finally, it has been shown that cities are generally moving away from the use of regulated
monopolies to provide taxi service because each element of the Depression era rationale for
using this form of organization is no longer valid and the competitive model is a more efficient
method of obtaining quality service.
Taxi Service
5
Economics & Politics, Inc.
c
c
c
Studies Demonstrating the Benefits of Competition in the Taxicab Industry
"Taxi Service Market Considerations - Cities of San Bernardino & Riverside"
by John E. Husing, Ph.D.
Economics & Politics, Inc.
Highland, California
May 2002
"Opening Boston's Taxicab Market"
by John E. Kramer, Director of Communications
and William H. Mellor, President
Institute for Justice
Washington, D.C.
Prepared for Pioneer Institute's "1995 Better Government Competition"
"Open the Door to Portland's Taxi Entrepreneurs"
by John E. Kramer, Director of Communications
and William H. Mellor, President
Institute for Justice
Washington, D.C.
Published in the Portland Oregonian newspaper on February 17, 1997
Provided by Cascade Policy Institute
Portland, Oregon
"Regulation and the Urban Marketplace"
by Stephen Goldsmith, Mayor of Indianapolis, Indiana
January 1997
Published in Regulation by the Cato Institute
Washington, D.C.
c
c
Page Two
"Putting Customers First - Taxicab Reform in the Greater Toronto Area"
by Consumer Policy Institute of Toronto, Canada
April 1997
"Taxicab Regulation in Ohio's Largest Cities"
by The Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions
Dayton, Ohio 45402
"Scared Yellow: An Analysis of Taxicab Competition in Allegheny County"
by Eric Montari, Research Associate
Allegheny Institute for Public Policy
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania
January 2000
"Taken for a $1 Billion Taxi Ride"
by Terence Corcoran, Columnist
Toronto Globe and Mail
AprilS, 1997
"1998 Public Convenience and Necessity Hearing Report for Taxicab Medallions to the Police
Commission, City and County of San Francisco"
by John Ehrlich, Captain of Support Services
Member Mayor's Taxicab Task Force
From August 1997 - April 1998 PC&N hearings
"Reforming Taxicab Regulations: Focus on the Passenger"
by Rudy Svorinich, Jr.
Los Angeles City Councilman
Transportation Committee Member
1998
C Published by Metro Investment Report
c
c
c
Page Three
"Taxi Regulation in Wisconsin - Law and Policy"
by Peter Carstensen, Professor of Law
University of Wisconsin Law School
April 3, 2000
Presentation to the Madison, Wisconsin Parking and Transit Commission
"Toward a 21st Century Taxicab Regulatory Framework: The Case of Madison"
by Samuel R. Staley, Ph.D., Director of Urban Futures Program
Reason Public Policy Institute
Los Angeles, California
June 5, 2000
"An Economic Analysis of Taxicab Regulation in Portland, Oregon"
by John W. Boroski and Gerard C.S. Mildner
Portland State University
April 1998
o
o
o
Peter Withers
AAA Inland Empire Cab
3000 Date Street
Riverside, CA 92507
Dear Peter,
Healthy competition is the essence of our free enterprise system. It follows that your
endeavor to bring choice to Inland Empire residents should be good for both patrons and
the local economy.
A number of our fans are elderly or disabled. Having a choice of taxi service will
hopefully spur competition for riders, improve service and help keep the focns on
providing the best taxi service possible.
c
As business operators, we know how important it is to provide customer service and
create repeat customers. If you can accomplish those goals, your new operation should be
a smashing success.
Sincerely,
'tfW~
Doug Vair
Director of Development
C
~"o'n~l'19"
v.j~t. 'j
J20(~~/
C'hamp\o'\\'"
280 South 'E' Street. San Bernardino, California 92401
Phone 909-888-9922 . FAX 909-888-5251
www.stampedebaseball.com
-~~.
~
Seattle Mariners
Minor League Affiliate
c
Executive Board
President
Dr. Paul Scott
President Elect
Donna Hunter
Vice President
Claudia Stoll
Treasurer
Bill Calvert
Secretary
Louise Lorenzen
i'~~~"'"""'\
~t Highland SENIC)R Center
Highland District Council on Aging, Inc.
"Seniors Helping Seniors"
July 10,2002
Mayor and City Council
City of San Bernardino
Dear Ladies and Gentlemen:
I am the Executive Director of the Highland Senior Center (which is located on
the grounds of Patton State Hospital in the City of San Bernardino). I am writing in
support of the effort to establish a second taxicab service in San Bernardino.
The Highland Senior Center serves our senior population with meals, activities,
and companionship. We have observed that a large number of our seniors are no longer
Board of Directors able to drive, for both health and economic reasons. In fact, one of our services is to
arrange for transportation for seniors, both to and from the Center, and for other
essential trips, such as to the doctor's office.
Past President
Mark Edwards
Tom Battaile, Jr.
Fred Berry
CJe Booth
Margaret Hill
Doris Jaynes
Audrey Martinez
Alice Miller
Marty Miller
Nancy NelBOn
Don Rude
Emerals St. John
John Tackett
Executive Director
Penny Lilbum
c
In arranging such transportation, the current taxi service is considered a last
resort, and is seldom used. This is for two reasons. First, the current taxis service is
slow, taking along time to get to the Center to pick up the seniors. Second, the current
service is very expensive, beyond the means of many seniors who live on a fixed
income.
If an additional taxi service will result in faster service and lower cost for the
seniors in our community, I am fully su ortive of establishing that second service.
e Truly Y oursn
~'(f\ ;LkJ L.{;\}IL--...
Penny Lilb
Executive D ctor, Highland Senior Center
3102 E. Highland Avenue, Patton, CA 92369 . P.O. Box 948, Highland, CA 92346
(909) 862.8104 . Fax (909) 862.8196 . e-mail- HighSenCtr@aol.com
. ARROWHEAD UNITED WAY AGENCY
c
c
c
John Anaya, Sr.
Volunteer Advocate for the Americans With Disabilities Act
1450 North LaCadena Drive, Colton, CA 92324
(909) 218 5886
July 10, 2002
Mayor Valles
San Bernardino City Council
San Bernardino, CA
Dear Mayor Valles,
My name is John Anaya Sr. I am a person with a disability and am a volunteer
advocate for the Americans With Disability Act.
I would like to take some time to share my own personal story and my experiences
with transportation in San Bernardino. There are a number of ways to travel in the
area. One is the bus, which does not run in the evening hours. Thus there are times
when I would like to attend a social event in the city of San Bernardino but am
unable to because the time schedules and routes mean that I am prevented from
taking wheelchair accessible buses.
My girlfriend is also a person with a disability - we are both wheelchair users. There
are times when we would like to go see a movie or to a baseball game at San
Bernardino stadium but there are neither buses nor accessible taxi cabs available.
AAA Inland Empire Can has accessible vans which we can use in areas outside San
Bernardino but at present they are prevented from offering service to people like me
and my girlfriend within the City. I would like to see this company extend its services
in the City of San Bernardino. I believe that persons with disabilities and senior
citizens should be able to have the freedom of mobility to travel to medical
appointments, visit friends, do their shopping and enjoy the evening hours.
It is also important to note the real health dangers arising from high summer
temperatures and poor air quality. There is a high health risk for senior citizens and
wheelchair users forced to wait at bus stops in the open air. This situation exposes
them to both respiratory and heatstroke problems which could be avoided with
greater access to reliable point-to-point transportation.
As an advocate for the city of San Bernardino I feel it would be a great benefit for
senior citizens and persons with disabilities in this community to have this service
through AAA Inland Empire Cab company extended to San Bernardino. I now use
this service, as does my lady friend, and we find it of great benefit - but we are
prevented from using it within the city of San Bernardino. A choice of transportation
is definitely in the interest of people like us.
YJX:' ~ 31.
John Anaya, Sr.
Roll.n. .ea.-e. Inc:.
'ndependent """,'n. Center
Servin. San Bernardino. Inyo and Mono Counties
February 24,2002
Dennis Cole
Chairman, Bureau of Franchise
San Bernardino City Hall
San Bernardino, Calif. 92401
Dear Chairman Cole:
c
I am writing this letter of support on behalf of the many consumers with
disabilities who have a need for 24-hour accessible transit options. Public
transportation at this time cannot accommodate this very important, and special
need. At present many people of disabilities must pattem their lives around
specific hours of public transit, which gives them a lack of spontaneity in their
lives. From time to time we have events where we bring many people with
disabilities to our community for special events that we offer. In the past we have
found it to be a great challenge finding ways to shuttle out of town wheelchair
users to various venues while visiting. With the addition of Inland Empire Cab
this will give us more flexibility when planning events in the City of San
Bernardino.
It has recently come to my attention that Inland Empire Cab has applied for a
franchise from the City of San Bernardino. It is my understanding that Inland
Empire Cab has a number of wheelchair accessible vehicles in their current fleet.
Although Bell Cab has some accessible vans available more vans are needed to
meet the growing needs of persons with disabilities who are being empowered to
take a more active roll in work and community life in general.
I fully support having Inland Empire Cab become part of the solution for the
accessible transit needs of my consumers and the persons with disabilities in the
community at large. Your consideration is greatly appreciated.
c
Sincerely
vtw ro~~
Fran Bates
Executive Director
c
TAXI SERVICE IN THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
STATEMENT OF PUBLIC CONVENIENCE AND NECESSITY
At present, only one taxicab company is permitted to operate within the City of
San Bernardino. No permit can be issued to allow a competing taxi service in the
City unless the City Council determines that the .public convenience and
necessity" requires such competition. (City Ordinance 5.76.050)
To determine "public convenience and necessity" the City Council takes into
consideration a number of factors, including:
. The public demand for a competing service
. The adequacy or inadequacy of service being provided by the existing
taxicab company
As the representative of an organization or institution whose clients, customers
and/or members are reliant on taxicab service for transportation it is my belief
that:
. Public demand exists for additional taxicab service in the City of San
C.' . Bernardino
. My clients, customers and/or members are not being adequately served
by the existing taxicab company
. The "public convenience and necessity" will be better served by, the
comm::~Of:eb;:;";e;~"::.:::.~. fl~. ". (
J(~F~ 6fl ~~ .~ ~C~~~~
;; ~-jf- . ~cJ? ~~/ t:JAAJL ~c0 _ ,.~~
_ oJ / a-v--e.~U ,. A~~~ ,?J~ V&-
.4.fl/1~ . ~-= .~, Co..;;2 rcr-~..eAl.
Date: c> ,..z
;:2,
Name: 13 / II. tJ, /; 1/ / ~ ?. c, ~ ~
Title: 0e-.K e/ A C:;;'et.l7 '
C OrQanization: AmT;(A K.
.FEB-06-01 03:17PM FROM-INLAND EMPIRE CAB
c
c-
c
9093693049
HC5 P.Ol
TAXI SERVICE IN THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
STATEMENT OF PUBLIC CONVENIENCE AND NECESSITY
At present, only ~ taxicab company is permitted to operate within the City of
San Bernardino. No permit can be issued to allow a competing taxi service in the
City unless the City Council determines that the .public convenience and
necessity" requires such competition. (City Ordinance 5.76.050)
To determine "public convenience and necessity" the City Council takes into
consideration a number of factors. including:
. The public demand for a competing service
. The adequacy or inadequacy of service being provided by the existing
taxicab company
As the representative of an organization or institution whose clients, customers
and/or members are reliant on taxicab service for transportation it is my belief
that:
. Public demand exists for additional taxicab service in the City of San
Bernardino
. My clients. customers and/or members are not being adequately served
by the existing taxicab company
. The "public convenience and necessity" will be better served by the
introduction of taxicab competition in the City of San Bemardino.
Hi9
Comments:
Or!-> t-...'~0l.<A Oc...c-"-*'" Cf'o'V:l we.. ~ ~
trD1 p"w" ^,-c'?f4 -1TMA (~ g:4~fHYI)' J-tu ~ w;L.-
fA.,O -k ~ -ff>bY>'l. a.. -Ia.4 i fJvYtt:l we- aM Io-U ~
-fI..J tuMf ~ b.R. frFYVI aM. J,..n..ty -h CM1 /MwY ~ tl.- Ae1f'
~~~ 1<.. M.:"'-'t" J,/u, JW><d 'I ~+ ~
SiQned'::I:iiMJ~A......LL Date: Fe-h U I ~O').
Name: CA/Zr;~ tl. UJIAtJ~
Title: 7ic4w ~
Oraanization: /hn-+r~
.
t
TAXI SERVICE IN THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
STATEMENT OF PUBLIC CONVENIENCE AND NECESSITY
At present, only one taxicab company is permitted to operate within the City of
San Bernardino. No permit can be issued to allow a competing taxi service in the
City unless the City Council determines that the "public convenience and
necessity" requires such competition. (City Ordinance 5.76.050)
To determine "public convenience and necessity" the City Council takes into
consideration a number of factors, including:
· The public demand for a competing service
· The adequacy or inadequacy of service being provided by the existing
taxicab company
As the representative of an organization or institution whose clients, customers
and/or members are reliant on taxicab service for transportation it is my belief
that
c
. Public demand exists for additional taxicab service in the City of San
Bernardino
. My clients, customers and/or members are not being adequately served
by the existing taxicab company
· The "public convenience and necessity" will be better served by the
introduction of taxicab competition in the City of San Bernardino.
Comments:
QfYL (Q~ ;) ~ fwi ~ c.o~ ohoiil
-&rnqtJc ob woit XlrmY.oJr1d tJP :tJtIl rnvJd . J &JL
fY}'W}'GUJOv"K m .DVm;}aA ~TJ ~~ ~
Date: ) - {) i-or:)
dJ )!1ho Orl-
Signed:
c
Name: ) ,LJArzLit
Title: dfPt (llrJ?L
Organization: :=qJ.f11? 1, m .oTo Q
t
TAXI SERVICE IN THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
STATEMENT OF PUBLIC CONVENIENCE AND NECESSITY
At present, only one taxicab company is permitted to operate within the City of
San Bernardino. No permit can be issued to allow a competing taxi service in the
City unless the City Council determines that the "public convenience and
necessity" requires such competition. (City Ordinance 5.76.050)
To determine "public convenience and necessity" the City Council takes into
consideration a number of factors, including:
· The public demand for a competing service
. The adequacy or inadequacy of service being provided by the existing
taxicab company
As the representative of an organization or institution whose clients, customers
and/or members are reliant on taxicab service for transportation it is my belief
that
c
. Public demand exists for additional taxicab service in the City of San
Bernardino
. My clients, customers and/or members are not being adequately served
by the existing taxicab company
. The "public convenience and necessity" will be better served by the
introduction of taxicab competition in the City of San Bernardino.
Comments:
~ '-k, ~ [e LL C 4 b ,t/'t' Y2; 't 7 S P'f 11 Vile
Cb,c-Z ~ uc" LVe(-{
l Clv' c( lor1cJ
t 1f'Vl 0.{.. ("J r- -+-/1'+ III -I- 0 <;).., o <-c) vp
;"
,i/ ,
//] (.~'r (/ it "l
Date:
1-~3-o~
'-.....i .
s............ / ((:" -,~ ( ,
IQIICU+-_",i>. (/ I /[,;'-t ,
../ . , . _.
c
Name: t1 ?Il.S' J: R/lIC. 1M c /["r;...~/;),f/e/<'S
Title: 1C1cY/y l0~S
Orqanization: Ca..1/ /(\ G.....f/o~ Gnvv{) --';'.a<>-<...-L-
.
c
c
c
TAXI SERVICE IN THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
STATEMENT OF PUBLIC CONVENIENCE AND NECESSITY
At present, only one taxicab company is permitted to operate within the City of
San Bernardino. No permit can be issued to allow a competing taxi service in the
City unless the City Council determines that the .public convenience and
necessity. requires such competition. (City Ordinance 5.76.050)
To determine "public convenience and necessity. the City Council takes into
consideration a number of factors, including
· The public demand for a competing service
. The adequacy or inadequacy of service being provided by the existing
taxicab company
As the representative of an organization or institution whose clients. customers
anj/or members are reliant on taxicab service for transportation it is my belief
that
. Public demand exists for additional taXicab service in the City of San
Bernardino
. My clients. customers andlor members are not being adequately serve:J
by the eXisting taXicab company
. The public convenience and necessity" will be beller served by the
Introjuctlon of taxicab competition in the City of San Bernardino
Comments:.J(//(Jl,V ilia '--/akiS DUfl<. 3u n7;^-.I /)JCKc.
f 0 17U2<A- VL6L Lj./IJLL- vJ-(. v(!.ALI. 73U
.' {c K..l ell L } . C^- O'L 12-- ----k'AJ. (nt.-i (]uA.-lo}/)-f1/(25
.JIu -h;"J-J.. LA.X ~)f--:V /1 J /i7C" jo WL:U: f, a I1-L+ /OI) 7f-K:..
u./Z(. u/-JS< -+ '+ LA. J l;r 0
s;"n.~,~i ""1/ ;d"u"t?
Name: t1:. I-...;/yrl<j MJ241?1U
Title: 117 A}J;q...C7 ~f..z
Orqanization: /IQ;-7 ':?/5 <-f BOX5
Date: 1 / C::F31 [i Q...
I t-
I,. 9-A/J BrYl1aE..o/AJO
c
TAXI SERVICE IN THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
STATEMENT OF PUBLIC CONVENIENCE AND NECESSITY
At present, only one taxicab company is permitted to operate within the City of
San Bernardino. No permit can be issued to allow a competing taxi service in the
City unless the City Council determines that the "public convenience and
necessity" requires such competition. (City Ordinance 5.76.050)
To determine "public convenience and necessity" the City Council takes into
consideration a number of factors, including:
· The public demand for a competing service
. The adequacy or inadequacy of service being provided by the existing
taxicab company
As the representative of an organization or institution whose clients, customers
an:jlor members are reliant on taxicab service for transportation it is my belief
that
.
C .
.
Public demand exists for additional taxicab service in the City of San
Bernardino
MI clients. customers and/or members are not being adequatell serve:]
by the existing taxicab company
The ..public convenience and necessity". will be better served by the
Introduction of taxicab competition in the City of San Bernardino
Comments:
S;Q"d, ~
,
V V/~~
Date:
/-L.J-..:>"L
Name: 'Nt'<-. V .4t1d.l#~
c
Tille: -zJ/tl",.r-'tf. 6r: .u.rUA.~1
Orqanization: j(, '/".:/,1>1 ,.r- Sn,v rJuNl"uel/./V4
.
, .
I
TAXI SERVICE IN THE CITY OF SAN BERNARDINO
.
STATFMFNT m: 01 BLIC CONVENIENCE AND NECESSITY
~
mpany is permitted to operate within the City of
be issued to allow a competing taxi service in the
ermines that the .public convenience and
tition. (City Ordinance 5.76.050)
upe Child Development Program
1633 W. 5th Sl./ P.O. Box' 7130
San Bernardino, CA 92411
PAUUNE BECERRA. lliAlcIor
AURORA FLORES. Bookkeeper
JULIANNE G. MARTINEZ, Secretery
CARMEN R. LUAS. Maintenance
(909) 885-0510
(909) 884.5914
Center: (909) 885-7422
ce and necessity. the City Council takes into
rs. including:
. I he public demand for a competing service
. The adequacy or inadequacy of service being provided by the existing
taxicab company
As the representative of an organization or institution whose clients, customers
and/or members are reliant on taxicab service for transportation it IS my belief
that
c
. Public demand eXists for additional taxicab service m the City of San
Bernardino
. r'/I; clients. customers and/or members are not bemg a::Jequat""l! s."u-= J
by the eXisting taXicab company
. Th", publiC convenience and necessity" Will be better served by the
Ir,lrO:h:tlon of taXicab competition In the City of Sa'! Bernardmo
com:;<~~ -Iff~ ~ .
~-a.k~ O-p~ ~k~
SiqneO/)H/~ &~
Dale:
I /.3tJ /~:;...
I
Nalnc:G~~ -&.t~
Title: J.P. .iA..u~
OrQanizalion: fidA. A ..0 A ). to" d..LJ. JJJ .i.J ~ .
PI-\ 01\/ E "
c
.
.
,
c
c
c
"
Transcript
City of San Bernardino
Franchise Bureau
September 8,1998
(grant of franchise to Bell Cab Company)
RECEIVE~.-Clrr CLERK
'02 Jtl 31 P 4 :50
Note: The following transcript was prepared from the City of San Bernardino tape recording of the
September 8, 1998 Franchise Bureau meeting. Only where an individual identifies him or herself, or where
the speaker's ideutity is clearly apparent, is the person named in this transcript. The various Bureau
members did not identify themselves and are not, therefore, named in the following transcript
.
:ft- d. S-
'6//1/6'L
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 1 of 20
Q. I'd like to call the meeting to order of the Bureau of Franchises. It's September the 8,
1998, at about 3 minutes 2:00 p.m. in the afternoon. I don't believe we've got anybody
here who would like to comment on any items not on the agenda but if there is, they have
got five minutes to do so.
[Unintelligible comments]
Q. Since there is no one here for public comments, we will close that portion of the
meeting. Has everybody had an opportunity to review the minutes from the last, previous
meeting of July 14th?
Q. [female] I move that the minutes be approved as submitted.
Q. I second it.
Q. Moved and seconded that the minutes be approved as written. All those in favor?
[affinnative group response] Opposed? [no response] Motion is carried. The only item
that we have on the agenda today is the consideration of an application for taxicab service
in San Bernardino that's by Bell Cab Company, and I believe that Scott Schaefer is going
to give us a presentation. The floor is yours if you would like to...
Schaefer: I will try to keep it relatively short. There is more papers here than
conversation. I passed out three documents and I will speak to some of the documents. I
will start offby introducing the [unintelligible] that are here today. Rusty Dayton is in
charge of our local community marketing out here in San Bernardino County. I am the
Vice President with Bell Cab.
We run about 300 cabs between Los Angeles County, Riverside County and San
Bernardino County, from the High Desert, from Yucaipa to out towards Agoura, so I am
in my car quite a bit. I apologize that we were here in February and didn't come back
now until the summer. We were doing some more studying, and then there was some
discussion with the other cab company about market share and Omnitrans and we have
solved some of those issues.
The senior management at Bell has about one hundred years of experience, and there are
four principals that manage the company, and they have run companies in Los Angeles
and Riverside. [Names of two individuals] are in a meeting in Los Angeles or they
would have been here.
I'll highlight some ofthe issues in this, and then I'll speak to some other issues. The
graphics that I have passed out talk about the ordinance speaks to one cab per every 2500
residents. Currently, with about 195,000 residents, there is sufficient room to add cabs,
assuming the Franchise Bureau thinks there is enough market for service. Some of the
things that contribute to that demand are Metrolink, and I will read from the SANBAG
work plan that I just picked up: "The Metrolink ridership here in San Bernardino County,
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 2 of 20
since 1992, has been ihe most successful of any of the lines. The three Metrolink lines
serving San Bernardino County are continuing to experience growih. At the end of
February '98 ofihis year, average daily patronage on the San Bernardino line was 8,028,
an increase of 8 percent increase over one year ago. On the Riverside line, the average
daily patronage was 4,400, an increase of over 18 percent. The Inland Empire / Orange
County line was 1,617, an increase of 16 percent over the same period a year ago.
Together in February 1998, these three lines carried nearly 55 percent ofthe total
Metrolink service. The San Bernardino line is by far the most successful and is currently
experiencing some overcrowding on most ofihe trains. There is currently plans before
SANBAG to add additional service for the Metrolink Service." Our company operates a
large amount of Metrolink feeder service, wiih cabs and vans, all the way from Burbank
to Covina. We are not doing any currently in San Bernardino County but we hope maybe
a partnership with the City or Omnitrans will promote more ofihat to increase the
ridership on the line.
I have also passed out, in that same packet, there is some letters of support, and ihere is
also some letters of complaints about the existing service, but I didn't want to focus on
the existing service, just what we could bring to the table. The Omnitrans survey that
was done and coordinated, or asked for, by the Board of Directors ofOmnitrans. I have
highlighted two different, or at least one tab, and it talks about service levels. The Board
funds about 120,000 cab trips a year. And on one of them, it says, "38% of the survey
respondents commented that they often have to wait too long for their cab. Many
recounted having to wait from two to four hours to be picked up after calling ihe cab
company, or be stranded." We are now currently providing Omnitrans service in every
city in the County wiih the exception of San Bernardino, which has caused a lot of
confusion because ihey have not redone the brochure. So we are not doing as much
volume as we would like to. The current brochure only lists the two Yellow Cab
operators: the one ihat operates from Fontana east through here, and then the one that
operates from Fontana through Montclair. The Board is now going to issue a brochure
out next month, so based upon this hearing, they mayor may not include San Bernardino
as part of the Omnitrans project.
In the application, I spoke about wheelchair accessible taxicabs. The current provider
doesn't have any. Where ihe large provider, ABA Taxicabs, in LA County, and I ihink
ihe only provider in San Bernardino County, there is only three cab providers currently,
there is two different Yellow Cab franchises and ourselves. Of the 36 cabs in the
application, six of those would be wheelchair cabs. Actually, I spoke to Lee at ihe start
of the meeting, we were hoping to amend the application to 42. We have recently signed
a contract wiih the Lorna Linda V A which transports a lot of veterans from the High
Desert into the lower portion here. So we actually could use some additional service, and
those would also be wheelchair cabs.
The last pass-out was statistics that I got from the Department of Welfare and Social
Services about Welfare-to-Work. There will be over a million dollars from SANBAG
available for local transportation vouchers, cabs and bus passes, trying to get people off
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 3 of 20
the Welfare rolls. The second page talks about San Bernardino specifically. Of
particular note, the City of San Bernardino has gone from 30% of its population on
Welfare last year to 32%, a drop of more than 10,000 people. In addition to finding
employment, they felt that they needed to critically support some of the transportation to
get the people to and from jobs, and the transportation, or the cab vouchers and bus
passes, will be the means to help assist that. And we think that will help stimulate more
demand.
There was some discussion brought up in these meetings, and the other provider is not
here, there was some discussion about congestion or too many cabs would be a bad thing.
And I am not supporting deregulation. Deregulation would saturate the market. These
cabs would work the region so its not as if these 42 cabs would be sitting here congestion
in San Bernardino. They'd actually be multi-licensed so they could work anywhere in
the County. But there would be enough cabs then available so that the service times
would be within ten to fifteen minutes which should stimulate more demand instead of
reducing the demand and the drivers having concerns about not making an adequate
revenue.
I mentioned the proposal about the anti-drunk driving programs. We will work closely
with the Police Department, and Students Against Drunk Driving and Mothers Against
Drunk Driving, to make sure that the taxicabs are used in both of those programs.
We are one of two providers now at the Ontario International Aitport and that is probably
where that new terminal opens on September 27th which they forecast that terminal is a
growth of almost 200%. That is probably a little bit unrealistic on the short-run, but we
think that gradually that ridership will increase. We are getting between 200 and 400
calls a month now from people for return service back that we take to San Bernardino.
So we think that would be another element for the Board to consider.
I will let Rusty talk for a couple minutes and then the Board may ask some questions and
I will respond to those questions.
Rusty: Hi, I'm Rusty Dayton and I am the Marketing Director for the Inland Empire and I
work closely with the communities. Among the things that I would like talk about today
are our drivers. Our drivers are uniformed, they wear black and white: white shirts, black
pants, and ties. When they are picked up, and it doesn't matter what the citizen or client
is, they are always in uniform. Our cabs are magenta and white. They're clean. They're
air conditioned, and we do what we can to make the comfort level for our people. Our
drivers are also drug tested, and their clearances are given through the Sheriffs
Department here on Third Street.
The next thing I would like to talk about is a little bit about the marketing. I am actively
involved in the majority of communities that we participate in, in that in Montclair, I am
in the Neighborhood Partnership Program. In the City of Rancho Cucamonga, I work
with the senior citizens, and I am just not getting involved with the senior citizens in
Fontana. They go to lunches, they have their hot meals, and they need transportation
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8,1998
Page 4 of20
back. They also need timely transportation, and that's one of the missions that Bell Cab
has had, and that's to get our seniors back in a timely fashion. We don't like the two and
three hour waits, and believe me, as becoming Ornniservers, we've heard our share of
complaints from our seniors. So that is a level of interest for me, and I do actively
participate in the senior citizens' communities, the parks, and things of that nature. And
we also do after school care. We take children to and from school. As a matter offact, I
have contacted the San Bernardino School District, and we are going to hopefully
participate in their program where their children are handicapped, taking them to and
from school, to help alleviate the purchase of more buses. We do that currently in the
cities of Chino and Chino Hills, we do it in Ontario, and we do it in Fontana just recently.
The last thing I would like to tell you is that we're a family service in that we also
provide car seats in all of our vehicles for children that are going to be transported to and
from the airports and things of that nature. This is the actual car seat. A [unintelligible]
complaint has always been that the car seat is too large to fit into the trunk along with
luggage, and groceries, and all the other things that go along with it. This accommodates
my driver, who needs that space, but it also assures the safety of that child.
I am an active participant here in the community. I live in Mentone. I have lived in San
Bernardino, and I have been familiar with this community for better than 17 years, and I
would love an opportunity to service you. Thank you.
Q. Did you get a packet?
Q. Yes, and I read the material that was sent to me.
Q. Do we have any questions? We can go around the table. David, why don't you start.
David: Yeah, I had a couple of questions here. One of them is: dispatching. Where will
they be dispatched from? Ontario or from...
A. Currently, out of Ontario, but we are looking to also get some space here locally in
San Bernardino. It has been our experience that the closer we are to the community, the
better the service levels are, and the involvement. Okay?
Q. That will be in San Bernardino?
A. Yes. And we can supply that new address to the staff.
Q. The other thing that I was concerned about: We just went through the ambulance
program and they have 2 million dollars worth of insurance on all, for their vehicles. I
notice you have one million.
C A. Right.
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 5 of20
Q. Is that statewide, or is that...
A. Actually, that's, because we are one ofthe ADA providers for LA County, we carry,
mostly cab companies only carry 150. I think the current cab company here in town only
carries 350.
Q. Per person.
A. Combined single limit...
Q. Combined single limit.
A. .. . and I am not an insurance guy, usually. But years back, we couldn't even get a
million dollars insurance because they considered cabs to be high risk, being out there 24
hours a day at all times. So we haven't been asked to get more than that. But the MT A
and Omnitrans asked us to carry the million.
Q. I wondered, since you are dealing in wheelchair, whether that's required for more, or
something that we need to look into, for insurance? I don't know.
Q. I believe that meets the City's requirement for liability insurance.
Q. Okay.
Q. Well then the state requirement for transportation has gone to 750 transporter. So, if
they have a million, that's...
Q. Okay. Then the only other thing is: are we going to put this up for review like we do
the ambulance once a year? Give them a five year contract but review their record every
year?
Q. They constantly report to. . .
Q. To Lee...
Q....to Lee's office, and as far as their drivers are concerned, they would have to be
registered with the City Police Department, and they go through their checks for any
convictions of a sexual nature or whatever that would make them not quality to be...
Q. Cause I've heard some horror stories about them.
Q. That's one of the questions that I have. As a matter of fact, I have several questions
about that aspect, and also about health. So, my first question, I'll just take off on that
point. You said that you go through the San Bernardino Police Department for checks on
your drivers?
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 6 of20
c
A. Currently, we don't, no. The Code requires that we go through the San Bernardino
Police Department. We go through the Sheriffs Department which is out here, so we
would also get the Police Department to go through that same check, or if they felt
comfortable not redundantly, actually using the Sheriffs Department, we prefer to use
the Sheriffs Department.
Q. Okay then, is there any special license, is this a Class III we are talking about? Or is it
a Class B?
A. No, it's a traditional Class III license.
Q. Class III.
A. They also go through additional sensitivity and wheelchair training cause of the
wheelchair cabs.
Q. Okay, and dealing with accidents, are you on the system, what we call the "pulse
system?"
A. The D&B [?] pulse, correct.
c
Q. Now, your drivers are drug tested. Now, is that a random sampling, or is that a group,
or is that specific?
A. Upon condition of employment, they go through the initial drug screening, and then
every three months, there is a random pull.
Q. A random pull? Meaning that if you have 400 drivers, you would pull a sample out of
the 400, all 400?
A. One out of every four drivers. 25%. Through the year, quarterly, all of them will
have been done. The drivers are less transient than you would think by watching Danny
DeVito on television. So, we don't go through a lot of drivers. And the interesting thing
here, the ethnic make-up of cab drivers is not necessarily typical of most cab drivers, as
opposed to Los Angeles. So they stay with us for quite a while.
Q. Okay, well my concern was that most ofthe drug programs are fairly inefficient in that
they pull from a pool, and so, if you do have a great number of drivers, very few of them
are being tested. So, and being random, its really not effective, its...
A. The current situation is supposed to provide that everyone gets tested in addition, at
least once a year. Potentially, they could be tested at least four times a year.
C Q. Okay, so they are tested at least once a year?
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 7 of 20
c
A. Yes. And then if any ofthem have been charged with accidents, they also go through
the test, just to clarify that.
Q. Okay, now you seem to run the gamut of transporting: the baby seat, meaning that you
are hauling infants; and then you specifically spoke about senior citizens. The baby seat,
I got a glance of it. That pad, is that in the back or the front?
A. [Rusty] It can go either position. Typically, we do not put children in the front seat.
The requirement, by law, we also have an infant car seat. This is not an infant car seat.
This is for two years and above. The infant car seat is in the back, and it is turned
backwards.
Q. Okay.
A. And that is upon request. This one is for any child that we happen to be picking up,
and if we are at the airport, if we are at a hotel, or whatever, we use this one. And this
one is in the back seat, as well. And its set up, it meets all state requirements, and
Federal guidelines. And what this does, this is fastened onto the back, and then this is
how the child is positioned. All of our drivers are trained in this, as well as wheelchair,
so that they know how to set up the, and it's convenient for the child.
C Q. SO, a thrust to the front, the child would move approximately how far from the seat?
A. I think the guidelines here, I think it's, it's less than 12 inches, because this is so firm
and tight. And what it is, it's geared to your shoulder harness, and your shoulder harness
doesn't go more than, what is it, 6 inches?
Q. Okay. Any training for handling senior citizens?
A. [Rusty continues] Absolutely. Because we are access certified, our drivers go through
training for seniors, as well as wheelchair.
Q. And they carry a certification?
A. They carry a metal [?] certification for it, they carry access training to be access
certified. Yes. And it shows that they comply with ADA.
Q. Are the drivers part of a union?
A. [Schaefer] Nope.
Q. So they are non-union?
A. Correct.
c
Q. Are they owner-operators?
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 8 of 20
c
A. We have owner-operators. None of them in San Bernardino County are. We have
offered some of them that option. We haven't had any takers. Interestingly enough,
probably 90% of the cabs we operate in LA County are all owner-operators.
Q. One point about the cabs themselves. You will be employing, or deploying, about
how many cabs?
A. 42 in this eastern region. We are running about 45 to 50 right now, from Fontana
through Montclair.
Q. Do you have any servicing of those vehicles in San Bernardino?
A. None currently, but we will be doing it here locally.
Q. Establishing your own place, or involving some company?
A. Ifwe were successful today, we will be leasing some property right here.
Q. Okay. So then revenue would be generated here?
c
A. Uh hah. [affirmative]
Q. You mentioned the access program. Will the qualifications for riders be the same as
they are, the guidelines?
A. The access program gets confusing because we are the largest. . .
Q. .. .we are talking about Dial-A-Ride, yeah... it's the different...
A. We are currently doing the ongoing [unintelligible] ...the access training to qualify
Ornnitrans.. .
Q. . ..the access training, yeah. But the Dial-A-Cab, will that be the same criteria as now,
the same rates and everything?
A. Yes. Yes. Actually our rates are cheaper in this packet. Our rates are $1.60 a mile.
The current cab provider is $1.80 a mile. So those rates hopefully will stimulate more
business for us with the Ornnitrans contract.
Q. And then you will have airport transportation from San Bernardino City?
A. Yes. Yes.
C Q. Which we haven't had.
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 9 of20
c
A. The current company isn't providing it?
Q. What are the rates?
A. The rates are $1.90 when you get in the vehicle, and $1.60 a mile.
Q. To the airport?
A. No. We would offer [unintelligible] ... to the airport, but I think it runs about $24.00
from here.
Q. Does everybody have the ordinances having to do with taxicabs and ambulances? I
passed that out at one ofthe previous meetings. Basically, Bell Cab has to show us, as a
Board, the need for additional taxicab service within the City in order for us to grant them
a franchise. I believe that the ordinance that sets forth, somewhere in here, the number of
cabs within the population base is one per every 2,500. And, unfortunately Yellow Cab
isn't here today, and I don't know how many cabs they currently have in operation.
A. They are licensed for 35.
c
Q. They are licensed for 35?
A. Yeah, which mayor may not reflect that they are even running 35.
Q. This says one for every 5,242.
A. Well, that's my...
Q. That's actual. . .
A. That's... I was comparing actual cabs versus population. The suggestion in the Code
is that there should be no more than one cab for every 2,500 residents. And that's on
page 338, or 576060.
Q. Using the same population base as we did for the ambulance service, that would work
out.
Q. The figures of 183,474. Is that the most recent?
Q. 184,000 what?
Q. Residents in the City of San Bernardino?
C A. Correct.
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 10of20
Q. Yes. That is the one we have maintained in the census.
Q. I have one other thing. We have a smog problem. That's obvious. It's pretty
obvious. I notice the age of these vehicles are three to seven years, or actually, four to
seven years. In some cases, they. . .
A. We have a vehicle schedule. But we have replaced probably 70% of those since we
were last here. Before we put anything in service here, we will get staff the new vehicle
schedule.
Q. Okay.
A. And part of that would be the Ontario Airport opening. The airport has suggested that
the cabs be no older than 5 years. More for esthetic reasons than any [unintelligible]
reasons. But, there is a benefit to that it's the fact that the newer the cabs are, the more
favorable they are for people to ride in. So we replaced most ofthose vehicles since then.
Q. Is there any way to possibly, I know Onrnitrans has gone to propane, and some of
these other alternative fuels to help our smog problem?
A. Sure. Well, two things. One is the ordinance itself can address the vehicle age.
Almost all of the other ordinances I work with have a maximum vehicle age for taxis.
Q. Okay.
A. Some of the shortest ones I've seen have been five years. And then the longest is
seven. Ontario just has adopted seven. So that might be something for the Board to
consider at one point. Pasadena, in fact, mandates that a certain percentage are
wheelchair cabs and then a certain percentages are what they would consider clean fuel
vehicles. Onrnitrans is actually talking about getting out of the CNG vehicles because
some of the fuels that are available allegedly are just as clean as CNG. We have had
minimal success using CNG. We also had a Super Shuttle franchise in the San Fernando
Valley, and we have had tons of maintenance problems. Maybe that's our mechanics, or
maybe it's the CNG. But we're not opposed to trying it again. I am not sure of the
availability ofCNG stations out here.
Q. Yeah, I'm not either. Ijust was concerned about that. Maybe a limitation on vehicles
and looking in the future to alternative fuels might be a possibility?
Q. I don't know that we have that right as a Bureau...
Q. . ..as a Board...
Q. .. .yep. I'm sure that AQMD will eventually catch up with them like they have the rest
of us!
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 11 of20
c
A. The vehicle age thing is probably an important issue, because from a public safety
standpoint, most of these vehicles are ex-police cars which have probably already gotten
pretty good abuse as police cars. And then the cab drivers obviously drive them
reasonably hard when they work two shifts a day. So it is something that we look after,
and have had to replace most of those since then.
Q. You just brought up another subject then. How many hours can they drive at one?
A. Eleven per shift.
Q. Eleven per shift. Has that ever presented any problems as far as...?
A. No, in fact, unlike the television show where people come in, and they go to the
garage and stuff, a lot of the drivers now lease cabs full time. And that's fairly standard
with most of the companies. Because business patterns are sporadic. If they pick Dave
up in the morning, and he goes to Fontana, they want to go back later to pick him up. So,
they'll change their schedules around. But all of our cabs have computers and they track
the amount of time that these guys log in and log off. So for safety standards, they are
not allowed to work more than eleven.
o
Q. Okay. The state standard is twelve.
Q. Is it really?
Q. Didn't you say two shifts a day, though?
A. Well, there are some vehicles that can be leased two shifts. Not to the same driver.
But a lot of the drivers actually do lease the cab full time because it gives them flexibility.
This particular contract with the V A allows some of these guys to make some lucrative
money. We actually go to Palm Springs, and up to Victorville and Barstow, and bring
people back to Lorna Linda. Those are high-end trips for a cab driver so he would like to
be around to take them back home. They don't do too much work other than the V A if
they can get those trips. We actually take some people to the V A in Brentwood from
here in Lorna Linda which is about a $150 cab ride. I'm not so sure where the Federal
government is getting all that money but they spend it quite vigorously on transportation.
Q. 42 cabs will be licensed here in the City of San Bernardino?
A. Yes. And I don't think... The one company currently hasn't had an attempt to go out
there and do a lot of marketing, or get involved. Because whatever it is, it is. And we
think most people probably aren't aware that the cabs are even available, or even when
they do call, the service is there. So the cabs... All these cabs here would be licensed
from Rialto, Colton, Victorville, this whole end of the area. So they would be legal to
C pick up anywhere.
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 12 of20
Q.How...
A. Because you asked me that because you would imagine 40 new cars driving around all
of a sudden?
Q. No, no. I just, if the. .. we're allowed to have one per 2,500 some residents? And
there are 35 licensed now?
Q. A total of about seventy-some under the [unintelligible].
Q. Yeah, seventy-some, so they will be a little...
A. It exceeds the...
Q. ...it will be about one in 2,400 if you go to 42.
A. So you want me to ask for 40 instead of 42? So it's a little bit closer?
Q. I'm just saying it will push the numbers at 42.
Q. Yeah, I'm still having a little problem as to whether we have established that there is a
need. Obviously, with Yellow Cab not here to defend themselves but they are the sole
provider at the present time.
Q. That's a question that I wanted to ask you. I assume they are inadequate. How
inadequate is it now?
Q. Lee gets all the complaints, and the last time I talked to him about it, we don't seem to
get that many complaints?
Q. From what I get in calls, about one a year.
Q. So, you know... and I haven't seen a public outcry for additional cab service.
A. On the complaint issue, having been in the paper from here to San Dimas for public
hearings, as we [unintelligible] last year, no one ever gets complaints. Nor do they get
complaints at Bell Cab, and we have complaints. They call the cab company to
complain.
Q. Sure, as well they should.
A. You're right. Nor are we that motivated. Initially, we would have to call each and
every municipality. In most of the cities, there is a rate card which says if you have
problems, call such and such. That isn't available in the Yellow Cabs here. In Ontario
now, we have big placards on the back of the seats. So there is a mechanism to call
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 13 of20
c
because there is often debates that, gee, ifit's not broke, don't fix it. There's no
problems. In all of our analysis going out there looking for business, there is a huge
problem. Which is slightly evidenced by the three or four letters that we supply. We
actually had public speakers at the meeting here in February. But it becomes horribly
adversarial. If I said left, Yellow Cab would say right.
Q. Sure.
c
A. And I don't think it's necessarily [unintelligible] of me to go out there and find thirty
or forty people who hate Yellow Cab because if they tried hard enough, I'm sure they
could find forty or fifty people that don't like Bell Cab. So I didn't think that's where we
should focus, on the complaint issue. But, the fact that Lee only gets one complaint a
year, isn't necessarily reflective that there is problems or not problems. I think there is a
lot more problems. The Ornnitrans survey in itself suggests that there is serious problems
with trips from home. If one were to follow the spirit of the ordinance in the population
thing, Yellow Cab should run 56 cabs here in 1952. There has been astronomical growth.
291 %. They're not supplying more, they are supplying less. And that's with Metrolink
opening in '92, Dial-A-Cab starting in 1995. There has been nothing but more demand.
AQMD Rule 2202 mandating ride share programs. It is 250 now, it used to be 100 for
employers. Their graph should have gone the opposite way along with the population
graph. They have chosen to reverse that trend. He probably gets a higher per capita
profit per cab but that doesn't necessarily stimulate better service. If people wait 45
minutes to an hour, they're not going to call a cab.
Q. Without being the owner of a cab company, it would be my thought that if the
business is out there, you would have as many cabs as you cumulatively could have to
generate the business. But quite the opposite, he decreased his number of cabs which
would indicate to me that the business is not as readily out there as what you indicate to
us. You know, obviously, if a new cab company comes into town, whatever business is
there is going to be cut in half.
A. You are assuming the business is static. And I don't believe it to be initially static. It
is static at airports where you just get in line and whoever is first in line. Ifwe went out
there and got involved with issues, with Route 66, or the Visitors Bureau, and promoted
the business, we believe that people would actually use taxicabs significantly more. I
can't understand his own rationale either, although I have come against it with one other
operator in the San Bernardino Valley that just runs less. He charges his drivers more,
and he feels in his mind that he has less of an insurance risk, and you're in the insurance
business. !think he's nuts. I think you're what[unintelligible]. I don't get it. We
believe in operating more cabs, maybe at less of a profit, and providing higher service.
Ted, who I know personally because we both sat on a state board together, got that
business from his father. I don't think Ted is that motivated to be running cabs as we are.
That's fine. That's Ted's prerogative.
c
c
o
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 14 of20
Q. Well, I think...I think a consideration would be that it's statistics bear out that another
company can come in. I think it's, you know, kind of a moot point as to whether it would
cut the business in half or not. I am kind of a competitive kind of guy and sometimes it
just needs stimulation through competition to get things going again. But if the figures
bear out that an additional company can come in, and the ordinance provides for that, and
what he has provided is a pretty good package, and if there were losses sustained because
of a lack of business, it would be his loss. So he would be going in looking at it with his
eyes wide open and I don't have a problem with him coming in.
Q. That's right, so, anyone want to make a motion to accept their...
Q. I just want to know, there is a [unintelligible] thing, excuse me, under 0-5-0 in the
hearing, it says that "before granting any such permit, the Bureau shall require it's
engineer or other authorized officer to present an oral or written report which shall
include his opinion as to the existence of public convenience and necessity for the
operation proposed by the applicant." And I'm not sure who the engineer or other
authorized officer would be, I guess anybody you authorize, but it appears to me that it's
a statutory requirement.
Q. It's not established on this Board. It would be an appointed.
Q. This is under the taxicabs, it's the 5.76.050. He read most of it. I will read the whole
thing so that you guys know it's the burden on us. It says: "No permit shall be granted to
any carrier, as defined in Section 5.76.020, except after a hearing thereon, conducted
under and in accordance with such rules and regulations as may, from time to time..."
Q. That is the one you're reading, right?
Q. That's correct. "...be prescribed therefore by the Bureau, and until the Bureau shall
have determined that the public convenience and necessity require the operation proposed
by the applicant for such permit. The Bureau, in determining whether or not such facts
exist, shall take into consideration the public demand for such service, the adequacy or
inadequacy of service being rendered by other carriers, the effect of such service upon
traffic, the financial responsibility of the applicant," which has been done, "the amount of
wages to be paid to employees, the character of equipment proposed to be furnished, and
any and all other facts which the Bureau may deem relevant. Before granting any such
permit, the Bureau shall require its engineer or other authorized officer to present an oral
or written report which shall include his opinion as to the existence of public convenience
and necessity for the operation proposed by the applicant. However, the burden of
establishing the existence of public convenience and necessity shall always be borne by
the applicant, and no permit shall be issued unless there has been an affirmative showing
of the existence of such public convenience and necessity by such applicant. The
foregoing provisions and requirements shall also apply where an increase in service is
C requested." And this was, I won't give you all the dates, it was...
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 15 of20
Q. So what we need to do is... We have satisfied a portion ofthis. And all we need to do
is figure out the portion that we haven't satisfied.
[Several individuals speak at once.]
Q. Well, I read that we are being... I read that we have to... We all corne from different
wards. So when we get this material in the mail, we are to deal with that information.
Now, I did in my ward. I looked to see ifthere was a necessity for additional cabs, etc.
etc. and I find that there is. And dealing with churches, schools, and places that use cabs
the most, I find that there is a need in the Sixth Ward. So I have pretty much satisfied
that for myself. Yes, and I read that you are the agent, you know, if you want to apply
that sentence, you are the agent or the individual who would need to finalize the report,
unless that goes to Lee?
Q. I don'tknowwhat...
Q. Are you talking about the "engineer"?
Q. Yeah. I would think that you would take reports from all the different wards and do a
summary report that would satisfy that requirement. That's what I thought.
Q. What I heard, and I think was the first thing that you have to do is go back to the
current cab company and discuss the inadequacies of the service and equipment and
everything else. And if they are not willing to work with you, then we need to start
considering [unintelligible].
Q. Since they are not here today...
Q. Yeah, I don't know...
Q. What I have seen of the cabs, they don't look like they are less than five years old
either.
Q. I didn't read that anywhere.
Q. He says his cabs are less than five years old.
Q. No, I mean...
Schaefer: In some areas.
Q....I didn't read that where we needed to go to the cab company. They were sent an
inquiry, right?
Q. They were put on notice that we were going to...
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 16 of20
c
Q. Yes, that's right here. So that was satisfied.
Q. Well, who would be the engineer? Is that somebody you appoint, or Lee?
Q. Traditionally, it's me.
Q. It's Lee.
Lee Gagnon: I want to tell you something from my perspective. To be totally honest
with you, and to get it on the record. I possess no specific skill to make a determination
whether or not it's needed. Because a lot of these things are not based upon just need. A
lot of times, they are based upon competition. And I saw this issue come before this
Board when it came to ambulances, and a number of issues over the years. It's not
always a case of whether or not we really need them. It's whether or not we want the
competition, and things of that nature. So, if you want my opinion, I have one just like
everyone else does. And I have dealt with Mr. Parlos [??] for a long time and I can give
you that, and it would be just that. So you have to understand that.
Q. Are you going to verbalize that opinion?
c
Lee: Okay, I will come down on it this way. My opinion is that competition, because,
first of all, I work in both worlds. I don't only work for the government. I also own a
business in this community. So, I walk in both worlds and I know what competition is.
To me, usually, competition stimulates good things. And it would for this community, I
believe. The other thing I would look at is: if you have a total number of permits
available, and you're only using part of it, just like Mr. Wilcoxson said, it's incumbent
upon the new person to make it work. Ifit doesn't, he's not going to make money. And I
think competition is good. But, you could make that, you could make a stipulation if you
wanted to look at it in a year, things of that nature. You could do a lot of things.
Q. You said there are a certain number of permits and they're not taking advantage of
using those permits. That's a perfect reason to go outside to find somebody else to use
the rest of the permits.
Lee: Exactly. Because the end result is that there are going to be more people out there,
or more cabs out there, for the residents to choose from.
Q. And competitive cabs.
Lee: Yes. But then again, there is also another end to that. Will there be some problems
with that? Will you have somehow two cabs showing up at one location for a fare, I
think. I dor;,'t know. I haven't been involved in that before, but my feeling is, my
opinion is, that competition is good.
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 17 of 20
c
Q. Any inv~lvement, with your involvement in the franchise thing is technical guarantor,
both sides, where you are sort of guaranteeing that cab companies [unintelligible] that
you will give them access to our community and in turn they will be available. So we all,
we have an obligation to that guarantor before we go outside. I'm not saying don't do
that, I'm just saying we have to satisfy that, or maybe I'm not understanding...
Q. Well, the fact is, we have a franchise available by virtue of the population. So
essentially, it's up to the Bureau, and the Council obviously has to approve it. Ifwe feel
that he has proven to us that there is a need within our community, and Mr. Wilcoxson
says that he has checked in his area, and there is obviously a need for additional cab
service. And I believe that Lee has given his opinion.
Q. [female] Does the existing cab company have, can do business in Fontana and Rialto
and in our surrounding communities?
Q. I don't know. They would have to, whatever those cities...
Q. [female] My question is, are we creating a pocket to where they are driving... Say
they have a fare that needs to come from Ontario or Fontana into the City of San
Bernardino. Are we creating a pocket to where...
c
Q. They can drop off in the City of San Bernardino from any location. They cannot pick
up from within the City of San Bernardino without being a franchise cab company.
Q. [female] So that creates a situation to where if you had people that were going back
and forth between communities and all, it's a difficult situation.
Q. Well, assuming that they follow the law, they would not be able to pick that person up
15 minutes later.
Schaefer: I think the question is, how many cities are they licensed in?
Q. [female] Yeah. I have used this, I have a daughter that's disabled and I have
attempted to use this various times, and I have checked basically the mileage so that she
would have enough money with her to pay for it. It always came out to about five dollars
more than the actual fare should have been. And so, we quit using it.
Schaefer: Actually, the SANBAG Work Plan says that the ridership has gone down
without cabs. And a lot of it is probably in that survey.. .
Q. [female] We quit using it and we use ACCESS now and some of the other, "mother
transportation. "
c
Q. As far as proving the need, or establishing the need, I think a lot, to me, that goes to
establishing the need for something different is the letters from the various businesses in
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 18 of20
c
San Bernardino. That almost all of them address the fact that they are having problems
with the current cab company. That their clients are having delay that is impacting their
business, and impacts hotels' businesses, and that is lost revenue to the city.
Q. Keep in mind that those letters, I presume, were somewhat solicited.
c
Q. I agree, and that could go the other way too, but as Yellow Cab did not take the
opportunity to be here and present any contrary information... But like, even Amtrak is
in here saying they experience delays, and that's having traveled by bus, Amtrak,
airplanes, everything else from around Southern California to the East Coast. I know for
me, it's very inconvenient, and I hate going to a community that has no competition for
service to where, as a user, and I hate to say this, but I can pit one against the other and
get good service. I would like to see us have something that's of a competitive mode in
this city. I think it's good for growth. And as we are looking at, our mayor is looking at
moving our city forward, and having growth, and bringing in businesses and stuff, I think
we need to be in a position, and look forward to being in a position to providing
transportation services for whatever growth comes to us. And if our current licensee is
not providing the quality of service we need... I can speak from limited experience, from
people that use it, seniors that use it at the church that I go to, and I know that they sit out
in the sun a lot on the streets waiting. And that is a limited experience, cause it's just one
small church. But, I know they sit out there. I have stood with them in the heat waiting
for service so. . .
Q. Yeah, I'm sure that Bell probably, they're not always going to pick up people at the
time that they would like to pick up. There's always going to be a certain amount of wait
unless we've got 20 cabs sitting there at the bus station.
Q. [female] Will you have taxi stands located throughout the city? Or how does that
operate?
Schaefer: We will apply for cabstands within the city, yes.
Q. That is another issue to come before the Bureau.
Q. [female] Another issue.
Q. Where do you guys anticipate the source of your business? I'm not sure where you
get it from. Is it, do you have so much coming from Dial-A-Cab, and so much from
Metrolink, so much from the hotels?
A. Obviously, those are normal staples. The bars and restaurants and anything. I think
you are from the car dealership.
C Q. Yeah.
c
c
c
Bureau of Franchises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 19 of20
[END OF FIRST SIDE OF TAPE]
A. Most ofthe business is [unintelligible] deliveries, that [unintelligible] accounts for
almost $55, 000 a month. And some of that demand will be coming from this area here.
So, it's just, years back we used to run the railroad crews, before the merger, from Colton
back and forth to LA., to Bakersfield, to La Paz, Arizona. Because by contract, they had
to stop at a certain point, because of the Department of Labor, they couldn't be on the
trains more than X. And they would fund these guys in cabs all over Timbuktu. So there
is lots, there is more cab work than somebody not in the cab business would think. But
it's not necessarily the guy flagging somebody down on the street, because you probably
will never flag a cab down on the street here.
A. [Rusty] Yeah, we look for non-traditional avenues, as well. The seniors. The seniors
taking lunch, taking them to and from, that type of thing.
A. Schaefer: Ms. Turner, you said your daughter is disabled. We do a lot of work for the
Regional Centers. Less here, for whatever reason, in the Inland Empire than the other
regional centers, which fund transportation for developmentally disabled. That's what
started with the infants, because we transport probably 100 Down's Syndrome infants a
day in LA through the Regional Center. But they don't tend to fund as much
transportation out here.
Q. Can we move on to the question? Did you make a motion? You move to approve the
granting of a franchise for what, 35 cabs?
Q. Yes, for the number stated. I believe it is 35.
Q. I thought he asked for...
Schaefer: I asked for 40.
Q. He wanted to amend it to 42.
Schaefer: I asked for 42 because there is concern that started to push the envelope with
the population.
Q. I'll move for the 42.
Q. Okay.
Q. Didn't we establish that exceeds, didn't we say that that exceeds slightly the....
Schaefer: Yeah. I looked at my calculator. .. 40 is fine.
c
c
c
Bureau ofFranebises Hearing - September 8, 1998
Page 20 of 20
Q. My reasoning was that 42 is not that much different than 40. But a lot of times when I
listen to a person present, I listen to him for many things. And it seems to me that he has
been really fair the first time I met him, and fair now. And sometimes, we can enhance
things by... and I will give you just a crazy little story...
Q. The forty cabs are what...
Q. Ifwe can't do 42, then we must stick with 40.
Q. We have to stick with the ordinance that grants based on a population base. So we
can't give him more than what that ordinance already calls for or we're not doing our job.
Q. So we are just going to strike, he doesn't have to re-write then?
Q. We are going to, based on your motion, for granting him a franchise for 40 cabs.
Q. But he doesn't have to re-write it? Weare just going to deal with the number?
Q. Yeah.
Q. Okay.
Schaefer [?]: You just need to pay me more money.
Q. Is there a second to that?
Q. Do we have a second?
Q. You will second it?
Q. Okay. It's been moved and seconded that we approve granting a franchise to Bell Cab
Company for 40 cabs. All those in favor? [Affirmative group response] Opposed? [no
response] It's unanimous.
Schaefer: Thank you.
[closing comments - explanation that decision will go before City Council for approval
giving Yellow Cab the opportunity to oppose - Bell Cab should be present to answer any
questions from the Council]
Meeting adjourned.
)
c
,"(
o
cnllJ;:O
(1) (1) c:
"'0 = en
_0_
(1) '<
3Q)o
C"C"Q)
(1) ~~
..., Q) 0
CX>"";:j
'"
~(1)
(O~
(O;:j
cx>CC
o
~:i
'.
...,
(1)
("')
_
o
...,
c
~o
:::Tc:
;:::+...,
(1)0..
en ~.
:::T<
--(1)
~...,
en en
~~
tl) (1)
("') c:
"';:j
"Ocr
Q) ...,
;l3
~en (1)
Q) _0..
;:j-
0.. :::T
_(1)
-"'<
m ~
- (1)
Q)
_ ...,
:::TC"
(1)_
'<Q)
tl) ("')
..., '"
(1) Q)
tl) ;:j
- 0..
~ :iE
'< :::T
en_
(1)
;:j --
c:
;:j
0'
...,
3
"
C/l
OJ
::l
OJ
et>
..,
::l
OJ
..,
C.
:oj"
o
-<G)
et> ..,
-et>
0,<
:;: :::r
aO
OJ e
0-5-
=ll:OJ
I'Ve
OJ",
(}1
O' 0
OJet>
et>-o
=0
a7
OJ '-
O-e
=ll:-
(}1'<
-.,JUJ
.):>0
0",
o
o
I'V
~
o
-0
3
'J
w (.
** FOR OFFICE USE ONLY - NOT A PUBLIC DOCUMENT **
RESOLUTION AGENDA ITEM TRACKING FORM
Meeting Date (Date Adopted): ~, 'I-O;l Item # ;:)~ Resolution #
Vote: Ayes /- f) Nays J?J Abstain &
Change to motion to amend original documents:
d CQ;)- ,?qS"
Absent (3
Reso, # On Attachments: - Contract term: -
Note on Resolution of Attachment stored separately: -=-
Direct City Clerk to (circle I): PUBLISH, POST, RECORD W/COUNTY
q -I I-c).?
'1-\ ').-O~
'1- t3-<.v
Date Sent to Mayor:
Date of Mayor's Signature:
Date of Clerk/CDC Signature:
Date emo/Letter Sent for Signature:
60 Day Reminder Letter Sent on 3
90 Day Reminder Letter Sent on 45th day:
See Attached:
See Attached:
ee ached:
Request for Council Action & Staff Report Attached:
Updated Prior Resolutions (Other Than Below):
Updated CITY Personnel Folders (6413, 6429, 6433,10584,10585,12634):
Updated CDC Personnel Folders (5557):
Updated Traffic Folders (3985, 8234, 655, 92-389):
Copies Distributed to:
City Attorney v'
Parks & Rec.
Code Compliance
Dev. Services
Water
Public Services
Police
Notes:
NullNoid After: -
By:
Reso. Log Updated: V
Seal Impressed: v
Date Returned: -
Yes .,/ No By
Ves NoL- By
Ves No~ By
Ves No~ By
Yes NoL B
EDA
Finance
MIS
Others:
BEFORE FILING, REVIEW FORM TO ENSURE ANY NOTATIONS MADE HERE ARE TRANSFERRED TO THE
YEARLY RESOLUTION CHRONOLOGICAL LOG FOR FUTURE REFERENCE (Contract Term, etc.)
Ready to File: i\11'
Date: q'n-c?-
Revised 01!l2/01
.-
MARK C. EDWARDS
ATIORNEY
LAVV OFtlCES c)F
'~?;<"""'"
MlRAl.l,EDWAmS~ON, HARrER ~ I
A PROFESSICt:!Al., CORPORATION
f;!'d':':":.'
1806 Orange Tree Lone, Suite C
Redlonds, CA 92374
telephone: (909) 793-0200
facsimile: (909) 793-0790
e-mail: medwards@mechlaw.com
AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
Presentation of Mark C. Edwards, Esq.
To the City of San Bernardino
Franchise Bureau
June 11,2002
-
q/c;/o:;
.:(:1 ;) ('!
-
JOHN K. MlRAU'
MARK C. EDWARDS
ROBERT W. CANNONt
STj/lii(;Y A. HARTER'
~LJ. LEWIN
-CenilicdSpeeialist,Taxation
Law,TheSlale8arofCalifomia
BoardofLeplSpcc:iaIiDtion
tceflifiedSpecialiSl,Estate
Plmming,Trustand Probale
Law,TheStltcBarofCalifomia
lloardofUgalSpecialization
1806 Orange Tree Lane, Suite C
Redlands, CA 92374
telephone: (909) 793.0200
facsimile: (909) 793-0790
medwards@mechlaw.com
Presentation of Mark C. Edwards
Attorney for AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
To The City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
June 11, 2002
Today, I am charged with demonstrating, and you are charged with determining, if "the
public convenience and necessity" is served by permitting a second taxi cab company to operate
in the City of San Bernardino. The alternative is to permit the current monopoly to continue.
o
At first blush, neither of us has an easy job. Look what has happened so far. My client,
AAA Cab, has presented to this Bureau a stack of statements from individuals and businesses
citing the poor quality of the current service. The holder of the current monopoly, Bell
CabN ellow Cab, in response, has presented its own statements, asserting that service is fine.
Who do you believe? Is it enough for your finding that we have demonstrated a significant
portion of the population is dissatisfied with the current level and quality of service?
Bell CabN ellow Cab, on the other hand, would have you believe that you should look at
the lack of complaints to this Bureau. Were there a formal mechanism for riders to make such a
complaint, as there is in other cities, we might agree. However, if you get into a BelINellow
cab, there is NO sign or other indication as to how to contact this Bureau or any other person or
agency of the City. Further, in the City telephone listing, this Bureau is not listed, nor is there
any listing under taxi or taxi regulation. Call City Hall, and the operators have no idea who is
responsible for taxi service regulation. The only indication, in a BelINellow cab, as to who to
complain about bad taxi service is in small letters at the bottom of a 4 inch by 4 inch rate sticker
which says "Inquiries or complaints should be addressed to Yellow Cab at (909) 884-6100." So
we really don't know how many complaints there are, and the fact is, as things now stand, it
doesn't really matter. As long as BelIN ellow Cab remains the only game in town, riders have
no choice but to accept the level of service offered (or not use taxi service) and BelIN ellow Cab
has no incentive to address riders' complaints.
o
So we have competing citizen statements and no way to know how many complaints
there are. How do you make the determination you are charged with making? Fortunately, we
have two other things. First, we have study after study after study demonstrating that quality of
service decreases, and the cost of service increases, when there is no competition. Conversely,
o
c
c
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 2
these studies clearly demonstrate that the quality of service increases, the cost of services
decreases, and ridership increases when there is competition in the taxicab market. These are
not the competing positions of AAA Cab and Bel1/Y ellow cab, these are independent studies by
governmental agencies, universities, and think tanks throughout the nation that concluded one
thing: If you want better taxi service, introduce competition. I have included a number of those
studies in the materials I've given you today, and I will refer to them throughout my
presentation. I've also included a study by local economist John Husing, who points out the
advantages of competition in the taxicab industry specifically in the Cities of San Bernardino and
Riverside. That study is located at Tab 1.
Second, we have our common sense. I could bring you reams of economic treatises
proving, through mathematical models, that competition lowers costs and increases the quality of
service. But you already know that. Common sense tells us that. And it is a fundamental
principal of the entire American economic system. If you don't like the lunch salad you get at
T.G.I. Fridays today, you can go to Chili's tomorrow. And after a fair number of Friday's
customers do that, Fridays is going to improve their food. If they don't, they won't survive. If,
however, through some bizarre regulation, there were only one place you could go to get lunch,
what incentive would that restaurant have to improve food or service?
So let us turn to the independent studies. These are located at tabs two (2) through
thirteen (13) of the materials I've provided to you.
Bel1/Y ellow Cab would have you believe, from the materials they have submitted to you
that the current system of regulating entry into the taxi-cab business was born of a need to
protect the quality of service. That is untrue. In fact, the Federal Trade Commission found that
the genesis of these restrictions came in the great Depression, when out of work individuals
turned to operating their cars as taxis to survive. As a result, the large cab companies sought to
protect their monopolies. The FTC found that the drive for regulation had nothing to do with
public interest but plenty to do with protecting monopolies.
The Institute for Justice's study of Boston's closed taxi cab system described the
historical basis for restrictions of the taxicab industry in this way:
"Entry restrictions did not even pretend to protect the "public interest," and were
often couched in explicitly anti-competitive terms. Improved safety or reduced
congestion and pollution were occasionally given as reasons, but only after-the-
fact rationalizations. In reality, regulators wanted to.. ..enable the organized cab
fleets and transit companies to increase their profits" (Tab No.2, Page No.2)
The folly of these historical restrictions is amply demonstrated in both the literature, and
in practice in the increasing number of cities which have opened their taxi markets to
competition. This trend is simply explained by the Oregon based Cascade Institute, which
concluded:
o
c
o
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 3
"The argument for opening taxicab markets rests on the principle that government
should not protect for-profit cab companies from competition to the detriment of
the riding public..." (Tab No.3, Page No.2)
So lets talk about quality of service and costs. Without a single supporting authority, Bell
CabNellow Cab asserts (and in fact makes it the heading of its written materials) that "More
Competition Won't hnprove Taxi Service." That is not what experience and the independent
studies have found.
As the Cato Institute concluded in a study authored by the Mayor of Indianapolis:
"Because the local (taxi) industry was protected from competition, the near
universal judgment was that service was poor, expensive and highly selective. If
you happened to live in a neighborhood that the dominant providers did not want
to serve, namely, low income and high crime areas, you were out ofluck." (Tab
No.4, Page No.5)
The Institute for Justice, in studying Baltimore's closed taxicab system found:
"Baltimore's restrictive system of taxicab regulation has deteriorated working
conditions for the drivers and has produced poor results for consumers." (Tab
No.5, Page No.8)
And who is most adversely affected by the results of a monopoly in the taxicab industry?
The poor and minorities, those who most need the service, especially here in San Bernardino. As
the Consumer Policy Institute in Toronto found:
"Taxicab regulation discriminates against single mothers, low and fixed-income
wage earners and the physically disadvantaged by reducing supply in their
neighborhoods and making the product uncompetitive and unaffordable." (Tab
No.6, Page No.2)
Perhaps the best description of the effect of the taxi-cab monopoly in San Bernardino is
found in the Toronto study, where the results of a closed system were described as producing:
"a network of inefficient taxicab operators who use the taxi stand as an opportunity
to sit in their vehicles and wait for the business to come to them." (Tab No.6,
Page No.7)
Does that bring to your mind, as it does to mine, the current situation in San Bernardino,
with cabs lined up at the bus depot, and nowhere else?
What is happening in San Bernardino? City Code, at section 5.76.060, limits the number
of taxicabs to one for every 2,500 residents. With a population of 185,401 (according to the
2000 census) this means that San Bernardino may legally have up to 74 taxis. BelIN ellow has a
o
c
c
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 4
permit to operate 36 cabs, slightly less than half of the code authorized number. However, a
review of the City Clerk's records reveals that there are only 19 drivers licensed to operate in
San Bernardino for BelINellow. If these drivers were to work 8 hour shifts with two days off,
this means that the average number of cabs on the road at anyone time would be less than 5
(4.52 to be exact). But even if BelINellow got all of its drivers working at one time, it can still
only serve San Bernardino with 14 of the authorized number of cabs. Why is BelIN ellow
keeping so few cabs operating in San Bernardino? Because without competition, public service
is not a factor they need to consider. Lowered costs and maximizing profit are the only factors
the market requires them to consider.
Now, Bell CablY ellow Cab would have you believe that all sorts of social ills will result
from putting more cabs on the streets. But that's not the reality. First, if AAA is granted the
license it seeks, it will operate 25 cabs in San Bernardino. 25 additional automobiles spread
throughout the City will have no adverse impact on traffic and, in fact, as ridership increases (as
I will speak about in a moment) it could have the effect of reducing traffic by taking private
vehicles off the road.
BelIN ellow Cab will have you believe that additional cabs will reduce per taxi usage,
and decrease earnings by drivers. In fact, again without citing any basis for the statement,
BelIN ellow Cabs states, in their materials to this Bureau, that: "Even though the number of
taxis increases in an area, the number of trips in that area stays the same, or even decreases."
That statement is simply not true. The independent studies reveal just the opposite. As
competition increases the availability of cabs, reduces the wait time, and increases the quality of
service, ridership actually increases. In fact, the Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions,
in studying taxicab regulations in Ohio, responded to just the argument that BelIN ellow Cab is
making, and soundly rejected that argument stating:
"If this (ridership levels remaining flat) were true, cities that deregulate would not
experience a significant increase in the number of cabs operating in their cities.
The demand would be insufficient to sustain a larger number of cabs and cab
companies. They would quickly go out of business. The fact that almost all cities
that deregulate their local taxicab market experience an increase in the number of
taxis in operation suggests that substantial unmet demand exists for these
services." (Tab No.7, Page No.9)
If this Bureau permits competition in the taxicab industry in San Bernardino, what you
will no longer have is a single company with its cars lined up at the bus station, and a phone
listing waiting for the customers to come to them, because they have no other choice. What you
will have is two (or more) companies competing for the business, by increasing the quality of
service, reducing wait times, and coming up with innovative new ways to serve the public.
This clear and well documented advantage is the reason that study after study after study
supports competition in the taxicab industry, and city after city after city is abolishing the old
monopolies, in favor of a competitive taxicab market. As John Husing's study points out, in
California cities with a population of 180,000 to 450,000, only two, Riverside and San
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 5
o
Bernardino, have a single licensed taxi company enjoying a monopoly. Every other such city
has at least 3 licensed companies. And that study is about to become outdated. Last month,
Riverside's Transportation Committee voted to end BelllYellow's monopoly and recommended
a license for AAA Cab to also operate in the City of Riverside.
Finally, let me address the drivers, as BelllYellow will have you believe that competition
will hurt them. But again, that is not the case. In fact what is hurting the drivers is the lack of
competition. Currently, BelllY ellow Cab charges a driver, in San Bernardino, more than
$300.00 per week MORE to lease a cab than AAA Inland Empire cabs charges its drivers. Now
in fairness, I should note that AAA will, shortly be increasing its weekly lease rate by $100.00.
However, even after that increase, a driver working for AAA Cab would, without working a
single extra hour or taking a single extra rider, earn over $800.00 more a month than he would
earn with Bell CabN ellow cab. But he can't. Why, because there is only one employer for taxi
drivers in San Bernardino and that monopoly allows that employer to continue to charge
exorbitant lease rates to its drivers. The single company monopoly doesn't protect drivers, it
hurts them. Competition will help them. If another cab company is permitted to operate in San
Bernardino, BelllY ellow Cab will be forced to reduce its lease rates in order to keep the best
drivers.
c
So who do you believe? I think that even the most cursory review of the literature,
including the studies I've provided to you, amply demonstrate that public necessity and
convenience will be served by competition, and will continue to be hanned if BelllYellow Cab's
monopoly is continued. But if you still don't know who to believe, then I suggest you listen to
Bell CabNellow Cab. Yes, that's correct, listen to Bell CabNellow Cab. But not the
statements made in the submittals to you, but the statements made outside of their efforts to
preserve their monopoly.
In Bell Cab Company's February 12, 1998 application for a permit to operate in the City
of San Dimas, it said the following:
"Bell Cab Company is not a supporter of market deregulation but strongly
opposes monopolies that result in lower levels of service, winimaJ marketing
and .lead to hostage pricing by service companies and taxicab operators.
Reasonable levels of competition l~ad tn.higl1er levels of service, stah]& con.lImer
~ces, better accessibility to taxicabs and availability at all times of day." (Tab
No. 14, Page No.8)
That statement was signed by Scott Schaeffer of BelllY ellow Cab. And lest you think
that was an isolated position, you need look no further than the July 11, 1997 San Bernardino
County Sun wherein the following appears:
o
"Vanik Zadurian, General Manager of Bell's Ontario office, said choice is critical
for consumers. (quoting Mr. Zandurian) 'To have a monopoly is not right. When
there's no competition, the level of service goes down.'" (Tab No. 15, Page I)
c
c
c
City of San Bernardino Franchise Bureau
Page 6
These statements, and a number of similar statements made by BelIIY ellow cab in the
newspaper are set forth at tabs 14 and 15 of the materials I've given to you.
We assert, and BelIlYellow Cab agrees (in their statements outside this room), that public
necessity and convenience are served by reasonable competition in the taxi industry, and are
harmed by the current monopoly. We respectfully request, therefore, that this Bureau approve
the introduction of such competition into the San Bernardino market.
Respectfully Submitted
ark C. Edwards
Mirau, Edwards, Cannon, Harter
& Lewin, a professional corporation
Attorneys for AAA Inland Empire Cab Co.
c
Economics & Politics, Inc.
3142 Cactus Circle
Highland, CA 92346-1739
(909) 425-8952 Pbone
lobnliillobnbnsln2.com
www.lobnbuslo2.com
Taxi Service Market Considerations
Cities of San Bernardino & Riverside
by John E. Husing, Ph.D.
c
In considering whether to open their taxicab markets to some competition, the cities of San
Bernardino and Riverside would be well served to address a single question:
. Which is more likely to enhance the quality of taxi service provided to citizens of
their communities: monopoly taxi service or competitive taxi service?
This question arises as each city considers whether "public convenience and necessity" will
allow the permitting of a second company. Certainly, neither community is inundated with
excess taxicab service. In San Bernardino's case, there is only one legal cab per 5,284 residents.
In Riverside, it is one legal cab per 7,181 residents.
Monopolv Service. The <p1estion of "monopoly vs. competitive" taxi service is posed as the two
cities are unique among the 13 mid-sized California communities of 190,000-450,000 people in
that each is only served bya single taxicab company (Exhibit 1).
, Exhibit 1.-Number of Taxi Companies, 2002
California Cities, 190,000 to 450.000
'JI'/
.l'
~
..~
/"'
~" qff""
...if "
,
-1:l
.::1' ..,1$-
&-<Y <(!'...
~t'f/'
..~
.#
./
c/ ",/
...0
f!'~
:.4-"
""
~'"
I Source: Cities I
c
'%
Elderlv. Handicapped. Poor. In addition, the question is important as the ultimate purpose of a
municipal government islo ensure that its citizens are well served and protected. In San
Bernardino and Riverside, this standard is important with regards to taxi service because unlike
huge cities such as Los Angeles, San Francisco and San Diego, taxi service is needed for local
residents not business or tourist travelers. In particular, three groups of city residents are
disproportionately dependent upon taxis:
Taxi Service
1
Economics & PoUtlcs, Inc.
c
c
c
1. Elderly. Many elderly persons can no longer drive. It is also difficult for them to reach
fix line bus stops. In addition, older persons often fear exposure to danger on the streets,
a fear exacerbated in the evenings when they might need medical services. The elderly
would thus prefer increased access to door to door taxi service.
2. Handicapped. The handicapped are in similar positions to senior citizens. Many cannot
drive. It is difficult for them to reach bus stops. At night, should they need access to
doctors or to be picked up from a medical facility, they are almost completely dependent
upon taxi service.
3. Poor. The poor often cannot afford automobiles. In addition, they are most likely to live
in neighborhoods that, given a choice of other customers, taxi drivers would prefer to
avoid. If they cannot get taxi service, the only alternative for the poor is fix route bus
service.
In both cities, the total of persons in these groups is quite large. In San Bernardino, for instance,
the San Bernardino County Social Services Department indicates that some 59,083 city residents
were on public assistance .or 31.4% of the city's population in 2000. In Riverside, the Census
2000 Supplementary Survey indicated that 17.0% of residents were below the p.ational poverty
level.
Population Per Lel!al TaXicab. In asking whether the existing companies are providing a high
level of service to the puqlic, a question that arises is whether there are objective measures of
taxi service quality. A review of the literature on such service indicates that two standards are
most frequently applied. The first is the population per legal taxicabs. On this measure, data are
available for II of California's 13 mid-sized cities (Exhibit 2). They break into two groups:
. Four cities had; over 5,000 residents per cab with Modesto the highest (8,836) and
both Riverside (7,181) and San Bernardino (5,284) in this category.
. Seven cities had well under 3,000 residents per taxi with Glendale the highest (2,653).
Significantly, the four cities with the highest number of persons per taxi also were the four with
the least amount of competition. As indicated, Riverside and San Bernardino were the only
monopoly situations (Exhibit 1). Stockton and Modesto each had only three companies.
Exl1ibit 2.-PopuliltIOIl Pel Le'~JI C"bs. 2002
California Cities. 190.000 to 450.000
#
,/'
<;
#'" ~~ #"" ,. .#
__,:#<1> '<~ " ~ ,;-
0/' ""
; r~<i'
.1 Note, Data not avollablo "" Huntington Beach " Santa Ana
Source: Otis
~"
.,-sf'
;l
o
.ll'
.'#'
~
JI"~
~
.#
./
Taxi Servl<e
2
Etonoml.. & Polities, Int.
--
l..-
c
c
Square Miles Per LeJ!a1 Taxicab. A second objective measure used to detennine the quality of
taxi service is the number of square miles covered per legal taxicab. Data were also available
from 11 of the 13 cities in the 190,000-450,000 range (Exhibit 3). Here, seven cities had less
than one square mile per taxicab and four had more than one square mile per cab. The city with
the most area to cover per taxi was Riverside (2.09 miles). The next highest was San Bernardino
(1.65 miles). The least was Oakland (0.17). Again, the four with the most area per legal cab
were the same four that had the fewest number of companies.
Exhibit.... ()qll,l!C' r,.li1f>c; P{'r TZlxlcab
COllloll110 Cities, I ~O,OOO to 450,000
0.19 0.17
<i>.i'" ~~/ ./ ,,/ ~/ /~ ~if ,,/ / / ./
<;
I ~DaDCt=~dnPBeach I
Summary. Looking at the data, the cities of San Bernardino and Riverside are shown to be the
only cities of Califomia's 13 communities with 190,000 to 450,000 people that confine their taxi
service to monopoly providers. They are two of four cities in this group with over 5,000
residents per legal taxicab. And, they ranked highest in terms of the square miles per taxi. In
each case, the cities with the least competition scored the poorest on these objective measures of
quality.
Given that San Bernardino'has a very high percentage of residents on public assistance (31.4%)
and Riverside has a large number of citizens living below the federal poverty level (17. a%), they
are communities in which the elderly, handicapped and poor appear to have a major need for taxi
service. These facts argue strongly that the introduction of competition into the taxi markets of
Riverside and San Bernardino is in the public interest on the grounds of both convenience and
necessity.
Why Cities Have Transitioned From
Monopoly to Competitive Taxi Service
Looking beyond objective measures of service quality, there is another dimension to the issue of
regulated monopoly versuS competitive suppliers for taxi service. That is the question of why
many cities are now transitioning towards the competitive model. This is an important
consideration since that is what both Riverside and San Bernardino are being asked to do.
Whv Rel!ulated MonoDolies? The use of regulated monopolies to supply taxicab service was
founded on the depression-era notion that taxi companies are similar to such public utilities as
telephone, electricity, natural gas companies. As such, the public is best accommodated by
having one regulated organization supply this service as opposed to several companies in
competition. The historic logic for such monopolies was fivefold:
To:d Service
3
Economics & ponti... Inc.
,-
~
. Larl!e Investments. Cities once believed that there was a need to protect certain firms
from marketplace competition due to the huge financial investments that they needed to
make in order to commence operations. This rationale was applied to taxi companies
since in the early days, it was very expensive to set up two-way radio systems and
acquire fleets of cars. Like other utilities, they were thus given protection from
competitors so that they would have a chance to recoup their investments.
However, this logic no longer applies as the costs of establishing taxi service is not
extremely expensive. Compared to incomes, vehicles cost a fraction of what they did in
the Depression. Meanwhile, wireless communications is inexpensive in today's world.
As a result, the cost of entering the taxi business no longer justifies protecting firms from
competition.
. Unnecessary DUDlication. In some sectors, cities believed that it would be a burden on
their infrastructure to have more than one company supplying services. This was obvious
with regards to telephone lines and power poles. The logic was extended to taxicabs out
of fear that too many competitive companies might clog city streets.
However, with so many people driving automobiles and so few taxicabs, this fear is now
unfounded. Even if the number of taxicabs tripled in the two communities, Riverside
would have just 111 legal cabs and San Bernardino would have just 108. These would
not be operating 24, hours a day and the number on the streets at anyone time would be a
minute fraction of the fleet of private vehicles on city streets.
. Qualitv. Cities on~e identified certain services like telephones and electricity as essential
to their citizens. They believed that the best way to ensure a high level of service was
through a single tightly regulated company. In the early days, many people did not have
automobiles. Taxi service was thus seen as a necessity to be provided by a single utility
with city regulation guaranteeing quality.
However, over the years, Americans have come to realize that competition is the most
efficient method of ensuring that companies deliver services at the quality levels
demanded by their customers. Where competition exists, those companies that do not
~
perform well find themselves losing clients. In fact, the benefits of competition are so
well established that goverurnents now work hard to encourage more, not less of it. It is
thus an historical anomaly that consumers are not given the power of choice with regards
to taxi service. Imagine the outcry if cities decided that only a single municipally
regulated food or oil firm were allowed to provide these essential items to the public!
For cities like Riverside and San Bemardino, the issue of quality has taken on a new
dimension in recent times. As indicated, with so many people driving, the groups most
dependent upon twti service are now the elderly, the handicapped and the poor. Quality
of service can thus be defined as having taxicabs readily accessible to these three groups.
Increasingly, cities' are finding that the best way to achieve this result is to foster
competition among taxi companies so that they each have an upside interest in adding to
their customer base.
. GOUl!inl!. On occasion, cities have tried to keep the prices of necessities low by allowing
only a single supplibr of a service and tightly regulating their prices. This was applied to
taxi service in the belief that it was a necessity and that this was the way to keep down
the price. Here, it must be remembered that price gouging is a natural symptom of
-
'-
c
Taxi Service
4
Economics & Politics, Ine.
c
c
c
markets dominated by sole providers as lack of competition allows the monopoly to
charge whatever pnces they feel will maximize their profits. Where strong competition
exists, prices tend to be lower as firms compete for customers.
When a city permits a single taxicab company to operate as a monopoly, it is imperative
that fares be regulated to keep prices down. Even where a small amount of competition
is allowed, it is necessary to have some price regulation. However in this case, many
cities are finding that it is in the public interest to establish price maximums and allow
companies to set prices below that level if they feel it is in their competitive interest.
. Public Safety. Cities always have had sectors whose activities impacted public safety.
These sectors are tightly regulated to eusure that unscrupulous operators do not harm the
public. As taxi service involves passengers entering a vehicle alone, the strategy for
protecting public safety was to have all drivers work for a single tightly regulated firm.
However, today, cities regulate numerous activities with an eye towards public safety
without resorting to the establishment of monopoly providers.
Conclusion. The cities 'of San Bernardino and Riverside are unique among California's
communities of 190,000-450,000 in still using regulated monopolies to provide taxi service.
Further, it has been shown'that they, together with Stockton and Modesto, have the least amount
of competition and the highest number of persons and most area to cover per legal taxicab. In
addition, both cities have, large numbers of elderly, handicapped and poor persons who need
ready access to cabs.
Finally, it has been shoWn that cities are generally moving away from the use of regulated
monopolies to provide taxi service because each element of the Depression era rationale for
using this form of organization is no longer valid and the competitive model is a more efficient
method of obtaining quality service.
Taxi Service
5
E.onoml.. & Politi.., Ine.
o
o
o
c
c
c
The folIowing study was an award winning proposal from the hllrtitute for Justice for the
Pioneer Institute's 1995 "Better Government Competition".
OPENING BOSTON'S TAXICAB
MARKET
by
John E. Kramer and William H. MelIor
INTRODUCTION
The argument for taxicab deregulation rests on the principle that government should not
protect for-profit taxi companies from competition to the detriment of the riding public as
welI as would-be entrepreneurs. Government's proper role is to ensure public safety with
driver background checks, vehicle safety inspections, and inspections for insurance.
THE PROBLEM: BOSTON'S CLOSED TAXICAB
MARKET
Since 1930, the city of Boston, through its police department's hackney unit, has imposed
an unofficial moratorium on the number of taxicab medallions (licenses required to
operate a taxicab) it issues. These regulations do little more than protect existing
medallion holders from much-needed competition at the expense of current and would-be
drivers and the riding public, especially the poor and minorities, who receive inadequate,
unreliable, and costly taxicab service. In addition, such a system creates an inflated price
for city-issued taxi licenses far beyond the reach of average entrepreneurs, never mind
those on the bottom rung of the economic ladder.
Because the city restricts the number of medallions it issues at welI below the market
level, Boston taxi medallions selI at $95,000 on the open market. 1 What is most striking
about this statistic is that the City of Boston charges a mere $175 to secure a medallion--a
$75 contribution for the Elderly Coupon Fund, which allows senior citizens to ride for a
discount, plus $100 in administrative fees. In essence, the city has created a black market
that encourages businesses to obtain a piece of city property-the medallion--and selI it
for an enormous profit, to their own (and no public) benefit.
A comparison conducted in 1995 of Boston's taxicab fares with three deregulated cities
shows that Boston's fares average II percent higher.2 A study published in 1982 of
Boston's taxicab industry as it was in 1970 estimated that Boston's medallion system had
kept taxi fares as much as 25 percent above market rates because of its restricted entry
and price controls.3
c
c
c
From 1930 until today, Boston has issued only 40 new taxi permits from the original
ceiling of 1525 medallions. That occurred in 1992 to allow 40 handicapped accessible
vehicles to operate. Applications for an additional 300 medallions were submitted nearly
two years ago, but there are no plans to process new applications, according to an officer
working in the hackney unit.9 Approximately 300 of the existing medallions are equally
divided between two fleets--Checker and Town--with another 267 operating as Boston
Cabs. Many of the remaining medallions are limited to operators under the Independent
Taxi Owners Association. As a result of the restricted entry, countless qualified
individuals have been denied the right to earn a living in a business ideally suited to
entry-level entrepreneurs.
The birth of the modem taxicab in the United States occurred without restrictions on the
free market; still, those restrictions were not long in coming. Some believe today's heavy
regulation of the industry in the United States began in response to "ruinous competition"
that harmed the public during the Great Depression. To the contrary, close historical
analysis indicates that, not only was there no "rninous comroetition," but the majority of
taxicab regulations were already in place in the late 1920s. 0 During the 1930s car prices
and wages fell, bringing large numbers of drivers into the industry. According to a report
by the Federal Trade Commission, .
"Many unemployed workers entered the taxi industry using rented cars, and as a result
taxi fares, occupancy rates, and revenues per cab declined Pressures for restrictions on
the toxi industry came from the American Transit Association, public transit firms, the
National Association of Taxicab Owners (which passed a resolution favoring entry and
minimum fare controls) and the established taxi fleet. J J "
Entry restrictions did not even pretend to protect the "public interest," and were often
couched in explicitly anti-competitive terms. Improved safety or reduced congestion and
pollution were occasionally given as reasons, but only as after-the-fact rationalizations. In
reality, regulators wanted to "drive many cut-throat cabs, operating without authority,
from the streets and. . .enable the organized cab fleets and transit companies to increase
their profits.,,12
There has been little change in the way taxicabs are regulated since the wave of
restrictions of the 1920s and 1930s. For example, with the 1937 Haas Act, New York
issued 13,566 taxicab medallions. Today, there are fewer than 11,800 medallions in the
City.13 Existing medallions can be sold to new operators, but at a price of$140,000
apiece, most aspiring entrepreneurs lack the resources to enter the profession. Similar
artificially high costs of entry exist in the majority of U.S. cities. Over the years, the
taxicab industry in heavily regulated cities (like Boston, Buffalo, Albany, Houston, Los
Angeles, Miami, Salt Lake City, San Antonio, and San Francisco) has stagnated. Poor
quality, high fares, and long waiting times are standard in many cities where taxicab
giants have taken control of the market with the aid ofregulation. A 1970 study of Los
Angeles, where regulations forbid new taxicab services, clearly illustrated this pattern:
powerful monopolies bought out the competition and raised taxicab fares, while new
competition couId not enter the market.14
o
c
c
As Dr. Walter Williams remarked in 1982 about such laws that block entrepreneurship,
"The[ se] laws are not discriminatory in the sense that they are aimed specifically at
blacks. But they are discriminatory in the sense that they deny full opportunity for the
most disadvantaged Americans, among whom blacks are disproportionately
represented. ,,24
The Solution: Opening Markets/Opening Opportunity
To improve poor taxi service and offer opportunities to would-be entrepreneurs, we
suggest fundamental changes to the cornmand and control monopoly imposed on
Boston's taxi market with its fixed number of cabs as well as fixed pricing. The hackney
unit of Boston's police department should open entry into the taxi industry and regulate
cabs to protect public safety by requiring a license, a background check on drivers, a safe
vehicle, and adequate liability insurance. Beyond that, regulations trench on the basic
civil right to pursue a business or profession free of arbitrary and oppressive government
regulation.
To allow market forces to work, the City Council should couple a change in rate structure
along with opening entry to the industry. This would allow drivers to expand their base of
customers by offering competitive fares, especially to the elderly--the fastest growing
segment of society who rely heavily on taxicabs, but many of whom also have fixed
incomes. To protect visitors to the city as well as others who rely on taxi service who
may not be familiar with rates, a fare ceiling may be imposed to restrict any price
gouging that may occur. Indianapolis used this approach recently with successful results.
This price ceiling, below which competitive fares could be offered, would in all
likelihood be what cabs must charge now. With this kind of price competition joined with
competitive services, the taxi industry can compete for customers like grocery stores, dry
cleaners, or any other less regulated industry.
Why should the City of Boston maintain regulations that protect current taxi medallion
holders from competition offered by otherwise qualified and capable citizens, who
merely want an opportunity to work for themselves and earn an honest living? The
answer is simple. It should not.
Perhaps the best statement that can be made on the subject of opening opportunity by
opening taxi markets was written by Linda Cagnetti of the Cincinnati Enquirer, who
wrote,
"No city should erect barriers that shut ouLentrepreneurship. A vote for deregulation is
more than a squabble over taxicabs. It's a stand for e~ual opportunity, jobs and individual
initiative--basic ingredients of the American dream." 5
To deregulate the taxicab industry in Boston, we offer model legislation (attached at the
end of this report), which was used in Indianapolis in that city's effort to open up
opportunity for those who have been shut out of the system. Optimally, we would like to
see the benefits of freedom extended to the entire transportation industry, including
C Reducing the Value of Medallions
When taXi markets such as Boston's are opened, the inflated value of medallions can be
expected to drop dramatically. This is not surprising when one considers that the city of
Boston would currently charge a resident $175 to issue a new taXi medallion. But,
because the city has created such a scarcity of medallions, well below the market
demand, the price a taXi owner pays for a medallion has risen to as much as $96,000. In
some instances, people have taken out substantial personal loans or invested their life
savings to secure a medallion, and therefore they will fight vigorously to retain the value
of their investment.
Because government created this potential problem, an argument can be made for the city
to buy back all or a portion of the value of the existing medallions to mitigate any
individual financial loss.
In 1994 Cincinnati Mayor Roxanne Qualls perhaps best summed up the lunacy of
retaining the current system as her city moved to deregulation:
"Both consumers and cab drivers have suffered because of an ill-advised council policy
which uses "public convenience and necessity" as the basis for issuing licenses. The city
interjects its judgment in determining need rather than allowing the marketplace to do so.
The current law requiring the safety director to issue licenses based on the public
convenience and necessity is too vague. The new ordinance would remove "public
convenience and necessity" and replace it with directions that the safety director issue a
license to anyone who has a safe driving record, a safe vehicle, insurance and the
required license fee. This is a very important change.
One of the major problems within the industry has been the hoarding of licenses by
companies and individuals. An increase in demand has created a black market on cab
licenses so that a cornmodity that can be purchased from the city for $161 is sold on the
street for $3,000 or more. City policy should not facilitate the creation of black markets.
The second problem with the city's current policy as it relates to taXicabs is that cab
companies that control the limited supply of licenses turn around and lease those city-
issued licenses to drivers for a profit. Drivers pay as much as $100 to $200 per week for
the privilege of using a city-issued cab license.
City policies should not create a system where individuals or companies are making a
profit by leasing city property. ,,26
c
Taxis as Utilities
The taXi industry sometimes describes itself as a utility--an entity that is as vital to a city
as water or electricity. But while historically it may have been cornmon for governments
to protect large capital investments of electric and water companies, such practices have
!c
c
c
c
"We used to describe the Colorado Public Utilities Commission [which oversees taxi
regulation] as an Eastern European-like agency for its suffocating oversight of
transportation, but lately that label has become an unfair insult to most of Eastern Europe.
Yet even as Poles, Czechs, Slovenians and the like liberate themselves from the shackles
of anti-competitive laws, our own PUC continues to coddle artificial monopolies that
punish consumers and bar small-time entrepreneurs from making a decent living. ..29
Through the Institute's efforts, similar deregulation was successfully carried out over the
past two years in Denver and Cincinnati, as well as Indianapolis. Early indications are
that results are positive:
In Denver, an African American owned taxi company became the first new entrant into
the market in nearly 50 years.
In Cincinnati, after deregulation, 209 new taxis (mostly driven by driver/owners) have
begun providing the city with additional service.3o
In Indianapolis, after only six months of deregulation, there was 'a nearly 7 percent
increase in the number of cabs. Seventy-five percent of the new companies are female- or
minority-owned. Nearly all the new taxi owners are former drivers who had long wanted
a chance to own their own business. Fares were reduced: pick-up charges dropped 12
percent; the average mileage rate dropped 3 percent; and the average first-mile rate
dropped 7 percent. Cabs are safer with all companies passing police background checks,
enhanced safety inspections, and verification of at least $100,000 in insurance coverage.
The program has been so successful that since taxi deregulation, the city did not receive
one written complaint, whereas they used to receive hundreds of complaints annually.31
Earlier efforts at deregulation also proved successful at getting new driver/owners on the
street:
.....the number of taxi rides per capita in Washington, D.C., where entry is not restricted
and fares are low, is over four times as high as in San Francisco, a comparable size city
where entry is restricted and fares are higher. ..32
Despite these victories, the need for additional, strategic replication of taxicab industry
deregulation is great. Cabs remain heavily regulated in cities such as Los Angeles, New
York, Miami, Buffalo, Houston, and San Francisco, where market entry is tightly
restricted. Such reform is also badly needed elsewhere in Massachusetts, including the
cities of Springfield, Worcester, and New Bedford.
MODEL LEGISLATION
C 6) place of birth;
7) length of residence in the city of Boston;
8) last previous employment;
9) whether the applicant is a citizen of the United States;
10) the date of judgment, court and description of each conviction for violation oflaw by
the applicant;
II) the date of filing, court and description of each charge pending against the applicant
alleging a violation oflaw;
12) all government entities from which the applicant has been previously licensed to
operate any type of public vehicle for hire, and each date and cause for which any such
license was ever revoked or suspended; and
13) such additional information as the controller deems necessary.
Section _' Attachments to the application.
c
Each application shall be accompanied by:
1) two (2) recent photographs of the applicant in a format prescribed by the controller,
designed to be easily attachable to the license;
2) a complete set of the applicant's fingerprints in a format prescribed by the controller;
3) a copy of the applicant's Massachusetts driving record certified within ten (10) days
prior to submission of the application; and
4) such additional items as the controller deems necessary.
Section . Fee
The biannual fee for license to operate a public vehicle for hire shall be [some token
amount, e.g. $40.]
Section _' Investigation of application.
The controller shall investigate an applicant for license to operate a public vehicle for
hire. The investigation shall include:
c
c
c
c
Upon completion of the investigation and any examination of the applicant, and a
determination by the controller that the applicant is eligible for a license to operate a
public vehicle for hire, the controller shall issue to the applicant a license to operate a
public vehicle for hire, in a format prescribed by the controller, which license shall
contain the photograph and signature of the licensee, the date of issuance and expiration
of the license, and such additional information as the controller deems necessary.
Section _' License ,period.
A license to operate a public vehicle for hire shall be valid until the renewal date for that
license occurring more than one year, but not more than two years, after the date of
Issuance.
Section _' Renewal date.
The renewal date for license to operate a public vehicle for hire shall be the last day of
the month of the birthday of the licensee.
Section . Renewal.
The renewal of the license to operate a public vehicle for hire shall be granted upon the
same terms and conditions as the original license. Pending action by the controller on the
application for renewal, the applicant shall be permitted to operate a public vehicle for
hire under the license issued for the previous licensing period, unless the controller enters
an order to the contrary.
Article _' General Licensure Requirements for Public Vehicles for Hire.
Section _' Separate license.
A separate license shall be required for each public vehicle for hire. Each public vehicle
for hire shall have one license: either a limousine license or a taxicab license. In order to
be licensed, every limousine and every taxicab must satisfY both:
I) the general licensure requirements for public vehicles for hire;' and
2) the additional specific requirements imposed by the article for either limousine
licenses or taxicab licenses, whichever is applicable.
Section _' Eligibility.
To be eligible for licensure as a public vehicle for hire, a motor vehicle must
I) be a passenger vehicle;
c
1) A public liability insurance policy or certificate of self-insurance for the vehicle; safety
inspection of vehicles shal1 be conducted annually or every 25,000 miles, which ever
comes first, to ensure the public's safety.
2) A certificate of inspection verifying the safe condition of any public vehicle for hire.
Such an inspection shal1 be made twelve months after the award of a license.
ABOUT THE AUTHORS
John E. Kramer is director of communications for the Washington, D.C.-based Institute
for Justice, and William H. "Chip" Mellor serves as the Institute's president. The
Institute for Justice exists to advance a rule oflaw under which individuals control their
destinies as free and responsible members of society.
End Notes
I Thomas Palmer, "Taxi Turmoil: Limousines' increase worries cabbies," Boston
Globe, January 17, 1995, p. 1.
2 Telephone surveys conducted August 18, 1995 with the Indianapolis mayor's office, the
Cincinnati Public Vehicles Department, and the Colorado Public Utilities Commission.
Survey reflects raw percentages without adjustments for cost ofliving.
C 3 Kennedy School of Government Case Study, "Boston's Taxicab Problems, 1970,"
1982, p. 3.
4 Original figures from A. Webster, E. Weiner, and J. Wel1s, "The Role ofthe Taxicab
in Urban Transportation," u.S. Department of Transportation, December 1974. Dol1ar
figure converted to 1992 dol1ars using the Implicit Price Deflator for the second quarter
of 1992. "Chal1enging Denver's Taxicab Monopoly," Institute for Justice, January
1993.
5 See Palmer.
6 Janet Novack, "Regulation at its Worst," Forbes, July 11, 1988, p. 48.
7 "Improving the Local Transportation Market," City oflndianapolis, publication in
support of Proposal 72,1994.
8 "Chal1enging Denver's Taxicab Monopoly."
9 "Gypsy cabs fil1 a need in neighborhood," Boston Globe, January 10, 1993, p. 1.
c
10 Gorman Gilbert and Robert E. Samuels, The Taxicab: An Urban Transportation
Survivor (The University ofNortb Carolina Press, 1982), p. 149.
c
c
c
24 Walter Williams, The State Against Blacks (McGraw-Hili Book Company, 1982), p.
25.
25 "Hailing cabs: City regulation blocks the road to slice ofthe American dream,"
Cincinnati Enquirer, January 18, 1995.
26 Roxanne Qualls, Cincinnati Enquirer, May 31, 1994, p. A7.
27 Novack, p. 48.
28 As demonstrated elsewhere in this report, although entry and service typically
improve as the result of opening a city's taxi market, some cities experience a decline in
the cost of fares, such as in Indianapolis where fares were deregulated, while other cities
experience a rise in fares.
29 "Slaying the Taxi Monopoly," Rocky Mountain News, February 2, 1993.
30 Telephone interview with Cincinnati Public Vehicles Department.
31 "The Fruits of Indianapolis Taxi De-Regulation," Indianapolis Economic
Development Committee, January 19, 1995.
32 R.F. Kirby, "Innovations in the Regulation and Operation of Taxicabs," in Taxicab
Innovations: Services and Regulations, U.S. Department of Transportation, May 1980.??
88 Invitation to Change830pening Boston's Taxi Market890pening Boston's Taxicab
/
Market
For further information or copies of this report, contact:
Institute for Justice
1717 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
Suite 200
Washington, D.C. 20006
Phone: (202) 955-1300
Fax: (202) 955-1329
E-Mail: instituteforjustice.org
Pioneer Institute
85 Devonshire Street
Boston, MA 02109
Phone: (617) 723-2277
Fax: (617) 723-1880
E-Mail: 75374.643@compuserve.com
o
o
o
c
c
c
Cascade Policy Institute
A "crsioll orihc lollowing cohllnn .was published ill the Portland (JreKolllall ncv..-spapcr on Fcbmm) J 7.
J 997 undcr thc hcadlinc
Tatis "clfert f,)., cntr,.-Ic\'cl cnl''CI,,'cncurs. It rcspondcd to a Fcb. 5 cditoriaL "Rethink taxi mles. " whieh
staled that "P0I11alld should be accol1lodaling airport shuttles. nol cnlcking down on door-lo-door service.."
Open the Door To Portland's Taxi Entrepreneurs
by WilIiam H. MelIor and John E. Kramer
Serious problems exist within Portland's taxi market, as highlighted by this week's
airport shuttle service controversy. Current city regulations have created a cab cartel that
restricts entrepreneurs from creating job opportunities and providing better service.
Portland should dissolve its onerous regulations and open the taxi market to
entrepreneurs.
For decades, like nearly 90 percent of cities across the nation, Portland has blocked a
primary avenue of opportunity ideally suited to low-income entrepreneurs: taxicab
driving. Driving a cab, like street vending, barbering and a host of other occupations, is a
perfect entry-level business for the poor because it requires minimal training or capital
investment, and the more you work the more your earn. But, the economically
disenfranchised are st)mied from entering such occupations by government restrictions.
Current city taxi regulations also harm the vel)' individuals most likely to rely on such
transportation: the poor, elderly, and others with fixed or low-incomes. These individuals,
and other taxi customers, are harmed in at least two ways. First, a low level of
competition leads to higher fares; second, less competition decreases service; for
example, fewer taxis means waiting longer to get a ride.
Several cities recently opened their taxi markets. The results are positive; increased
competition has produced more options, better service, lower fares, and job opportunities.
In 1994, Freedom Cabs became Denver's first new cab company in 50 years. Today, it
employs nearly 100 people and provides service to the historically under-served minority
community.
In Indianapolis, six months after opening entl)' into its taxi market, there was a nearly
seven percent increase in the number of cabs. Seventy-five percent of the new companies
are female- or minority-owned. Nearly all the new taxi owners are former drivers who
had long wanted a chance to own their own business. Fares were reduced: pick-up
charges dropped 12 percent; the average mileage rate dropped three percent; and the
average first-mile rate dropped seven percent. Cabs are safer with all companies passing
police background checks and enhanced safety inspections.
c
c
c'
After deregulation in Cincinnati, 209 new taxis (mostly driven by driver/owners) began
providing additional service in the city.
Since 1979, through its Bureau of Licenses, Taxicab Supervisor and Taxicab Review
Board, Portland has imposed an unofficial moratorium on taxicab permits (licenses
required to operate a taxicab). Under the "public convenience and necessity" standard
imposed that year, the city gives existing companies an unfair advantage--in fact a veto
on entry--over would-be competitors. Though control appears to be in the hands of
government, it really rests in the hands of existing cartel companies.
The "public convenience and necessity" standard creates yet another nearly
insurmountable presumption in favor of established businesses. The entrenched
companies can examine an aspiring entrepreneur's application, which identity new
market niches. Thus, an old business can that idea and provide the very service the
applicant was using to gain market entry. With the standard filled, there is no need for a
new company.
It should come as no surprise that since the public convenience and necessity standard
was enacted, not a single new cab company has entered Portland's taxicab market. The
last new entry into the market was in 1976. In a five-year period, from 1985 through
1990, not a single one of the five applications to begin a new cab company was accepted.
The four taxicab companies currently doing business in Portland (Radio Cab, Broadway
Cab, New Rose City Cab, and Portland Cab) have all been around since 1979. No
applications for new cab companies are currently pending.
The effect of the de facto ban on new taxicab businesses and, more importantly, on the
lives of would-be cab owners and drivers, is devastating. It impairs their ability to earn a
decent living for themselves and for their families. It limits their opportunity to work for
themselves, instead off or others. It destroys their dream of a brighter future.
These aspiring entrepreneurs realize there is no guarantee of success in a competitive
economy, but only upon encountering this ban did they realize that they would not even
have a chance to compete. Until Portland's oppressive ban is removed, they will be
denied one of the most basic civil rights: the right to earn an honest living.
The argument for opening taxicab markets rests on the principle that government should
not protect for-profit cab companies from competition to the detriment of the riding
public and would-be entrepreneurs. Rather, government's proper role should be to protect
the public's health and safety. Insurance and vehicle inspection requirements, as well as
background checks for drivers, are reasonable. A prohibition on competition is not.
Common sense says such decisions can best be decided by individuals in the
marketplace, not government bureaucracies.
~"-_._~.~~.,>._~------~_.~~~.~..~--------~-'-'-'----'."'"--~~--~._~---------~-
William H. Mellor is the president and general counsel, and John E. Kramer the director
of communications for the Washington, DC-based Institute for Justice. This article is
c
c
c
adapted from Opening Portland's Taxi Market. one often winning reports from the 1996
Oregon Better Government Competitio!l, organized by Cascade Policy Institute in
Portland.
_..._-....~..._.--=---._.~..~_"',.._.,.,_.,.".....~'...~_~~...,~~;~._.".~,___,.,_.,._,.,.~.,L.'~ '.__~A '-'<-"_'~"~'''_''~' .. "~__,....q.'.~..~_.
Cascade Policy Institute 813 S. W. Alder, Suite 450 Portland. OR 97205
Phone: (503) 242-0900
send mail to info(iiJ.CascadePolicV.ol'1l
Rehlm to Cascade home valle
o
o
o
c
c
c
1
This page has been accessed 182 times since 27 May 1997.
----.---
from Regulation which is published four times a year by the Cato Institute.
Editorial and business offices are located at
1000 Massachusetts Avenue, N.W.,
Washington, D.C., 20001.
For subscription information, please write to Circulation Department, Cato Institute,
same address, or call (202) 842-0200. Send email inquiries to cato@cato.org, or
subscribe online via the World Wide Web at: http://www.cato.orglpubs/regulation/reg-
ordr.html
..__.,..__...----_._,-,--~._._-~._-----
Regulation and the Urban Marketplace
Stephen Goldsmith
January 1997
Stephen Goldsmith has been mayor of Indianapolis since I 99 I.
Contents
Introduction
RetlUIatorv Study Commission
RSC Goals
RSC Princinles
Chantrlnl! the Permit System
A VictorY For Taxis
Asbestos: When A City is More Harmful than the Feds
SavinI! our Neil!hborhoods throul!h Derel!Ulation
How to Identify Beneficiaries of Rel!ulatorv Reform
Conclusion
Introduction
c
c
r
'-
2
My most important job as mayor of Indianapolis is to ensure the continued
economic success of America's twelfth largest city. While many mayors rely on one-
time tax breaks and attractive incentive packages to lure business to their cities,
these are not my primary tools for ensuring Indianapolis's long-term economic
bealth. My administration intends to serve Indianapolis by restoring regulatory
sanity to the municipal marketplace.
Estimates of the costs imposed on the national economy by federal regulation reach
$500 billion a year. In Indianapolis, that means more than $1 billion a year is
sapped from our local economy just to comply with federal regulations. When it
comes to mandates from Washington, we in Indianapolis have no choice but to
carry the burden.
Federal regulations are but one part ofthe crushing regulatory onus inflicted on
America's cities. After meeting the regulatory demands imposed from afar, we are
forced to bear the burden of state-imposed mandates, over which we have limited
control at best.
But the most unacceptable portion of the regulatory load is that which we choose to
carry. Indianapolis has only recently begun to confront the problem presented by
2,800 pages of local regulations.
Upon taking office, I sought to tackle our regulatory problems by first preparing a
full inventory of all the areas we regulate. Then we surveyed local businesses to
gauge their sense of the regulatory impact on doing business in Indianapolis. The
top three responses listed as "Impacts on Profits" were: taxes, environmental
regulations, and "all other regulations." Community leaders had often complained
about local regulation, but this survey gave us our first hard data about the degree
of public discontent with the local regulatory climate.
Governments have a hard time comprehending the reality of these complaints.
Governments do not pay taxes, they collect them. While the cost of regulation
reduces the size of employers' payrolls, enforcing new regulations expands
government's payroll. Because bureaucrats do not pay the costs associated with
meeting the mandates of a regulation, they are often the least suited to make
decisions balancing regulatory costs and benefits to the local economy.
The Regulatory Study Commission
In order to help remedy this problem, I created the Regulatory Study Commission
(RSC) in July 1992. The RSC's fundamental operating principle is a regulatory
version of the ancient injunction to doctors: first, do no harm. Of all the RSC could
achieve, its most important contribution will be hardest to quantify; not what it has
positively accomplished, but what it has prevented.
c
c
c
3
While the RSC's performance has not been flawless, it is being cited nationally as
the most comprehensive and successful local regulatory reform effort of any city in
the United States. I believe that the success we have had stems from our operating
goals and principles:
RSC Goals:
. To lighten the regulatory burdens imposed on the citizens and businesses of
Indianapolis.
. To use the local regulatory code as a tool to encourage new business opportunities.
. To eliminate regulatory barriers to the creation of affordable, resident-owned
housing.
. To eliminate regulatory impediments to easier citizen access to municipal services.
RSC Principles:
. Regulations should be used as a tool to achieve a policy objective only as a last
resort. The use of regulations indicates a failure of all other means to achieve a
policy objective.
. The cost of a regulation should be no greater than the benefit it creates for the
community:
. Regulations must be simple, fair, and enforceable.
. Regulations must be written to insure the imposition of the minimum possible
constraints upon businesses and individuals.
. Regulations must never exceed existing federal or state standards unless there is an
overwhelming, compelling, and uniquely local reason for them to do so.
In its two-year existence, the RSC has pinpointed many areas where regulatory
policy conflicts with these principles.
Changing the Permit System
There are few areas in which the problems of regulation are more evident than the
disincentives in the building and development permitting process. The more permits
we require, the more hassles and expenses we load on our builders, which gives
them even more incentive to build and grow elsewhere.
A RSC subcommittee charged with re-engineering our development permission
process spent the better part of a year designing the Indianapolis Homeowner
4
c
Freedom Act (IHFA). This initiative, which received a "do-pass" recommendation
from the City Council's metropolitan Development Commission on November 22,
represents a giant step toward making building and living in Indianapolis more
competitive with our lower-taxed and less-regulated neighbors in adjacent counties.
The IHF A will drastically reduce the number of annual transactions our citizens
and developers will have to conduct with city bureaucrats, while greatly relieving
the city's workload. If adopted as submitted to the Council, IHFA will eliminate an
entire category of permits currently required for "low-impact" home repair.
Currently, we require permits for embarrassingly minute tasks. A citizen who wants
to do something as routine as replacing a door or installing a bathroom fan must
first come downtown, find a place to park (a task neither easy nor cheap), make his
or her way up to the 21st floor ofthe City-County Building, only to stand in what
can easily be an hour-long line, fiU out a series of forms, and submit to an interview
by a "permit specialist," at which point the homeowner must pay the city a
permitting fee for the privilege of improving his or her property.
c
This re-categorization of low-impact permitting will eliminate more than 7,200
permits a year and the litany of hassles listed above. But the IHF A goes much
further. In addition to eliminating permit requirements for low-impact work, we
plan to tie a permit employee to a particular project in much the same fashion that a
case worker stays with a family. Once adopted, our plan will redirect the entire
focus of our internal operation away from self-perpetuating bureaucracy and
towards meeting the needs of our customers.
The IHF A will allow builders and contractors to obtain a single master building
permit for an entire project rather than demanding that each subcontractor be
individually permitted, as is presently required. This reform will dramaticaUy
reduce the time and resources that our builders and contractors are forced to devote
to bureaucratic compliance, thereby increasing the time and resources they can
dedicate to the much more important task of building homes.
Another example of over-regulation imposing unnecessarily large costs on private
enterprise is the arcane system our city uses to issue encroachment permits-
permits needed most commonly for landscaping, awning, or signs. Under our old
system, a citizen submitting an application to improve his business or residence had
to wait up to eight weeks while the site plan was reviewed by as many as four city
agencies.
The president of a local bank recently told me about the ordeal he had to undergo in
order to obtain permission to put on an awning at his new downtown branch. He
spent more than twice as much money on professional help in navigating the permit
bureaucracy than he did on the awning itself. Unfortunately, what seemed
remarkable to our local bank president is far too routine for many of our citizens
C and businesspeople.
5
C A Victory For Taxis
The RSC begins with the premise that regulatory restrictions must be justified, not
simply assumed. From that starting point, we search for the least burdensome level
of regulation that meets our objective. Not surprisingly, we learned upon assuming
office that very little of our regulatory code had ever been subject to such a test.
The taxi industry is a good example of an area where regulations had completely
displaced the economic principles of demand and competition. The number of
licenses was fixed and so were the fares.
At a series of public meetings designed to develop community consensus on the need
for dramatic regulatory reform in ground transportation, nearly everyone who
testified confirmed our worst fears. Complaints about service were rampant.
Because the local industry was protected from competition, the near universal
judgment was that service was poor, expensive, and highly selective. If you
happened to live in a neighborhood that the dominant providers did not want to
serve, namely, low income and high crime areas, you were out of luck.
c
Drivers who wanted to go into business for themselves argued that local regulations
made it virtually impossible for them to own their own taxis. Denying business
opportunities is bad enough, but to do it to the very people who need
entrepreneurial opportunity most is downright shameful.
Entry into the Indianapolis taxi market was tightly controlled; the city government
had set the ceiling on taxi permits at 392. The taxi market was a de facto monopoly
controlled by a single large operator who owned or controlled, either directly or
indirectly, nearly two-thirds of the 392 taxis. The RSC determined that local taxi
service was so poor in large part because the regulations that governed them were so
bad.
Taxis and ground transportation became a major test of our administration's
credibility to deliver city-wide regulatory reform that could lead to real enterprise
creation. If we were to do anything to reform the local regulatory marketplace,
ground transportation was the arena in which we had to deliver.
c
But after a nearly two-year battle, the City County Council fmally voted 21-7 to
adopt Proposal 72 into law in May of 1994. On July 1, the artificial cap on the
number of taxi licenses was lifted, offering the first significant prospect of new
market entrants into the ground transportation industry since shortly after the end
of the Second World War. For the first time in just as long, the new law lifted the
prohibition against "cruising," or hailing a cab. This anti-competitive provision was
cunningly designed to prevent new market entrants from getting into the business
by cruising the streets. Since the only practical way to get a cab was to call one, only
those cabs with city-approved radio dispatch systems could compete, and since the
only companies that could afford the city-approved dispatch system were the few
c
c
c
6
dominant, well-heeled, and legally protected providers, their position in our market
was secure.
The impact of the new Indianapolis ground transportation ordinance, which also
abolished the official minimum fare, allowing taxis to charge as little as they like for
a ride, even surpassed our own expectations. In the first month, the number of
licensed taxi operators rose an amazing 60 percent, from twenty-eight licensed
companies to forty-fIVe. In addition, the new competition dropped fares among the
new licensees almost 7 percent. But perhaps even more impressive than reduced
fares and increased competition is the effect that the new market system has had
upon the drivers themselves.
Nearly overnight, the dress code for taxi drivers went from ripped T-shirts to collars
and ties. Cabs are noticeably cleaner, cabbies are friendlier and their vehicles are
more visible on our streets.
In all, there have been twenty-nine new taxi companies licensed since deregulation,
which means that the numher has more than doubled since the proposal was
adopted. Today there are fifty-nine licensed taxi companies in Indianapolis, and an
entirely new industry in jitneys and minivans.
Asbestos: When A City is More Harmful than the Feds
Upon assuming office, I was surprised to learn of the degree to which many local
regulations, particularly environmental regulations, actually exceed existing federal
and state standards. Operating on what I thought was a safe assumption that the
federal government is not known for its regulatory lenieney, I instructed the RSC to
insure that local regulations must not exceed federal or state standards unless there
is an overwhelming and compelling local reason for them to do so.
Indianapolis, like many other cities across the country, has obtained from the
Environmental Protection Ageney (EP A) the right to enforce local, national, and
state clean air laws through an independent Air Pollution Control Board. In 1992,
the longstanding memhers of that board, previously appointed by the mayor and
City-County Council, adopted one of the most stringent asbestos abatement
regulations in the country. While I would be the last one to argue against the
toughest reasonable safeguards to protect citizens against a dangerous substance, I
asked the RSC to determine what, if any, unique conditions existed in Indianapolis
that justified such regulatory maximalism.
Needless to say, the RSC didn't find much in the way of justification. But what it did
find was enough to alarm me and much of the community. Our analysis determined
that local adoption of this proposed asbestos regulation could cost Indianapolis
residences and businesses anywhere from $8 to $20 million a year.
c
c
c
7
This proposed asbestos regulation would have done much more than cost local
industry and citizens millions of dollars. It would have sacrificed jobs by creating
yet more economic burdens for businesses wishing to locate or expand in
Indianapolis. In addition, the proposed asbestos regulation would have adversely
affided compliance incentives. If adopted, the additional burdens of the proposed
asbestos regulation might well have increased the risk to asbestos workers by raising
the already substantial costs of legal operation. By raising the threshold necessary
for abatement, these new regulations might have resulted in just the opposite of
what the sponsors intended. Some of our health experts feared that a new,
underground "rip-and-run" asbestos abatement industry could pop up in
Indianapolis that would obey none of the existing laws, let alone the new ones.
Under such a scenario, asbestos workers would be subjected to much more danger
than are they now.
Fortunately, the RSC's constant scrutiny of new regulations prevented the well-
intentioned but misguided Regulation XUI from becoming law.
By first performing an evaluation of the pros and cons of additional asbestos
regulation and then making the results known to both the Air pollution Control
Board and the general community, enough pressure was brought to bear by
interested parties to insure effective and independent legislative action to defeat the
proposal. The costly measure's rejection by a unanimous vote of a normally pro-Air
Board City-County Council was an important legislative victory for the RSC.
Saving our Neighborhoods through Deregulation
Restoring regulatory sanity is a critical component of rescuing our inner city
neighborhoods from decay and lack of opportunity. I have charged the RSC with
reducing the regulatory impediments to expanded residential and commercial
development in our neighborhoods.
In government's misguided efforts we sometimes place much too much emphasis on
process and not enough on results. While I am concerned about how many citations
we write, how many inspectors we employ and how much a departmental budget
may rise or fall relative to the previous year, I am even more concerned about how
much we achieve relative to a policy goal-i.e., how many abandoned buildings did
we convert to habitable use, and how many neighborhoods have safer and healthier
environments? These are the types of measurements that matter in the private
sector, and in the end, they are the only kind of measurements that should matter to
us.
Measuring what we pay housing inspectors from year-to-year tells us nothing about
the condition of residential housing. The Health and Hospital Corporation of
Marion County, an independent government entity that in many ways overlaps with
our own city bureaucracy, employs more than fifty full-time inspectors to enforce a
remarkably detailed housing ordinance that regulates everything from how thick
8
c
countertops must be to how many inches off the ground one is allowed to store
firewood.
This emphasis on process at the expense of outcomes creates results that run
counter to the intent of the regulations. After a recent wind storm, for example, one
local property owner was threatened with citations and fines for transporting
downed limbs from her rental properties to an approved burning facility without a
proper permit. As a consequence, this rental property owner will think twice before
again attempting to haul debris from her property or similarly trying to provide for
the needs of her property and her tenants.
A similar story involved a citizen renovating a recently purchased distressed
property. She placed the debris under a tarp on the back porch before transporting
it off to the dump. Instead of being praised for improving our local housing stock, or
even being left alone to continue a commendable project, she was cited for having
debris on her property. She was forced to call a trash hauler, which added unneeded
expense and delayed the rehabilitation project by several weeks.
c
Seeking alternatives to the traditional but ineffective bureaucratic approach, I have
asked the RSC to investigate the possibility of relaxing housing and development
regulations and creating a "Regulatory Enterprise Zone." Instead of thinking in the
traditional manner about a designated geographic section of our city I have asked
the RSC staff to think more broadly about how to apply the Regulatory Enterprise
Zone concept to demographic and economic thresholds. Instead of defining our
concept geographically, why not define it through the very people we are trying to
help?
Since our goal is to spur private development, why not ask those doing the
developing to identify the specific non-health-and-safety barriers that prevent an
idea from becoming a reality? What would happen to development if we allowed
people who fall below certain pre-determined thresholds of income, age or regions,
to take advantage of our Regulatory Enterprise Zone development incentives?
Such an approach might be more likely to succeed politically because we could
identify specific people who stood to gain from the initiative, while minimizing the
impact of thrusting the totality of dramatic experimentation, the consequences of
which we can not know in advance, upon a single, already distressed neighborhood.
Ideally, the Regulatory Enterprise Zone participants would document their
successes and failures to help us amend local development regulations by removing
burdensome restrictions that add no health or safety value to our community. We
are hoping that the data we collect will enable us to employ performance-based
standards. If a builder can document areas where more efficient techniques can
achieve comparable outcomes, we will gladly amend our city code to encourage such
use. By focusing on the result, we believe we will increase the affordable housing
C stock available to the people of Indianapolis.
9
C How to Identify Beneficiaries of Regulatory Reform
While the RSC has done wonders for the regulatory climate in Indianapolis by
preventing destructive new regulations as well as eliminating existing ones, its
efforts have also revealed an important impediment to restoring regulatory sanity to
our municipal marketplace. I believe that one of the reasons regulatory reform has
been overlooked for so long at the municipal level derives from Tip O'Neill's famous
aphorism that all politics is local. If local considerations dictate the conduct of
public policy at the state and national level, then those concerns will certainly
dominate at the local level.
c
In battling for regulatory reform, the RSC has run up against the classic problem of
concentrated benefits and diffuse costs. Identifying constituencies for regulatory
reform is difficult, since the costs of regulation are spread over so many people in so
many different walks of life. The individual taxicab passenger or home buyer might
not realize the extent to which misguided regulation adds to his expenses. To
bureaucrats and rent-seekers, however, the benefits ofthe status quo are more
readily apparent. Any regulatory reform is a direct threat to their established
interests; thus, they are willing to fight for the regulatory policies of the past. Once a
regulation is promulgated, the onus for any sort of change is placed on the regulated
parties and the community. Perversely, instead of local government having to justify
why people should continued to be burdened, we expect citizens to justify why they
should be free.
The benefits of our more broadly publicized competitiveness agenda have resulted
in a clearly definable number of tax dollars saved and an improvement of service
that can be felt by all. In addition, those benefits are spread over a fixed class of
people who are more conscious ofthe process and able to determine the benefits to
them in concrete terms.
But the more diffuse the benefits, the more difficult it is to mobilize those people and
forces that stand to gain the most. Perhaps our single greatest political challenge is
to identify those stakeholders who stand to gain from our reforms and help them
work to encourage our effort to reduce the impact of local regulations.
In an attempt to build broader support for local regulatory reform, the RSC
recently proposed an initiative called Fair Fees for Small Business. This initiative
will eliminate licensing requirements for five types of local businesses, saving 426
small businesses more than $85,000 a year in fees and countless wasted hours of
annual reporting. Not only does Fair Fees reduce burdens to businesses, it also helps
build political support for deregulation.
c
While $85,000 is a statistically insignificant component of a $471 million annual
budget, public reaction has been remarkably positive. Needless to say, the 426
businesses who will no longer have to be licensed by the city nor pay fees for the
privilege are universally delighted, if not bewildered by the notion of a government
c
c
c
10
shrinking of its own accord. The proposal has been formally endorsed by both of
our mass circulation daily newspapers and the highly respected Indianapolis
Business Journal.
Conclusion
The problems of big cities in America are well known. But what we do not know is
how to isolate and concentrate on what aggravates those problems. Municipalities
must become more competitive and restore the principles of the marketplace. It is
imperative that we hold the line on taxes and restore a sensible regulatory
environment.
Regulations have smothered the entrepreneurial spirit for so long, that the
inefficiencies they create in the marketplace are now a part of doing business. For
new entrants to the market, these regulations are at best discouraging. At worst,
they are morally reprehensible.
We cannot afford to wait for citizens and businesspeople to mount organized
campaigns for regulatory reform. Such uprisings often come too late. By the time
regulated parties are fed up enough to mobilize against the regulatory bureaucracy,
many of them will have been fed up enough to have left Indianapolis.
This is the cycle that big city mayors must break. I believe that by restoring market
principles to our regulatory environment the RSC will do just that.
Founded in 1977, the Cato Institute is a nonpartisan public policy research
foundation headquartered in Washington, D.C. The Institute is named for Cato's
Letters, libertarian pamphlets that helped lay the philosophical foundation for the
American Revolution.
The Cato Institute seeks to broaden the parameters of public policy debate to allow
consideration of more options that are consistent with the traditional American
principles of limited government, individual liberty, and peace. Toward that goal,
the Institute strives to achieve greater involvement of the inteUigent, concerned lay
public in questions of policy and the proper role of government. The Cato Institute
undertakes an extensive publications program dealing with the complete spectrum
of policy issues. Books, monographs, and shorter studies are commissioned to
examine the federal budget, Social Security, monetary policy, natural resource
policy, military spending, regulation, NATO, international trade, and myriad other
issues. Major policy conferences are held throughout the year, from which papers
are published thrice yearly in the Cato Journal. The Institute also publishes the
quarterly magazine Regulation.
"""
\...t
c
c
II
In order to maintain an independent posture, the Cato Institute accepts no
government funding. Contributions are received from foundations, corporations,
and individuals, and other revenue is generated from the sale of publications. The
Institute is a nonprofit, tax-exempt educational foundation under Section SOI(c)3 of
the Internal Revenue Code.
This essay by Mayor Stephen Goldsmith is from Regulation which is published four
times a year by the Cato Institute. Editorial and business offices are located at 1000
Massachusetts Avenue, N.W., Washington, D.C., 20001. For subscription
information, please write to Circulation Department, Cato Institute, same address,
or call (202) 842-0200. Send email inquiries to cato@cato.org, or subscribe online
via the World Wide Web at: http://www.cato.org/pubs/regulationlreg-ordr.html
o
o
c
C Baltimore: No Harbor For Entrepreneurs
By Scott G. Bullock [Economic Liberty]
Institute for Justice
1717 Pennsylvania Ave., NW, Suite 200, Washington, D.C. 20006
Tel (202) 955-1300 Fax (202) 955-1329
http://www .institutefOljustice.org
Contents
c
Introduction
Vendin!!:
Baltimore's Grand Tradition of Arabbin!!:
Newsstands
Vehicles for Hire
Cosmetolol!:V and Hairbraidin!!:
Trash Removal
Child Care
FamiIv Child Care
Child Care Centers
Home Based Businesses
Conclusion
Endnotes
Introduction
Baltimore is a city-to use a popular catch phrase of urban planners-"in transition."
Many of Baltimore's once mighty industries are gone. The city itself has struggled
with unemployment and a declining population. More than 21 percent of city
residents live below the poverty line, while 16.4 percent of the population receives
some type of public assistance. An astounding 46.1 percent of Baltimore households
are headed by one parent, the fifth highest ranking among American cities. 1
Despite these depressing statistics, Baltimore during the early 1980s witnessed
somewhat of a renaissance, spurred by the development of the Inner Harbor area
into a major tourist attraction with shopping and a world-class aquarium.
Furthermore, in 1992, the City opened the much-praised, "old-style" Camden
Yards baseball park, home of the Baltimore Orioles.
c
In the City's and State's zeal to promote tourism, attract sports franchises, and
revitalize business through public/private partnerships, Baltimore's proud history ()
of local entrepreneurship and small enterprise has, for the most part, been
overlooked. This report addresses the state of entry-level entrepreneurship in the
City of Baltimore. The report focuses primarily on the following entry-level areas:
vending (including Baltimore's threatened tradition of "arabbing"); newsstand
operation; hairbraiding and cosmetology; vehicle-for-hire services (taxis, limousines
and vans); child-care centers; trash-removal services; and home-based businesses.
Many small enterprises-in such areas as vending, newsstand operation, taxicab
service, and garbage collection-face oppressive government regulation or even
outright prohibition. This report calls on the City not to lose sight of these
industrious, small-scale entrepreneurs struggling to survive in a changing
Baltimore.
Vending
Entrepreneurs who wish to sell food, T-shirts and other goods face an array of
regulations, fees and, in certain instances, outright prohibitions.
The good news for Baltimore vendors is that the City, unlike numerous other
metropolitan areas, does not place a cap on the number of vending permits. This
lack of an artificial, and, in many instances, arbitrary limit on permits should open
an avenue of entry into the vending business.
o
Although vendors do not face a numerical restriction on entry, they nevertheless
face heavy fees and numerous regulations. All vendors face at least two levels of fees
and regulations: those imposed by the State of Maryland and those imposed by the
City of Baltimore.
Any person wishing to sell non-edible goods such as T-shirts or incense from a
stationary stand must obtain a trader's permit from the State. The fee is reasonable-
$20. If the stand is mobile, however, the vendor must receive a foot peddler's permit,
which costs $202 per year. The great disparity between these permits is unjustified
and represents a bias against traditional mobile vendors. The State should equalize
the fees for peddlers and traders by reducing the peddler's fee. Even better, the
State should remove itself entirely from the regulation and registration of vendors
and allow localities to regulate vending on their streets in reasonable fashion.
In addition to the categories of vending established by the State, the City classifies
vendors into three geographic categories: non-downtown areas, downtown, and city
parks.
The City requires vendors to acquire one of two tags to affIX to the cart: a pushcart
permit, which costs $14 per year, or a wagonlhuckster permit (for wagons, vans,
etc.), which costs $20 per year. While these fees seem reasonable, the City does not
stop at licensing just the carts used by vendors. To vend in non-downtown areas, a 0
c
c
c
vendor must receive a "minor privilege" permit from the Department of Housing.
These permits are issued only to vendors selling food. The Department gives minor
privilege permits to "primary users" (store owners who wish to extend their
property rights on the sidewalk) and "second porters" (pushcart vendors). A minor
privilege permit for pushcarts is currently $324.
In downtown areas, pushcart vendors, in addition to getting the pushcart permit,
also must obtain a special permit from Baltimore's Board of Licensing for
Hucksters, Hawkers, and Peddlers. The application fee is $25, and the permit costs
$75 for vendors selling merchandise and $375 for food vendors. Food vendors are
hit with additional fees from the City. On top of the special permits for downtown
areas and minor privilege permits in non-downtown areas, food vendors also must
obtain a retail food permit from the City's Bureau of Food ControL A permit for
potentially "hazardous" food (such as hot dogs) is $250 per year; a permit for
prepackaged or non-hazardous food is $160 per year. Tom Dambrosky of the
Department of Building and Construction estimates that a pushcart vendor who
seUs food pays close to $1,000 in permits and fees just to set up.
Even if a vendor can afford the rather exorbitant fees charged by the City, he or she
also faces a number of regulatory hurdles. To receive a permit to sell downtown, a
vendor must submit an application to the Board of Licensing for Hucksters,
Hawkers and Peddlers. The application must include a photograph of the location at
which the vendor plans to do business and a photograph of the pushcart the vendor
plans to use. From there, the application must be reviewed by three City agencies
(Traffic, Police, and Community Development). Review by each of these agencies
(any of which can recommend that the permit be denied) culminates in a hearing, at
which time a decision is made on the application. The hearing board meets only
once every other month and requires applicants to submit their materials at least
two weeks before board meeting dates.
If a property owner objects to a vending station in a particular downtown location,
he or she can request a hearing before the Board of Licensing. In non-downtown
areas, a competing property owner has a much more powerful weapon against
vendors. To obtain a minor privilege permit in non-downtown areas, a vendor must
obtain the permission of the property owner on whose sidewalk they plan to operate.
This requirement gives effective veto power to store owners, thus insulating them
from vendor competition and essentially transferring regulatory power over public
property to private entities.
The licensing fees coupled with the regulatory process impose significant burdens on
vendors throughout the Baltimore area, and limit the ability of would-be vendors to
enter the market. For instance, although there is no cap on the number of vending
permits, only about 60 vendors currently operate in downtown Baltimore.
In addition to imposing stiff licensing fees and a burdensome regulatory process on
would-be vendors, the City also prohibits vendors from operating in the most
potentially lucrative market in downtown Baltimore-the Inner Harbor area. As
mentioned in the introduction to this report, the Inner Harbor is the revitalized J
center of the city, and has become a nationally renowned tourist attraction. The
City, however, prohibits all vending south of Lombard Street, the street two blocks
north of the Inner Harbor. Apparently, the City buckled under to pressure from the
Rouse Company (the developer and owner of most Inner Harbor shops) to prohibit
vending in the area, undoubtedly to limit competition with their tenants.
Admittedly, if vendors could operate in the Inner Harbor area, they would have to
be tightly controlled due to the heavy pedestrian traffic. However, the City should
not block out a whole area from those who wish to vend.
Baltimore's prohibitory attitude toward vending in tourist areas extends to vending
within city parks. Prior to 1994, the City issued bids for the opportunity to vend in
the parks. One company, Baltimore Sports and Recreation, dominated the bidding
process and focused primarily on the adult softball leagues that frequented city
parks during the summer. In 1994, the City abolished the bidding process that led to
domination by one company and began issuing permits to vendors to operate in the
city's larger parks. The permits cost 5250.
According to Geri Donnerman of the City's Department of Parks and Recreation,
the process and the vending itself became disorganized and the City found itself
unable to control unauthorized vending. Donnerman cites examples of unlicensed
vendors pulling up onto the grass and selling rugs from the backs of their cars.
Because of these and similar problems, in 1995 the City abolished all vending in city 0
parks. The only exception to this prohibition is in Druid Hill Park. In that park, the
City runs two concession stands.
The City's attempt to deal with vending problems in city parks was both
unnecessary and extreme. Rather than prohibiting vending outright, it could have
relied on more stringent enforcement of vending rules and regulations to prohibit
unauthorized or chaotic vending. While the City certainly has an interest in
maintaining order and preserving the aesthetic qualities of its parks, it should
reconsider its ban and allow vendors once again to sell snacks, beverages, and other
items in a safe, orderly, and aesthetically pleasing manner throughout Baltimore
parks.
Baltimore's Grand Tradition of Arabbing
In addition to these more modem vendors, a slice of history exists amid the narrow
streets of West Baltimore. Although practically everyone is familiar with the sights
and sounds of modem city life-horns, loud music, chatter, truck engines-a trip to
this side of town on a summer day reveals a tradition not familiar to most city
explorers: the c1ippity-clop of horses pulling wagons filled with fruits and vegetables
and the unmistakable bellow ofthe "arabbers" (pronounced "AY-rabbers")
hawking their wares. These few surviving arabbers-the name supposedly derives
from a nineteenth century London slang term for homeless urchins and street 0
c
c
c
peddlers2 -are the "only working reminders of a vanished era of horse-and-wagon
commerce dating back more than 200 years. They recall a time when deliveries of
wood, coal, ice, milk, food and almost everything else were made by horsecart."3
The arabbing tradition is under attack not only from the encroachment of modem
life, such as supermarkets and pickup trucks, but also from the stifling effects of
government regulation. The decline of arabbing began in 1966 when the City made
it virtually impossible to construct any new stables within its limits. Around the
same time, government urban renewal projects closed some of the remaining stables
as well as the City's wholesale produce market in the Inner Harbor, which made it
much more difficult for arabbers to conveniently obtain their stock.
The arabbing tradition struggled along, however, until the arabbers faced a larger
and far more politically powerful adversary: animal-rights activists from the
suburbs who are philosophically opposed to the use of horses for trade, especially in
a city environment.
To fight efforts that would heavily regulate and eventually prohibit arabbing, the
Arabber Preservation Society (APS) was formed in January 1994. The Society-
which had restored some older stables and raised funds to preserve arabbing-swung
into action against Bill 753, which, among other things, would have sharply limited
the number of arabber licenses issued each year. Most members of the community,
while acknowledging problems with how the animals were cared for in some of the
stables, recognized that arabbing is a vital entrepreneurial tradition worthy of
preservation. As Richard Kurin, director of the Smithsonian Institution's folk-life
program has recognized: "In the end, when we lose the arabbers. . . I think a bit of
the city's soul is lost."4 Because ofthe efforts of APS and others, Bill 753 eventually
went down in defeat.
The regulations and harassment of the arabbers have taken their toIL Only about 40
arabher licenses are currently issued. Meanwhile, pressure from the animal-rights
activists continues. According to Steven Blake, a carpenter by trade and president of
APS, new regulations have been pending for more than a year. The regnlations,
pushed by the animal-rights activists, would not need City Council approval and
instead could be implemented by the City's Health Commissioner. Among other
things, the regulations would establish a detailed and stringent
temperature/humidity index that would curtail the ability of arabbers to work. For
instance, according to Blake, the temperature could be 75 degrees with light rain
(but high humidity) and the horses could not be taken out.
The racial dimensions to this struggle have not been lost on the community-
especially the arabbers. While almost all of the arabbers are older, African-
American men from the inner-city trying to eke out a living, the animal-rights
activists are uniformly well-educated, white suburbanites on an ideological crusade.
Moreover, what the activists ignore is that the arabbers themselves are "horse-
crazy" and often choose arabbing as an occupation or do it in their spare time so
that they can be around horses.
~
For the grand tradition of arab bing to be preserved, regulations that go beyond
reasonably protecting the safety of the horses must be defeated. Indeed, the City
should encourage the expansion ofthis dynamic remnant of Baltimore's splendid
history of neighborhood enterprise. Unlike most historic preservation efforts, the
arabbers do not rely on government subsidies or regulation to preserve their
tradition. Rather, the arabbers only ask that the government limit its role to
reasonable regulation of the horses and stables and allow them to continue in the
occupation many of them learned from their fathers or grandfathers.
The arabbing tradition also is important as a rich African-American cultural
tradition. In areas of the city plagued by drugs and urban decay, arabbing
represents a historical link to an era of more sound communities and to a strong
entrepreneurial ethic. Reflecting on the diminished opportunities for arabbing,
Dante, the son of arabber John Gladney said: "This is a simple lifestyle. My
generation was misguided on how to survive. It was all big-screen TVs and gang
[fights). We lost reality within ourselves. But with arabbing, you can be your own
boss, work your pace. "5
As controversy continues to swirl, older arabbers like Pistol, Man-Boy, and Nubby
(arabbers rarely go by their given names) will watch over the stable near Hollins
Market and swap stories as the few remaining arabbers load up their wagons and 0
hit the streets. Despite the challenges faced by arabbers, these resolute
entrepreneurs will doubtlessly kecp going unless extinguished by overzealous
government regulation. As arabber Keith Brooks explained to the Philadelphia
Inquirer:
'They try to push the arabber out of business. But I love this job. Becn doing it 28
years. Sometimes I get in fights with my girlfriend over it. She said I care more
about my horse. And I said, 'Girl, don't talk about my horse.' By early evening,
Brooks and Roy were clopping through the honey-combed streets near Camden
Yards, the arabbers voice still strong: 'Fruit man. Strawberrrrries. . . .'6
We recommend several reforms to open up opportunities for those who wish to
vend. First, the fees charged for permits, especially food-vending permits, should be
substantially reduced. Second, the regulatory process for Baltimore vendors should
be streamlined to make it less burdensome and bureaucratic for would-be vendors
to obtain licenses. Third, the abutting property owner's veto should be eliminated in
non-downtown areas. If an adjoining property owner has a problem with a vendor,
then he or she can present those problems to the board, but the property owner
should not be granted an automatic-veto right. Fourth, the City should open up the
area south of Lombard Street and allow limited vending in the Inner Harbor area.
Fifth, the City should open the city-owned parks once again to limited vending.
o
'C
c
Finally, the City should allow arahbers to continue in this venerable tradition by
limiting its role to reasonable regulation of the horses and stables.
Newsstands
How ironic that Baltimore-the home of one of America's most famous
newspapermen, B.L. Mencken, and whose City logo proudly proclaims it to be,
"The City That Reads"-prohibits newsstands entirely within its bounds. Although
one can buy newspapers from boxes (which, incidentally, are tightly regulated),
newsstands are simply forbidden. This ban is unreasonable and may even raise First
Amendment concerns, as it prohibits a common means of access to information.7
Newsstands are a common feature of life in most American cities, a place where
pedestrians can browse through magazines or quickly buy a paper. Newsstands
come in various shapes and sizes depending on the foot traffic and potential
congestion in a particular area. Although limiting congestion and potential hazards
on city streets are legitimate governmental objectives, such interests can be
furthered through regulation of the size and location of newsstands, rather than
prohibiting them outright. It would be a boon to entrepreneurship and a fitting
tribute to Mencken's legacy for Baltimore to lift its prohibition on newsstands.
Vehicles for Hire
The State of Maryland's Public Service Commission regulates taxicabs and
passenger-carrier services in Baltimore. Indeed, the City really has no say in the
"vehicle-for-hire" industry, and the Baltimore City Code contains only two sections
relating to taxicabs. 8 In contrast, the State's Public Service Commission has
extensive regulations governing vehicle-for-hire service in each county and city in
the state.
Maryland classifies "vehicle-for-hire" services in two categories: taxicabs and
passenger carriers (charters, limousines, coaches, shuttles, etc.). The State issues
permits for operating both a taxicab and a passenger-carrier service. Although the
commission issues permits to either individuals or corporations that wish to operate
taxis, permits for passenger carriers are issued only to companies. The bright side
for individuals or companies who wish to start these services is that the State does
not charge for the permits and there are no mandatory courses for those who wish
to go into the business.
The sharpest contrast between passenger-carrier services and taxicabs in Baltimore
is that while no cap exists on the number of permits issued for passenger carriers,
the number oftaxi permits is strictly limited. Only 1,151 taxi permits have been
issued for Baltimore, and that numher has not changed for approximately 20 years.
Because the City has reached its limit and the Commission will not issue more
r permits, permit owners must trade among themselves. As a result, even though the '
'-
City imposes no fee for a permit from tbe Commission, obtaining a permit tbrougb
trade costs between $12,000 and $20,000.
:>'
Given tbe cap on taxi permits witbin Baltimore, it is not surprising tbat tbere are
only eigbt "approved associations" or companies operating witbin tbe city. Wbile
some cabbies own tbeir own permits, most cannot afford tbe permits and must
tberefore work for a company. Some cab drivers cboose to work for companies even
if tbey own a permit because of bigh insurance rates and tbe ability to take
advantage of dispatcb service. However, it costs drivers (or "independent
contractors") approximately $80 to $85 per day to rent from tbe company (or, in tbe
words of tbe taxicab industry, to become "members" of a particular cab
association). Witb gasoline costs averaging $20 to $30 a day, many cabbies must
work very long days to turn a profit-sometimes as bigb as 17-bour sbifts, even
tbougb tbe legal limit is 12 bours.
In addition to tbe insurance costs and dispatcb services, many drivers cite anotber
less savory reason to work for a company despite bolding a permit-tbe favoritism
sbown by many downtown businesses and tbe City government toward large
companies, especially Yellow Cab. Cabbies complain tbat downtown botels will only
allow certain cab companies to pick up at tbeir location. Tbis practice even extends
to city-owned facilities sucb as tbe convention center, wbere police officers and City
employees bave been known to bassle non-Yellow cabs waiting for fares.
Baltimore's restrictive system of taxicab regulation bas deteriorated working 0
conditions for tbe drivers and bas produced poor results for consumers. A recent
article in tbe Baltimore Sun concerning Royal Cab Company's purcbase of permits
from otber companies concluded tbat tbe "deal doesn't mean pedestrians will
sudden~ be awasb in cabs, tbe scaree number ofwbicb tend to orbit around local
botels." Moreover, leaders in tbe minority communities of Baltimore underscore
tbe Sun's report. Many cite inadequate taxicab service to tbe city's poorer areas and
long waits before a cab will arrive for a pick-up, if tbe cab arrives at all. Anotber
result of tbe cap on permits is tbe rise of gypsy cabs or "backers," illegal, unlicensed
cabs tbat try to fill in tbe gaps in service. Not surprisingly, backers cause mucb
consternation among licensed cabbies trying to make it on tbeir own or witb a cab
company.
Tbe State of Maryland sbould open entry into Baltimore's taxicab market by lifting /
tbe cap on tbe number of taxis permitted on tbe streets, providing greater
entrepreneurial opportunities for drivers and better service for consumers. Anyone
witb a safe driving record, a safe vebicle, and tbe proper insurance sbould be
allowed to enter tbe taxicab market. In advocating opening tbe taxi industry in ber
city in 1994, Cincinnati Mayor Roxanne Qualls described a situation quite similar to
Baltimore's, and eloquently stated the case for reform. By capping tbe number of
permits, tbe State:
o
c
c
c
interjects its judgment in determining need rather than allowing the marketplace to do
so... .
One of the major problems within the industry has been the hoarding of licenses by
companies and individuals. An increase in demand has created a black market on
cab licenses so that a commodity that can be purchased from the city for $161 is sold
on the street for $3,000 or more [up to $20,000 in Baltimore]. City policy should not
facilitate the creation of black markets.
The second problem with the city's current policy as it relates to taxicabs is that cab
companies that control the limited supply of licenses turn around and lease those for
a profit. Drivers pay as much as $100 to $200 per week [usually at least three times
that in Baltimore] for the privilege of using a city-issued cab license. City policies
should not create a system where individuals or companies are making a profit by
leasing city property.IO
In addition to adopting the reforms referenced previously, Baltimore officials
should also refrain from favoritism toward any cab company, thereby placing all
cabbies, whether independent or company-employed, on equal footing.
Cosmetology and Hairbraiding
The practice of African haircare has been a growth industry throughout the nation.
African hairstyling consists primarily of braiding or "cornrowing" hair. The
practice differs from traditional cosmetology in that African or natural haircare
eschews the use of chemicals, relaxants, and other trappings of traditional
cosmetology.
Despite the significant differences between African hairstyling and traditional
cosmetology, many state boards of cosmetology seek to impose the entire regulatory
apparatus on those who wish to practice hairbraiding and cornrowing, often with
destructive consequences for entrepreneurship. Until recently, hairbraiders in the
State of Maryland faced a similar situation. (Regulati()n of cosmetology in Maryland
occurs at the state level by the State Board of Cosmetologists, a division of
Maryland's Department of Labor, Licensing and Regnlation).
Consider the case of Bikane Diop, an immigrant from Senegal. Noting the growing
popularity of braiding and the lack of an established braiding shop in the Baltimore
area, Diop in 1994 opened the African Braiding House on Charles Street on the
north end of Baltimore. He applied for and received a business owner's license from
the City, hired several skilled braiders, trained others, and began what in only a
year's time turned into a successful small business.
In August 1995, inspectors from the State Board of Cosmetology visited Diop's shop
and discovered that Diop and his braiders did not have cosmetology licenses. He was
told that he and the braiders must obtain cosmetology licenses for the braiders to
continue and for the shop to remain open. If he did not abide by the cosmetology
law, he would face fines and even jail time. A cosmetology license in the State of 'J
Maryland requires 1,500 hours oftraining in an approved school. The examination
for a cosmetology license includes demonstrating knowledge of pin curls,
fingerwaves, and other hairstyles that have not been popular for close to half a
century and are never used in hairbraiding.
Diop and several other braiders from other parts of Maryland were summoned
before the State's Cosmetology Board. At the hearing, Diop met Taalib-Din Uqdah,
a national advocate for the reform of cosmetology laws and a champion of the rights
of hairbraiders. Both Uqdah and Diop spoke at the hearing of the inapplicability of
traditional cosmetology laws to the art of African hairbraiding. They urged the
Board to either explicitly exempt hairbraiding from the cosmetology laws, or, at a
minimum, to create limited licensure for hairbraiding.
Although the Board initially seemed reluctant to accept any changes in the law, the
hairbraiders were informed after the hearing that the board supported the concept
of a "new limited practice license for hairbraiding."ll Uqdah, working with
sympathetic legislators in the Maryland General Assembly, drafted legislation for
limited licensure for hairbraiders. The legislation was introduced and a hearing was
conducted on February 29,1996.
Testifying before the Senate Committee on Economic and Environmental Affairs
was Harry Loleas, Deputy Commissioner for the Maryland Department of 0
Occupational and Professional Licensing, the umbrella ageney of which the
cosmetology board is a part. To the surprise of virtually everyone, the Department
took a position different from the initial position of the cosmetology board: it now
favors exempting hairbraiding entirely from any type of cosmetology regulation.
Loleas' testimony before the committee, which reveals a keen understanding of the
problems faced by hairbraiders, merits quotation:
[T]he current cosmetology law does in fact cause a significant problem to
hairbraiders. They are in fact either illegal or forced to take a cosmetology
curriculum that does not reflect their true curriculum and the knowledge they need
to practice their profession. But our reaction in how to deal with this has evolved
over the last few months or so. Our initial reaction to this was in fact to look at the
idea of having a limited license for hairbraiders; but as the department has
considered this more fully, we have come to the conclusion that.. .the definition of
cosmetology be changed to deregulate; to take out of any regulatory mode,
hairbraiding. That the issues of health and safety and other issues which normally
drive regulation are not there in a significant extent for this profession to require
the intervention of government. . . .
We commend the department's change of heart. Hairbraiding and hairbraiding
salons could still be inspected to ensure that health and safety concerns are
o
c
c
c
addressed, but the irrelevant cosmetology regulations need not be applied to this
craft to satisfy legitimate governmental objectives.
Although the department's 180-degree turn diminished the need for separate
licensure, the Department should still make official its determination that
hairbraiding is exempt from cosmetology regulation through the issuance of an
opinion letter or a formal rulemaking procedure. Contrary to the Loleas' testimony,
the statutory definition of cosmetology need not be changed to exempt hairbraiding,
since the practice of braiding and cornrowing is not explicitly included in the
current definition of cosmetology under Maryland law. Again, the Department
should, at the very least, issue some type of official opinion letter or rule to make its
position absolutely clear, so that other braiders will not be subject to harassment or
threats simply for practicing their craft.
Moreover, the Department should apply its insights onhairbraiding to the entire
cosmetology profession. The Department should re-examine the extensive and
antiquated training it requires for cosmetology licensing. It should question whether
the l,500-hour requirement really protects public health and safety or if it rather
serves as an anti-competitive impediment to entry into the cosmetology profession.
Trash Removal
Trash collection in the City of Baltimore is a public monopoly. The 508 employees of
the Collections Division of the City's Solid Waste Department do all of the trash
pickup within city limits. The monopoly extends to both residential and commercial
trash removal and to the collection of recyclables. Moreover, it is illegal to
"scavenge" (pick up recycled materials that are left for City collection). The fine is
$500. In addition to collecting trash, some of the City's collection employees are
actually "beautification police." That is, supervisors from the Collections division
patrol city streets looking for unkempt lawns that may violate the City Code,
regardless of whether a complaint has been made.
As a result ofthis monopoly, private businesses are excluded from the marketplace.
The Superintendent of Collections for the City of Baltimore, while admitting that
privatization has been discussed in the past, defends the monopoly primarily on the
grounds that the City performs non-recyclable collections twice a week, while most
private companies only pick up once a week.
Contrast the City of Baltimore's trash removal system to the one in Baltimore
County. The county has almost entirely privatized its collections system. It employs
49 collection companies to pick up the trash of its more than 320,000 residents. Each
company has a specific area in which to perform trash collection. If for some reason
a hauler cannot pick up, the county makes sure that the trash is removed.
Accordingly, it keeps a limited number of county employees on hand. Compared
with the more than 500 employees of Baltimore, the county collection department
has fIVe employees.
According to Bill Horn, Superintendent of Baltimore County Department of
Collections, the collectors make their rounds once a week, with alternating pickups ()
for bottles and paper. Apartment complexes receive service twice a week, because,
according to Horn, they do not yet have proper reeycling programs in place. Horn
said the county's collection system provides efficient, cost effective service to its
customers, and he has never received complaints that the trash is not picked up
more frequently than once a week. When asked why places like Baltimore City have
collections two times a week without any corresponding benefit to the public, Horn
responded: "People do not like to change."
In comparing Baltimore County's system oftrash collection to the City's public
monopoly, it seems hard to justity keeping competitors out. of the marketplace on
the grounds that the public monopoly provides pickup twice a week-as opposed to
once a week-especially when there does not seem to be any corresponding benefit to
the public. Moreover, the county's privatized system creates a public benefit:
business opportunities for 49 companies and their employees to enter the market. In
fact, Bill Horn of the county's collection department believes that one of the reasons
for the success ofthe county's system is that the contractors are either locally owned
or the employees live in the communities in which they work.
Although initial capital costs can be quite significant for entrepreneurs, Baltimore
County's system allows smaller companies into the marketplace and provides
entrepreneurial opportunities for dozens of companies and their employees. The
City eviscerates these opportunities through maintenance ofits monopoly. The City 0
should reconsider its monopoly on trash collection and follow the lead of Baltimore
County in opening up its trash collection service to private companies.
Child Care
In Baltimore, child care is divided into two categories: care provided by licensed
child-care centers and family child care provided in the home. The regulation of
both types of child care comes from the State of Maryland, not City of Baltimore
officials.
Given Baltimore's alarmingly high rate of nearly 50 percent of households headed
by a single parent, it is essential to maintain low-cost and easily available child-care
services. Thankfully, Maryland seems to have adopted a fairly reasonable
regulatory regime for child care, with some exceptions. Child-care centers in
Maryland must be licensed, while family child-care centers need only be
"registered" with the State. Baltimore allows a home to care for up to eight children
(the maximum permitted by the State) without obtaining a variance from
Baltimore's Zoning Board of Appeals. 12 A use permit required by the Zoning
Board to operate a family child-care center is $14.
One of the most admir,able aspects of Maryland's system is that the State charges no 0
fee for the license application, the licenses or registrations, or the orientation classes .
c
c
c
it requires for those who wish to provide child care. This eliminates at least one
potential hurdle for those who wish to enter this burgeoning field.
Family Child Care
In regard to family child care, the application for registration is rather extensive,
but most of the requirements focus on ensuring the health and safety of the children
(such as emergency escape plans for the home, notarized permission forms to
examine records of child abuse, etc.).13 However, some of the requirements, such as
submitting a statement of the outdoor areas, playgrounds, parks, and pools near the
home, seem directed not at protecting health and safety, but at guaranteeing a
certain level of recreational opportunities outside the home. Such factors should not
be a basis for denying registration to a family child-eare center that may be fully
capable of providing care and enjoyment to children within the home or backyard
without resort to outside activities.
Another troublesome regulation of family child-eare providers is the built-in bias
against issuing any waivers or variances to the regulations. The regulations provide
that the State may not waive a particular regulation or grant a variance unless a
child-care provider "presents clear and compelling evidence that a regulation is met
by an alternative which complies with the intent of the regulation... ."14 Although
it is certainly important to not vest too much discretion in State officials to waive
important health and safety requirements, the State should take a more flexible
approach to individuals who wish to provide safe, low-cost care to satisfy ever-
expanding child-care needs. The presumption against waivers and the inflexibility of
the regulations make it difficult to grant entirely reasonable waivers to those who
safely provide child care, but who may not be able to meet every minute facet of the
regulations.
In contrast to such jurisdictions as New York, Maryland has rather reasonable
educational requirements for directors and employees of child-care centers and for
those who wish to run family child-care centers out of their homes. To establish a
family child-care center, one must attend a three-hour orientation class. The classes
are offered twice a month in each ofthe state's regions, usually in local libraries.
The family providers must be at least 18 years old. They are not required to have a
college degree or any advanced training in child care. The family provider need only
complete six hours of health-related classes and three hours of approved training on
child development or child-care business classes. For a provider's registration to be
renewed (registrations must be renewed every two years), the provider must
complete six hours of approved training on child health issues and six additional
hours on business-related issues.
Child-care Centers
As mentioned previously, child-care centers outside the home must be licensed by
the State. To be licensed, centers must meet detailed regulations governing
everything from food storage to the disposal of refuse.IS Many of the regulations
are aimed at protecting children's health and safety. However, some ofthe
regulations are so detailed and onerous that they may serve as a barrier to the
establishment ilf a child-care center.
~
For instance, the State sets forth in extensive detail, complete with mathematical
equations, the space requirements for child-care centen, supposedly to ensure a
specific amount of "useable floor space." One must wonder, however, whether such
complexity actually serves the needs of children or whether a more flexible standard
could be developed that would allow adequate space for children to learn and play
without seemingly arbitrary requirements.
All directon of a licensed child-care center for preschool children must be at least
21 yean old and have a high school diploma or its equivalent. In contrast to New
York's requirement that child-care center directon receive a master's degree or be
enrolled in a master's program, Maryland requires that all directon have
completed at least six college semester houn or 90 houn of approved training in
addition to one year of experience in child care. Perhaps in an effort to lift the
credentialing requirements for smaller child-eare providen, Maryland has a three-
tiered approach for credentialing directon of small, medium, and large child-care
centeno For instance, a director of a large institution (more than 40 children) must
have attained at least an associate's degree in early childhood development and have
two yean of experience in child care. In contrast, directon of small centen (fewer
than 20 children) need only have one year of work experience under supervision or ~
two yean of experience caring for preschoolen as a registered family child-care
provider. A director of any center caring for infants needs an additional 4S houn of
training in infant care.
Maryland's effort to loosen credentialing requirements for smaller centen is
commendable. The approach creates a fairly reasonable regulatory environment.
Home-based Businesses
As throughout the country, home-based businesses are growing rapidly in
Baltimore. Unfortunately, zoning regulations that govern businesses operating in
the home have not kept up with this important sector of the economy. According to
Don Grauel, who handles legislative matten for the Maryland Home-Based
Business Association, zoning regulations in Baltimore and many other cities are
outdated and create a climate of fear and uncertainty for those starting a business in
the home. For instance, many zoning ordinances prohibit business equipment in the
home. When these ordinances were drafted, they were obviously aimed at banning
industrial-like equipment, such as a printing press, from a residential setting.
However, given the breadth ofthe ordinances, they conceivably could be applied to
such innocuous modern business equipment as fax machines and computen.
o
c
c
c
Grauel claims that while the City of Baltimore and Baltimore County have not
aggressively enforced their outmoded zoning ordinances, the laws nevertheless make
those who wish to start home-based businesses reluctant to contact any government
official with questions or concerns, for fear of running afoul of the law. Of coune,
this atmosphere hinden the growth of home-based businesses and gives an air of
illegitimacy to a vital and growing part ofthe economy.
Last year the Home-based Business Association pushed House Bill 158 in the
Maryland Legislature, a bill that would have standardized local ordinances
throughout the state to make them conducive to operating businesses in the home.
Concerns about the displacement of local authority and controlled to the bill's
defeat. The Association has now turned its efforts to reform of local laws. Grough
points to Montgomery and Prince George's counties as examples ofzoning laws in
Maryland conducive to starting up and maintaining a home-based business.
Baltimore should likewise revamp its zoning ordinance and lift the veil of
uncertainty and fear surrounding businesses in the home.
Conclusion
In its transformation to a tourism center, Baltimore must not fonake its robust
tradition of entrepreneunhip. Too many entry-level opportunities in Baltimore-
whether in vending, newsstand operation, taxicab-driving, or trash removal-have
been shut down by a combination of state and local regulations. Although sports
teams and tourism certainly bring jobs and dollan into the downtown area,
Baltimore's small shops and entry-level entrepreneun are also a vital, year-round
source of employment and opportunity for those struggling to gain a foothold on the
economic ladder. Removal ofthe barrien and regulation documented in this study
will go a long way toward making Baltimore once again a center of commercial
activity-whether the enterprise be large or small.
Endnotes
I u.s. Department of Commerce, County and City Data Book, at xxix-xxx (12th edition 1994) (census
data).
2 Mary Pemberton, "If The Arabbers Go, A Bit of the City's Romance Will be Lost, Too," Capper's,
June 6, 1995.
3 John Sherwood, America's Vanishing Lives 209 (1994).
4 Mary Pemberton, "If The Arabbers Go, A Bit of the City's Romance Will be Lost, Too," Capper's,
June 6, 1995.
5 Jeffrey Fleishman, "Vanishing Breed," The Philadelphia Inquirer, May 28, 1996.
61d.
7 See City of Lakewood v. Plain Dealer Publishing Co., 486 U.S. 750 (1988) (leaving open question of t""I\.
whether it would be constitutional for a city to ban newsracks entirely). .~
8 BaiL City Code, Art. 19, **187, 187A (criminalizing refusal to pay fare and making it illegal for
eabs outside of the City to pick up passengers within City limits).
9 Alec Matthew Klein, "Royal Cab Buys Two County Taxi Services," The Baltimore Sun, June 3,
1996.
to Roxanne Qualls, Cincinnati Enquirer, May 31,1994.
II Letter of Kathleen A. Harryman, Administrator, State Board of Cosmetologists to Taalib-Din
Uqdah, November 22,1995.
12 Ifthe family child-care center has more than eight children, it must be licensed as a child-care
center. If such a facility was operated out of the home, a provider needs a variance from the City's
Zoning Board. The variance requires a hearing before the Board and the application Is $175.
However, the City's Building and Construction Department reviews plans without charge to
determine whether a center needs a variance or not.
I3 See Md. Reg. 07.04.01.04.
14 See Md. Reg. 07.04.01.12.
15 See Md. Reg. 07.04.02.35 et seq.
~
Copyright @ 1997 Institute for Justice
1717 Pennsylvania Ave., NW, Suite 200, Washington, D.C. 20006
Tel (202) 955-1300 Fax (202) 955-1329
http://www.instituteforjustice.org
__ ',_ "W__.'___._'_~'~_~..__~~H_ ___. _'------....--~_ __.____.~___.._.__~_.~._+..+_..._.._ ..___~._______~_.
Back to T AXI-L Home Pa2e
o
o
E
(
i
!
o
o
c
c
c
This page has been accessed 194 times since 7 May 1997.
PUTTING CUSTOMERS FIRST
Taxicab Reform in the Greater Toronto Area (GTA)
by Consumer Policy Institute
Toronto, Canada
April 1997
PART ONE
Analysis of the Problems
I. Introduction
Urban transportation is one of the last transport monopolies to confront the
customer-driven challenges of a competitive marketplace. In most cities,
the public's flexibility to move freely on a competitive urban transit
system has been compromised by the inefficiencies of the local
government's monopoly service provider, and by a complex regulatory
framework that discourages innovation and prevents safe private sector
alternatives.
Freedom of movement, and the freedom to pursue a respectable living in a
chosen field, should be the right of every individual, yet these freedoms
have been limited by self-interest and obliging government bureaucracies
since the turn of the century. Authorized jitney transport, for example, has
been all but banned in North America since the mid- to late I 920s. Jitneys
are taxicabs that run on fixed routes and can be hailed by passengers. They
often accommodate up to 10 people as opposed to the six that regular
taxicabs are allowed to carry. Jitneys are so named because the fare was at
one time a "jitney," which was slang for a 5-cent piece. Jitneys operate
today in at least one Canadian city, several small American cities and a
number of European cities.ill
Unfortunately, the regulatory process is gradually taking the freedom of
movement and the right to pursue a respectable living away from society's
most vulnerable people, through restrictions in their choice and
opportunity. W.T. Stanbury, an economist specializing in the impact of co-
redistribution through regulation, estimates that approximately 20 per cent
J
o
o
c
of Canada's economic output, including taxicabs, is subject to some form
of direct economic regulation.ill For the United States, Inc. magazine
points out that approximately 10 per cent of all jobs requires some form of
licence, and that many of those jobs are low-skill, entry-level occupations
such as taxicab driving, working as a street vendor, cosmetology, trash
hauling, and recycling.ill A similar analysis has not been done in Canada,
but given our tendency to regulate coupled with the fact that all of the
industries in Canada listed in the Inc. article are either regulated or
government owned, it is reasonable to conclude that the number of
regulations that are a barrier to low- income and unemployed Canadians is
equal to, if not greater than, the number in the U.S. Nothing illustrates that
point more than the taxicab business. in Metropolitan Toronto and
surrounding communities that, together, make up the Greater Toronto
Area (GTA).
c
In most Canadian cities, a competitive taxicab industry remains a local or
provincial government sanctioned illusion. The business, whose customers
are disproportionately those less well off (because limited financial
resources often prevent the ownership and operation of a motor vehicle), is
one of the last transportation industries to be opened up to a deregulated
environment. Tight control on taxicab supply and government-set tariffs
have resulted in consumers paying an exaggerated price for a stale and
uninspired service. In his 1982 paper, The Taxi Industry and Its
Regulation in Canada, Benoit-Mario Papillon points out that most
regulations governing the taxicab industry "pushes up the cost of taxi
service in Canadian cities [studied] by 30 to 50 per cent. "ill
By 1987, in Metropolitan Toronto specifically, taxicab regulation (which
includes tight controls on supply and price) had resulted in a price for
service approximately 25 per cent higher than if the market was
unregulated. ill
Taxicab regulation discriminates against single mothers, low- and fixed-
income wage earners and the physically disadvantaged by reducing supply
in their neighbourhoods and making the product uncompetitive and
unaffordable. Taxi regulation also acts as a barrier for displaced workers,
recently arrived immigrants, and people on welfare who would prefer a
hand-up rather than a handout to become economically self-sufficient in
an easy-entry, low-cost business. Although government is cutting back on
the handout in the form of reduced unemployment insurance and welfare
pay-outs, it is hindering the hand-up by retaining urmecessary regulations
that only serve to absorb tax dollars and act as a barrier to individual
c
entrepreneurship.
~,
Finally, current restrictions on vehicle supply is limiting the number of
opportunities that postsecondary students have in order to pay for rising
tuition fees during a period of high youth unemployment and tighter
control and eligibility requirements for student loans.
A truly competitive taxicab industry that promoted the use of jitneys and
other alternative transportation services would give all members of society
greater public transportation options and business opportunities in an age
of slashed government budgets, urban transit service cuts, and congested
city roads.
This study, while commenting on the economic effects of regulation on
the taxicab industry in general, primarily focuses on the Greater Toronto
Area (GTA), with particular emphasis being placed on the Corporation of
Metropolitan Toronto and the proposed amalgamation of the five cities
and one borough that will make up the new City of Toronto.
II. Evolution of taxi regnlation
o
The taxicab is the most immediate and flexible of the so-called paratransit
vehicles. Paratransit is a term given to small passenger transport vehicles
that operate informally on a fare-paying basis. Paratransit vehicles
represent the median between the personal convenience of the private
automobile and the d&licated route structure of public transit.
In most cities, taxicabs cruised the streets in an unregulated, free market
until the I 930s, when car prices and wages tumbled, and transit systems
and established taxicab companies were confronted by cutthroat
competition from struggling, unemployed workers who saw the low
capital, easy-entry characteristics of taxicab driving as a way of
maintaining a livelihood.
According to a report by the U.S. Federal Trade Commission, pressure to
regulate the taxicab industry was not stimulated by the public interest, but
by limited self-interests. "Pressure for restrictions on the taxi industry
came from the American Transit Association, public transit firms,
established taxi fleets, and the National Association of Taxicab Owners
o
f
c
(which passed a resolution favouring entry and minimum fare controls)."ID
According to figures released by the Federal Trade Commission, an
estimated 43 out of 93 U.S. cities with a population of more than 100,000
had restricted entry into the taxi industry by 1934.
Taxicab regulation in Toronto and other Canadian cities
In major Canadian centres, taxicab regulation has evolved much as in the
United States. In the I 920s, privately owned streetcar companies, fearful
of increased competition, successfully pressured Toronto city council to
ban jitneys, arguing that such form of transportation would worsen
congestion on already inadequate roads. Existing taxicab owners were also
successful in eliminating competition from new entrants by convincing
council to regulate the supply of taxicabs on city streets. Council said that
regulation was necessary because taxicabs were a public service.
c
A proliferation of regulation took place in the 1930s and was based on the
same economic and anticompetitive arguments. The Manitoba Legislature
argued that taxi transport was a public service similar to electricity,
telephone, and mass transit monopolies when it limited the supply of
taxicabs in Winnipeg in 1935.rn
In 1937, Montreal city council based the need for taxi regulation on
congestion caused by an unnecessarily high number of taxis. Regulation
would also address the low incomes of taxi operators, which city council
believed was caused by excessive competition. But Montreal relaxed its
restriction on supply in 1946, following complaints by taxi users "tired of
being unable to obtain a taxi by telephone," and a subsequent report by
1.0. Asselin, chairman of the city's executive committee, that disputed the
earlier rationale. Asselin reported that complaints about an excessive
number of taxis came "primarily from those worki~ in the industry,"
while low wages were a product of the Depression.
Immediately after council relaxed regulations on supply, the number of
Montreal taxicab licences exploded from 765 to 4,280. Council restored
limits on taxicabs in 1952, and taxi regulation in Quebec became a
provincial government responsibility in 1973.
Creation of the Metropolitan Licensing Commission
c
In 1956, the recently created Metropolitan Toronto regional govemment
set up the Metropolitan Licensing Commission. The Commission has
licensing authority over a wide range oflocal businesses, including local
taxicab supply and tariffs.
"'J
The taxicab industry is a public service insofar as its function is to pick up
members of the public at the customers' point of convenience and
transport them to their destination of choice in exchange for payment.
Therefore, a limited amount of regulation is necessary to ensure the safety
of the passenger, and to protect surrounding vehicular and pedestrian
traffic. Such regulation should cover driver qualifications, vehicle
insurance requirements, and vehicle maintenance standards (including
compulsory equipment for the purpose of safety). A licensing commission
must have the power to revoke a licence if a driver or taxi company is in
violation of basic regulations. But most municipal and provincial (or U.S.
state) licensing commissions have extended their authority by imposing
. regulations on taxicab supply, boundaries of operation, driver behaviour,
and price.
Excessive regulation has benefitted existing participants in Canada's
taxicab industry. Fixed pricing, jurisdictional restrictions, and closed entry
have resulted in a transfer of wealth from the customer to the producers in
the industry.
o
III. Protecting a stale industry
The shape, size, and mechanics of the Toronto taxicab have altered
significantly since the early 1900s when established taxi companies used a
willing city council to discourage competition. Market potential --
although weakened by the economic downturn of the early 1900s -- has
flourished over the last 10 years. Public awareness and tougher
enforcement of drinking and driving legislation, higher automobile
operating costs (including insurance), congestion, increased tourism (who,
along with business travellers, make up the so-called "floating
population"), and greater use of the taxicab as an intercity courier service
by the business community have increased demand and created new
opportunities for entrepreneurial cabbies prepared to seize the initiative.
Little else, except for the fortunes of established taxi companies, has
changed since the Metropolitan Licensing Commission took control of the
industry in 1956. As a result, consumers are overpaying for an
underperforming industry characterized by lengthy waits for unclean
o
c
vehicles, operated by substandard drivers.
Commandeering a taxicab is a universal practice, where the customer is
given three basic choices:
1. To telephone an order;
2. To secure a taxicab at a nearby taxi stand; or,
3 . To hail a cruising taxicab on the street.
The following describes the three options for securing a taxicab in the
GT A, and how excessive regulation has severely compromised the distinct
competitive advantages of each practice.
Telephone orders
c
The telephone gives a customer the greatest advantage in terms of
convenience, flexibility and competition. The vehicle is requested to show
up at a precise location 24 hours a day. The customer has exclusive control
over the company he will patronize. The percentage of on-time arrivals
will vary according to the time of day, weather conditions, and location,
but the option of cancelling an order and contacting a rival taxicab service
rests with the customer.
The telephone order already gives a customer the convenience to preselect
a taxicab based on personal criteria and past experience (on-time
performance, knowledgeable drivers, cleanliness of vehicle), although
service even among operators driving for a specific cab company is not
consistent. Because of price controls, the telephone user is denied the
added value of shopping the market on the basis of price.
Taxi stands
Taxi stands originated in 17th-century London as spots where customers
could fmd horse-drawn hansom cabs bidding for their business based on
price and service. If competition at the stand was too fierce, the cabbie
would patrol the streets of London for custom.
c
Properly managed, a taxi stand should be a model of efficiency in the
taxicab business, resulting in fast turnarounds, with clean vehicles and
price competitive rates attracting customers, and, to a certain extent,
helping to set spot-market rates for nearby cruising cabs (see Cruising
taxicabs). Instead, most taxi stands are a subsidized haven for the most
inefficient taxicab operators.
.~
There are three key reasons taxi stands in an overregulated and protected
environment such as Metropolitan Toronto do not work:
Lack of incentive: Metropolitan Toronto provides arterial roadway to the
taxi industry free of charge for the purpose of maintaining taxi stands.
Unlike a private car owner who must pay a meter in advance of parking
time estimated (and risks a fine if the time parked exceeds time available
on the meter), the taxicab operator pays nothing for taxi stand space, thus
eliminating the incentive for fast fare turnarounds. The City of Toronto
has reserved three prime taxi stand locations (including the stand in front
of Union Station, the city's VIA and commute rail hub), for drivers who
are veterans of the Second World War. These spots are now being used by
drivers who did not serve in the Second World War, but maintain
ownership of those spots through informal arrangements with veterans.
o
Industry intimidation and unwritten rules: Most customers approach a
taxi stand under the misconception that they must take the first vehicle in
line. In reality, customers may select any taxicab they chose, although the
linear design and apprqach to the stand makes vehicle exiting difficult, and
too many drivers are more interested in preserving an unwritten rule of
first in, first out, through intimidation and outright refusal to transport a
customer. Neither the industry nor the Metropolitan Licensing
Commission that regulates it have shown much interest in protecting the
customer's right of choice through information and enforcement.
System weighted to promote inefficiency: The first two reasons have
conspired to create a third; a network of inefficient taxicab operators who
use the taxi stand as an opportunity to sit in their vehicles and wait for
business to come to them. By encouraging such abuse, the current system
of no charge taxi stands permits an oversupply of poor drivers, thus
forcing more ambitious drivers, who would likely use a taxi stand as a
competitive tool of business, out of the industry.
o
c
Cruising taxicabs
The cruising taxicab participates in a fluctuating market, in which the
customer's decision to take a cab is often impulsive, and in which the main
concern (particularly when weather or time is a factor) is availability of
supply rather than price, age, or cleanliness of the vehicle. Price regulation
that enforces a flat fee fails to recognize the full asset value of a service at
certain times of the day. Regulatory authorities such as the Metropolitan
Licensing Commission claim that unregulated tariffs will lead to price
gouging, and to congested city streets cluttered with taxicabs and
customers bartering and arguing over fares. The criticism is reminiscent of
earlier claims that city streets were not wide enough to support jitney
traffic.
c
Cruising, which has been banned in several North American cities, has
also become something of a red herring by opponents of taxicab
deregulation in general, and unregulated pricing in particular. Many
economists who specialize in price regulation dismiss the prospect of fare
reductions, since customers who hail taxicabs tend to take the first
available vehicle, meaning that drivers who discount fares are cutting into
the revenues unnecessarily.OO
Both criticisms reflect conventional thinking on the part of the taxicab
industry and its regulators. There are, however, innovative methods to
introducing price competition while giving customers upfront pricing
information and guaranteed discounts. Such voluntary innovations could
include posting a standard rate on the side of the door (compulsory in
cities such as Washington, New York, and others), using a system of roof
lights to indicate when standard, discounted, or premium pricing are in
effect, and upgrading the taxi meter to allow the driver to enter an agreed
upon per kilometre tariff or flat fare. In a deregulated market, such
suggestions should be implemented at the discretion of the taxicab or fleet
owner to attract new business.
IV. Licences
c
For two legitimate reasons, the bulk of the taxicab industry (fleet owners
and independent taxicab operators) opposed open entry and increased
competition; price controls have artificially shrunk the market below its
full potential and inflated the value of the licence (referred to in this study
as the plate) that authorize a holder to provide a taxicab service.
J
The Metropolitan Licensing Commission charges $4,500 for a plate,
which has a current open market value of approximately $85,000. The
open market value of the plate reflects the conditions of the market
compared with the number of licensed taxicabs on the road. In 1979, for
example, the market value for a Metro plate was $30,000, compared with
a market value for that same plate in 1987 (the height of I 980s mass
consumption and consumerism) of $105,000.
For a first time applicant and potential entrepreneur who wants to invest
time and money in the Metropolitan Toronto taxi industry, the average
waiting period for a plate is approximately nine years. A successful
applicant must purchase any additional plates on the open market.
Taxicabs, as previously noted, should be a low-cost, easy-entry business.
But because of control on supply and the resulting waiting list, the
potential entrepreneur is left with two immediate options:
I. To rent a vehicle, thereby increasing the capital value of a plate for
the cartel of current owners; or,
2. To purchase a plate on the open market.
o
The rental of a vehicle further demonstrates the inconsistency of price
regulation, and how fleet owners and lessees stand to benefit from
regulation. While Metro sets tariffs, it has no corresponding regulation on
what an owner may charge an operator to rent his vehicle, thereby
ensuring that what limited deregulation exists in the industry benefits the
taxicab owner at the expense of both the vehicle contractor and the
customer. (Although this study identified Metropolitan Toronto's uneven
pricing structure of regulated pricing versus unregulated vehicle leasing
charges as a problem for both the customer and the lessee under current
market conditions, it does not recommend that the Metropolitan Licensing
Commission should attempt to adjust the imbalance by introducing price
caps on what a lessor may charge for his vehicle.)
Drivers who purchase a plate on the open market do so with the approval
of the Metropolitan Licensing Commission (which makes an additional
$4,500 per transfer). These drivers are investing in an artificial market
where a capital gain (in addition to the estimated annual return of 15 per
o
c
cent on the value of a plate) relies on the issuance of new plates not
keeping pace with increases in the fixed and floating population (tourists,
business travellers, and so on), and other changes in the marketplace. Price
and supply restrictions mean that prosperity in the industry can only come
from substandard and costly service to the customer.
If Metro were to switch to an open-entry system, the open lI\Wket value of
the plate would disappear almost overnight, resulting in financial hardship
for those who had purchased a plate on the open market as a consequence
to the licensing commission's control over supply.
In any attempt to change the status of the GT A from a closed market to an
open-entry system, the plate and the compensation for owners will be the
biggest obstacle. The issue must be discussed thoroughly and handled
appropriately to ensure a smooth overnight transition.
c
The plate is, in fact, the property of Metropolitan Toronto, and the
Metropolitan Licensing Commission reserves the right to revoke it. Those
who purchase a plate on the open market, do so with the knowledge that
possession does not equal ownership in this instance. But because of
controlled entry, the plate has evolved into a necessary business
investment for many taxicab owners, sirnilar to capital assets in a fixed
business location.
By controlling supply while allowing for an open market resale of existing
plates, the Metropolitan Licensing Commission has developed an uneven
playing field among plate holders that greatly benefits owners who
purchase their plate from the commission, while exposing those
purchasing plates on the open market to great risk. Based on a $4,500
licence fee and a current open market value of $85,000, a taxicab owner
who purchases a plate from the commission has a no-risk opportunity to
realize a 1,800 per cent return on his asset ifhe sells the plate at market
value after an obligatory three-year holding period. The owner who
purchases that same plate on the open market, assumes all the risk since
control of the market and ownership of the plate rests exclusively in the
hands of the Metropolitan Licensing Commission.
c
In a normal business environment, risk would often be assumed by the
investor. But regulation has made the taxicab industry anything but
normal, and control over supply has created an environment where
exposure to high risk over the plate is unavoidable if the owner wants to
be in business or expand his business to include more vehicles. The
commission can decide to increase vehicle supply, introduce an open-entry
policy (as is being recommended in this study), or ban the practice of open
market resale without compensating the investment made by the open
market plate holder.
.~
Most Toronto plate owners bought their plates in good faith based on rules
established by the Metropolitan Licensing Commission, and with the
confidence that the current system would at least protect the value of their
investment. For many owners, the value of the plate is security for
retirement. It would be unfair for the City of Toronto to implement any
new system that would significantly devalue the worth of a plate without
offering appropriate compensation.
V. Discrimination through regulation
Canada's overregulated taxicab system discriminates against women (who
are frequent users of taxicabs as a safety precaution when travelling
alone), the poor, and entry-level entrepreneurs who lack investment capital
or a formal education. The regulations favour those with the most
influence, in this case the taxi fleet owners and brokers. In his paper, The
Economic Effects of the Direct Regulation of the Taxicab Industry in
Metropolitan Toronto, Professor D. Wayne Taylor describes Metro's
regulated environment as a "producer protection hypothesis."
o.
"The producer protection hypothesis," Professor Taylor wrote, "calls for
regulation to be provided either to offset or prevent the effects of a
competitive market situation, or to redistribute income from consumers to
producers. The expected effects of this hypothesis are controlled or closed
entry, inflated prices above marginal cost, price discrimination, lower
quantities of goods produced, production inefficiencies and economic
profits. "illU
Because the Metropolitan Licensing Commission artificially limits the
supply of taxicabs through a controlled-entry policy, consumers paid an
estimated 13.5 per cent more for services in 1977 than they should have in
an open-entry market. That represents a transfer of $8.1 million from the
consumer to the producer. Ten years later, the situation worsened for the
consumer. Metro taxicab users were paying 24.8 per cent, or $39.1
million, more than was necessary because of controlled entry. Had
Metropolitan Toronto not controlled entry in 1987, a standard trip would
o.
c
have cost $4.90 instead of $6.52, and an additional 730 taxicabs would
have been competing for business.ill}
Because low-income households often lack the resources to support a
private automobile, they spend a larger proportion of their disposable
income on taxis than high-income households, thereby bearing the brunt
of the inflated price and the lower availability of vehicles. The
underprivileged in Canada's urban population are becoming increasingly
dependent on taxicabs as cities sprawl and urban transit systems such as
the Toronto Transit Commission (TIC) scale back operations in the
downtown core to spread limited resources across a broader area.ml
The traditional taxicab fare meter has been designed primarily for price-
regulated markets where the tariff is set by the distance travelled. In
Metropolitan Toronto, as with most jurisdictions, drivers are only
permitted to negotiate a flat fare on trips that take them where the vehicle
is licensed outside the Metro area, or to the airport. Once outside the
licensed jurisdiction, drivers cannot legally pick up fares. The meter is a
licensing authority's preferred method of securing a price for service, and
enforcing pre-set pricing regulations.
c
Metropolitan Toronto cannot have a competitive cruising market because
!here are not enough taxicabs to hail. Three thousand four hundred
taxicabs, or approximately 1.6 vehicles per 1,000 residents, ply Metro
streets.
U .8. experiences in taxicab deregulation show that cities with open entry
have more than three times the number of cabs per capital than regulated
cities.Wi And supply helps to control cost to the customer. For example, in
New York City the number of so-called medallion cabs is limited to
approximately 1.7 vehicles per 1,000 residents. The medallion refers to the
metal numbered shield that is attached to the outside of each of New York
City's landmark, the yellow taxicab. (In Canada, the medallion is referred
to as the licence.) An average four-mile fare in a licensed New York City
cab costs approximately U8$5.70. In Washington, D.C., where there is
unrestricted market entry and approximately 13 taxicabs per 1,000
residents (the highest ratio in the country), the average four-mile fare costs
approximately U8$3.30.
c
New York City restricted open entry in 1937, but did not increase the
original supply of 11,737 medallioned cabs for another 59 years. New
York's Taxi and Limousine Commission auctioned off 400 new
medallions in 1996 as part of regulatory reforms that included a fare
increase of 20 per cent (the first since 1990), and the banning of second-
hand vehicles (wiping out the benefit of the increase for many New York
City cabbies). As a result of demand greatly outstripping supply, a
thriving, underground gypsy cab industry developed in the 1940s. The
commission was forced to officially recognize gypsy cabs in 1987, as
legitimate vehicles for hire. In theory, vehicles for hire cannot cruise for
hailers, must rely solely on the radio dispatch, and cannot place taxi signs
on the car roof except in Staten Island. But as writer Thomas G. Donland
observes in Barron's, rules governing vehicles for hire are observed
mostly in the breach. (ill
.~
Drivers of vehicles for hire can negotiate fares with the passenger, which
makes them a favourite source of transportation for the telephone market
and street smart, frequent cab users searching for the lowest price.
Ignoring the environment
Taxicab regulation too often works at cross-purposes from the
environmental and conservation interests that various governments claim
to support and promote. While governments encourage the use of car
pools to reduce vehicle emissions and relieve pressure on crowded roads
and highways, they refuse to re-introduce the car pool concept to taxicabs
by allowing for shared-ride services. A shared ride allows a driver to
realize greater efficiencies in his vehicle by picking up and dropping off
passengers along a loosely defmed route. Passengers willing to share a
taxicab and accommodate a slight deviation from their route to drop off
customers would benefit from a lower fare than if they used a taxicab
exclusively. During the Second World War, drivers in Washington, D.C.,
created a hybrid between the exclusive cab and the jitney by displaying
destination signs in their front window for passengers to hail a cab that
was going in their direction.
o
In Metropolitan Toronto, the shared-ride concept is available for the
disabled and seniors who qualify through the Toronto Transit
Commission's (TIC) Wheel-Trans service. But the curb to curb Wheel-
Trans service, with its high labour and capital costs, is being reduced
through government budget cuts at the same time that demand is
increasing. Experiments in the U.S. have demonstrated that shared-ride
taxicab service with vouchers for the disabled and low-income users
(including seniors) will result in more people being transported at a lower
o
c
cost. ill]
A shared-ride policy would also promote local transit and intercity
commuter systems by feeding passengers into railway and subway stations
and main bus lines -- ironic, given that in the 1 930s, private streetcar
operators and public transit commissions pressured city councils to ban
jitneys and shared-ride services. The shared-ride service also relieves peak
demand on local transit systems. Not surprisingly, neither the TIC nor GO
Transit have conducted studies into how their monopoly approach to
service cutbacks could be softened by encouraging a more efficient and
competitive taxicab industry in the GT A.
A second regulatory cause of vehicle inefficiency with an urmecessary
consequence to the environment are jurisdictional boundaries that only
permit a driver to transport a passenger from one city to another. The
driver is prevented from picking up passengers while making the return
trip, resulting in an empty vehicle releasing emissions into the
environment, occupying road space, and resulting in a personal cost to the
driver.
c
In Metropolitan Toronto, the biggest promoter of waste through
jurisdictional restriction has been Lester B. Pearson International Airport,
which is located in the City of Mississauga, but whose licences for fare
pickups at Terminals One, Two, and Three (privately operated) have
traditionally been issued by Transport Canada. Metro's taxicabs can take
fares into the airport, but cannot bring fares back into the city without
risking a $100 fme. There are, however, no restrictions on airport licensed
taxicabs (which are limousines) that transport passengers in and out of the
airport.
The airport system, which encourages inefficiency through its taxi stand
approach to business, serves neither the non-Transport Canada licensed
taxicab operator, nor the airline passenger. The increase in licensed
vehicles at Canada's busiest airport has not kept pace with the increase in
passenger volume. In cases where airport ground transportation managers
(commissionaires) are confronted by a shortage of airport licensed
vehicles, calls for non-airport licensed cabs are largely ignored because
those vehicles must join the taxi stand queue and are forced to yield their
place in line to any airport licensed cab that shows up.lli.l
VI. The impact of proposed Metro amalgamation and the GT A
c
The January 1996 Report of the GTA Task Force (Golden Report) and the
Ontario government's proposal to amalgamate the five cities and one
borough that form the Metropolitan Toronto Corporation will negatively
affect urban transportation if reform is not a part of the amalgamation
package.
J
The Report of the GTA Task Force has failed in areas such as urban
transportation to recommend a market-driven model to break the supply
and price barriers that presently separate the customer from competitive
local transportation options. For example, the report recommends the
consolidation of taxicab licensing by recommending that licensing for
taxicabs, limousines, and tow trucks be assigned to a Greater Toronto
Area council representing 29 cities and regions in the GTA.
If, as appears likely, the provincial government follows the
recommendation of the Golden Report and appoints an unelected Greater
Toronto Area council to coordinate services across the broader Greater
Toronto Area, and that the council becomes responsible for taxicab
licensing without the deregulation of entry and price, three things will
occur:
I. The inefficient jurisdictional barriers outlined in this study will
have been eliminated, except for cities and regions outside of the
GTA;
2. Consumers in cities that neighbour Metro will start to see a decline
in taxicab service levels; and,
3. Approximately 3,400 Metropolitan Toronto taxicab plate holders
will see a combined $170 million investment in plates (based on all
available plates realizing full value at current market prices)
diluted almost overnight by the increase in supply from neighbour-
ing GT A vehicles. Open entry would wipe out the market value of
the plate entirely.
~
Jurisdictional barriers
Without an increase in vehicle supply, a Greater Toronto Area council
would try to meet the public transportation requirements of 4.5 million
people with a single pool of GT A taxicabs. From a driver-customer
standpoint, the benefits are apparent. A Burlington taxicab driver
transporting a fare to Scarborough (which is expected to become part of
the amalgamated City of Toronto as of January I, 1998) will not have to
o
c
make the return trip empty. Instead, the operators can pick up and drop off
fares over a wider territory.
Unfortunately, without reforms that end jurisdictional territory altogether,
the same Burlington operator who transports a fare to neighbouring
Hamilton will have to either continue to make the return trip with an
empty vehicle or break the law to cover the extra cost of transporting a
passenger across jurisdictional lines.
Increase in taxicab vehicles within the amalgamated City of Toronto
Because communities in the GTA outside of Metro are both low density
and heavy users of personal motor vehicles, taxicab drivers in cities such
as Mississauga, Brampton, Markham, and so on, will be inclined to desert
their home market for high density areas such as downtown Toronto.
c
While the segment of the Toronto market that hails taxicabs would
immediately benefit from an increased supply of vehicles, the overall
benefit will be limited if price deregulation is not part of a reform package.
(Taxicabs in the GTA, but outside of the Metropolitan Toronto
boundaries, are unlikely to join a Metro-based dispatch service. What is
more likely, is that existing dispatch services in Metro and surrounding
communities will be expanded to cover the entire GT A area.)
Immediate devaluation of taxicab licences
c
Even without free entry, the elimination of jurisdictional boundaries will
result in a substantial depreciation of the $170 million in plate value of
Metropolitan Toronto licence holders. As previously noted, the open
market value of a taxicab plate in Metropolitan Toronto is approximately
$85,000 (20 times the administrative cost for the region to have issued the
original plate). By comparison, the open market value of a taxicab plate in
neighbouring Mississauga is approximately $12,000 and will likely see the
market value of the plate increase to reflect market and supply. The
increase in a Mississauga plate, however, will be limited by the downward
pressure coming from increased competition by taxicab owners in smaller
communities. In its final report, the GTA Task Force entirely ignored the
financial hardship that a recommendation to amalgamate taxicab and
limousine licensing would have on the owners of vehicles.
J,
PUTTING CUSTOMERS FIRST
Taxicab Reform in the Greater Toronto Area (GTA)
PART TWO
Solutions
I. Introduction
The current laws regulating the taxicab industry have overtaken the
delivery of a convenient cost-efficient service to the public. Metropolitan
Toronto's city mayors, elected representatives, and the Metropolitan
Licensing Commission only appear interested in finding solutions to the
region's transportation challenges within the existing regulatory and
bureaucratic framework and, in accordance to the interests of public
funded services, within the monopoly of urban transit and intercity
commuter service providers. Governments and government agencies are
not prepared to improve transportation service to the public at large, or
increase the quality oflife for low-income households, recipients of
government programs, and other dependents on taxicabs if those
improvements will result in the reduction or removal of government
influence in certain areas of the urban transportation industry.
.~
A province-wide, deregulated taxicab industry would transfer the cost
advantage from the producer to the customer where it belongs, by
increasing supply, reducing fares, and improving service. A truly
competitive industry would also create new opportunities, particularly in
niche markets such as low-income users and intercity commuters who
could take advantage of shared-ride' services across previously restricted
jurisdictions.
Deregulation, a U.S. experience
o
c
Taxicab competition creates new inner-city jobs. A study by the U.S.
Department of Transportation has found that taxicab restrictions cost
consumers nearly US$800 million a year. Also, removing those
restrictions would also create 38,000 new jobs in the taxi industry.ill)
Unlike the recent Canadian practice of using publicly funded
infrastructure projects for short-term job creation, taxi jobs would likely
be permanent additions to the labour force, offering the independent
owners or drivers new opportunities in a previously depressed and
underserviced industry.
In U.S. cities that have deregulated the taxicab industry to allow open
entry, the size of the industry has grown between 18 and 33 per cent with
substantial industry turnover among small companies and independent
drivers, slight turnover among medium and large companies and no
detectable turnover inside the largest taxicab firms.ill)
c
The City of Indianapolis deregulated its taxicab industry in May 1994 as
part of the city's comprehensive deregulation effort. "Bad local regulations
hinder job creation, stifle healthy neighbourhood development, and chill
business expansion," said Mayor Stephen Goldsmith after announcing a
Regulatory Study Commission to eliminate unnecessary and bad local
regulation. "In nearly every survey of local businesses, regulation appears
at the top of the list of barriers to growth. "iJ2l
Prior to deregulation, it was illegal for a cab driver to cruise the streets or
for a customer' to hail a cab, resulting in waits of up to 90 minutes for
telephone orders. The Indianapolis Department of Metropolitan
Development benefitted established taxicab owners by allowing only 392
taxi licences in this city, the 12th largest in the U.S.
By eliminating most taxicab regulations (a driver still requires a licence, a
US$100,OOO insurance policy, a photograph, and a US$I02licence fee),
the number of Indianapolis taxi companies has almost doubled from 28 to
52. Fares have dropped nearly 7 per cent and waiting times have fallen
dramatically. All of the new companies are owned either by minorities or
women, and an industry that was legendary for its poor service and large
volume of customer complaints has not had a single customer complaint
regilltered since deregulation.lW
c
Where open entry has not resulted in improved service and lower fares (or
increases no greater than the Consumer Price Index), the culprit is often a
dependence on first in, first out taxi stands and airport queues by new
drivers and owners without radios. As long as a municipality or airport
operator does not seek time-based compensation for taxi stands, and
measures are not introduced to free the customer from the industry
imposed first in, first out rule, those features of the taxicab industry will
preserve inefficiency, poor service, and artificially high prices.
~
II. Benefits of taxicab deregulation
As noted in the previous section, if deregulation had been in place in
Metropolitan Toronto in 1987, the fare, at the time, on a standard trip
would have been $1.62 lower (resulting in a $39.1-million transfer of
wealth from the producer to the customer), and there would have been an
additional 730 taxicabs on the streets.
Telephone orders
The telephone gives a customer the greatest advantage in terms of
convenience and flexibility. Because of price regulation, however, the
telephone user is denied an opportunity to shop the market on the basis of
price. If the Metropolitan Licensing Commission did not control price,
operators would likely stimulate the market and provide the customer with
added information through promotions such as printing tariff schedules
(including discount periods), or by taking out ads in newspapers and on
billboards.
o
Customers could telephone in advance and get the best price on a specific
trip. Dispatchers could relay the price over the radio network and return to
the customer with a confirmation number from the driver who was willing
to accept the business. The convenience that computers and management
systems have brought to the service industry (guaranteed delivery times by
Pizza Pizza and Swiss Chalet or frequent flyer points or customer rewards
by Air Canada and Zellers) are missing in the taxicab industry because the
Metropolitan Licensing Commission has built protective barriers around
the suppliers that exclude benefits to the customers.
There are concerns, for example, based on interviews with the
Metropolitan Licensing Commission that the City of Toronto (which
o
c
would become the geographic core of the proposed amalgamated city) is
evolving into a hail or taxi stand industry because of changing
demographics and customer attitude, and a growing realization among
drivers that "a live customer on the sidewalk is a bird in hand (while a
dispatch order may turn into a wild goose chase). ,,{W The current trend to
a dedicated hail or taxi stand approach to the marketplace would result in
inconvenience and hardship for seniors, and the physically disabled, who
are less capable of going onto the street to commandeer a vehicle. In
contrast, increased competition through open entry would preserve and
enhance the telephone market as a niche service.
Taxi stands
The taxicab industry would become more efficient and offer customers a
higher level of service at a competitive price if cities such as Toronto were
to organize taxi stands on a user-pay basis, either by sellmg existing and
new taxi stands to private operators (the preferred option), or by having
municipal parking authorities install parking meters. User-pay taxi stands
would encourage drivers to attract business while increasing revenue to
the city from a direct sale <if taxi stands or revenue from the meter.
c
Cruising taxicabs
The advantages of a price-deregulated taxicab industry are best illustrated
by the cruising segment of the market. As with long distance telephone
services, a driver's rates should reflect demand. For example, drivers could
charge premium fares during times of shortages such as periods of
inclement weather, peak rush hour, and the late evening, and lower fares at
other times. Cruising in a price-deregulated market requires trust between
the driver and the passenger. Both are obligated to honour the fare already
negotiated (much the same way that the customer is obligated to pay the
amount that appears on the meter at the end of a trip).
Taxi meters
c
Deregulation of the taxicab industry will result in new investment in
additional vehicles to increase supply and to lower the price, and in
improvement to industry staples such as the taxi meter. For example, in a
deregulated industry, tariffs negotiated on the spot between a driver and a
customer could be secured through an upgrade in meter technology. A
driver would either program an agreed upon per kilometre rate into the
meter, or set a fixed rate and issue a receipt that the passenger would pay
in full upon arrival at his destination.
~
III. Conclusion and reeommendations
Abolition of all restrictions on the taxicab industry, except for those that
govern public safety and environmental standards, will result in an
immediate increase in taxicab supply, an overall reduction in taxi fares,
and improved service, while reducing pressure on urban transit systems,
and creating new business and employment opportunities in a low-cost,
easy-entry industry.
With an increased market for taxi services, the use of private automobiles
would decrease, alleviating traffic congestion and air pollution while
contributing to a smoother functioning economy. While almost all citizens
would benefit from these reforms, they would especially benefit those less
well off (low-skilled entrants and consumers who cannot afford an
automobile), students looking for employment, and women who use taxi
services the most.
o
But the road to revitalizing urban and intercity transportation through
taxicab reform is an all-or-nothing proposition. Metropolitan Toronto
cannot afford to do nothing. Open entry will not work without price
deregulation. And price deregulation (and other customer service benefits)
would be ineffective if the existing inadequate supply of taxicabs in
Metropolitan Toronto and the surrounding area was preserved. It is
therefore recommended that the province and local govemments take
immediate steps to develop a safe, competitive, cost-efficient, and
environmentally responsible urban and intercity transportation policy by:
1. Creating an open market for taxieab operators
The government of Ontario should immediately create a province-wide
open market for the taxi industry by ending price controls, restrictions on
taxicab supply and on shared-ride services, and jurisdictional boundaries.
Open jurisdiction would include airports owned either by local airport
authorities such as the Greater Toronto Airport Authority or Transport
Canada.
o
c
2. The return of competitive jitney services
The amalgamated City of Toronto and surrounding GTA communities
should end restrictions on shared rides and jitney services. Owners of
multipassenger vans and minibuses with safety certificates should be able
to provide local and intercity transportation services in competition with
transit companies (TAC) and GO Transit.
3. Taxicab driver re-testing
To ensure the safety of the passenger, and to protect surrounding vehicular
and pedestrian traffic, the Ministry of Transportation should require that a
driver must hold a chauffeur's licence to operate a taxicab. The ministry
should also make regular driver re-testing compulsory.
c
4. Ensuring safety and environmental standards through vehicle
certification
Each taxicab or multipassenger van used for taxi purposes should be
subject to an annual inspection by a certified agent of the Ministry of
Transportation. The cost of vehicle certification would be paid for by the
vehicle owners.
5. Greater efficieney through user-pay taxi stands
Municipalities should set up taxi stands on a user-pay basis either by
selling stands to private operators or setting up meters. Transit companies
and hoteliers would be able to sell or lease space in front of subway
stations, bus stops, and hotels. Airports could charge for space allotted to
the taxi pool.
6. Compensation for plate holders
Municipalities should develop criteria to compensate plate holders.
c
References
~,
1. The Economic Effects of the Direct Regulations of the Taxicab Industry
(Logistics and Transportation Review, Vol. 25, No.2, September 1989), p.
181. ~
2. Studies on Regulation in Canada, Executive Summary (Logistics and
Transportation Review, Vol. 15, No.1), p. 2.
3. Inc., May 1994.
4. The Taxi Industry and Its Regulation in Canada (Economic Council of
Canada, March 1982), p. 85.
5. The Economic Effects of the Direct Regulation of the Taxicab Industry
in Metropolitan Toronto (D. Wayne Taylor, Logistics and Transportation
Review, Vol. 25, September 1989), p. 169.
6. An Economic Analysis of Taxicab Regulation (Federal Trade
Commission Bureau of Economics Staff Report, May 1984), p. 75.
7. The Taxi Industry and Its Regulation in Canada (Economic Council of
Canada, Working Paper No. 30, March 1982), p. 21.
o
8. The Taxi Industry and Its Regulation in Canada (Economic Council of
Canada, Working Paper No. 30, March 1982), p. 22.
9. Call a Taxi: Cab Drivers in Pursuit of Liberty and Profit (Barron's, July
12,1993).
10. Logistics and Transportation Review, (Vol. 25, September 1989), p.
173.
11. The Economic Effects of the Direct Regulation of the Taxicab Industry
(Logistics and Transportation Review, Vol. 25, No.2, September 1989) p.
179.
12. The Taxi Industry and Its Regulation in Canada (Economic Council of
Canada, March 1982), p. 31.
13. Private Innovations in Public Transit (John C. Weicher, American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C., 1988),
p.73.
14. Call a Taxi. Cab Drivers in Pursuit of Liberty and Profit (Barron's,
July 12, 1993).
o
c
IS. Revitalizing Urban Transit (Robert Cervero, American Enterprise
Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C., 1988), p. 75.
16. Okay, You're a Taxi (Metropolitan Toronto Business Journal,
July/August 1989), p. 22.
17. Wall Street Journal, February I, 1993.
18. Impact of Taxicab Deregulation in the USA (R.F. Teal and M.
Berglund), p. 40.
19. Proposal 72 Would Free the Cabs, Help the City (Indianapolis
Business Journal, April 18-24, 1994).
20. Revolution at the Roots: Making Our Government Smaller, Better, and
Closer to Home (William D. Eggers and John O'Leary, Free Press, New
York, New York, 1995).
21. Okay, You're a Taxi (Metropolitan Toronto Business Journal,
July/August 1989), p. 21.
c
Updated: 4/8/97
c
~
o
o
--
\,.,
c
c
I
-------....--.-.----..-------.--..-------- ---_.,-_._-_.__._-~-----_.__..._.....__.,-_._--- .-,.,..- ..----..
TAKEN FOR A $1 BILLION TAXI RIDE
by Terence Corcoran
Columnist
Toronto Globe and Mail
5 April 1997
No city in Canada is exempt from the shambles created by the ancient regulatory regimes
that govem our taxi industries. In the name of levelling the playing field and making taxis
safe and cheap for everyone, our licencing agencies have created a bumpy road patrolled
by overpriced taxis operated by undertrained drivers of unsafe vehicles. Any lessons
learned? Apparently not.
Parts of the national taxi mess explode locally from time to time, sending city officials
scrambling to clean things up. In this routine, everbody works up a pet theory about the
cause of the problem - too many taxis, not enough regulations, incompetent licencing
boards, gret;dy owners, immigrant drivers, whatever - but nobody ever seems to land on
the real solution: deregulation.
Economists have been working over the taxi industry for decades, finding the obvious
economic problem. David Carr, a transport analyst for the Consumer Policy Institute,
cites two studies that point to the high cost and distortions of taxi regulation. An
Economic Council of Canada study from 1982 concluded that the licencing and price
controls imposed by governments push up "the cost of taxi service in Canadian cities by
30 to 50 per cent."
Another study of the economic effects ofThronto taxi regulation concluded that
consumers pay the price for regulation wbile producers are protected. The policies limit
the supply of taxis, inflate prices, lower the quality of service, and cause inefficiencies
and higher profits. Despite powerful economic analysis, the push for more regulation still
dominates debate.
A taxi uproar is under way in Metro Toronto, stirred by the Board of Trade, based on the
fact that an inordinate proportion of the area's taxi fleet is made up of ancient, unsafe and
unclean vehicles. Drivers don't appear to be in much better shape than the cars. All of this
is bad for Toronto's image and tourism. The solutions offered in Toronto, however,
appear to be limited to mandatory hosing down of both cars and drivers, removing old
cars from the road and tightening some of the licencing rules.
None of which win work, because these regulatory solutions merely avoid the core
problem. Like most cities across Canada, Metro Toronto controls the supply of taxis by
limiting the number of medallions. These medallions, or plates, are government-created
pieces of paper that nominally represent the right to operate a taxi. In practice, however,
o
o
o
c
c
c
2
they become like share certificates or bonds, putting a capital value on the shortage of
taxis.
At current market rates, according to my sources, a Toronto taxi plate is worth maybe
$80,000 on the market. The total current market value of Toronto's 3,400 plates,
therefore, is about $270-million. In other cities, apparently, the value of each plate can be
even higher: $110,000 in Vancouver, $95,000 in Ottawa. A national tally of the total
market value of taxi plates could approach $ I-billion.
All taxi passengers are therefore being taken for a $I-billion ride by the taxi licencing
agencies. A significant portion of each fare goes to pay the owner of the taxi plate a
decent return on investment. Indeed, the value of the plates fluctuates with market
conditions and interest rates, much like a bond. When interest rates were high a few years
ago, and business slow, Toronto's plates were much cheaper, apparently as low as
$40,000.
These market values are for an artificial shortage of taxis created by a government that
restricts supply. Private sector executives can go to jail for doing this. Instead of fares
paying for better cars or better wages to drivers, the money is going to owners of taxi
plates.
If a plate owner controls 60 plates, his investment is worth $5-million at current market
prices. Plate .owners do not typically own the cars themselves; the actual taxis are usually
owned by somebody else. At current rates, obviously, the $80,000 plate is worth three,
four or five times the value of the taxi. The cars and plates are then rented aut on a shift
basis to itinerant drivers, who must hustle for long hours to make up the cost of the
regulatory apparatus before they get paid themselves.
The longer these regimes are in place, the deeper the rot and the more difficult
deregulation becomes. Easy though it may be to dismiss the plate owners as greedy
absentee landlords, the system is not their creation. The owners were actually fulfilling a
useful and logical service under the circumstances.
One solution in Toronto, treating the owners fairly, is to buy them out. But at $270-
million current market value, that option is clearly out of the question. A better solution
would be to phase out the transferable plate system. In many U.S. cities, plates cannot be
sold or controlled by anyone other than a driver. When the driver dies or quits, the plate
returns to the city and a new driver gets the licence. But that's a makeshift plan that
doesn't solve the problem.
The best solution of all is deregulation of supply and fares. As with restaurants,
governments could licence for safety and driver knowledge, leaving the number of taxis
and the prices to market forces. The result, would be lower fares and better service.
o
o
o
o
j
........-
o
o
I
C Taxicab Regulation in Ohio's Largest
Cities
A Policy Report
prepared by
The Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions
131 N. Ludlow Street, Suite 317
Dayton, OH, USA 45402
(937) 224-8352
(937) 224-8457 (fax)
email: buckeyeins@ao1.com
--~-,--~-----'--"_._-~-'-- ..,..--..-.--..-.----------
Taxicab Regulation in Ohio's Largest
Cities
c
c
c
c
c
2
Executive Summary
Ohio's largest cities impose numerous regulatory burdens on the start up and operation of taxicab busine:
regulations often prohibit small, independent operators from starting a taxi business. This limits econorn
opportunities in Ohio's major cities. Additionally, the regulations severely limit service and price compel
among taxi companies.
Meanwhile, other U.S. cities have found success in deregulating their taxi markets, Within the first six IT
deregulation, Indianapolis had 32 new companies start up. In Denver, four entrepreneurs sued the State c
Colorado in order to start their own company. "Freedom Cabs" became the first cab company in 48 Yelm
up in Denver and now employs 100 drivers.
Taxi Regulations
. Minimum Number of Cabs: Cleveland will not issue a taxi license to any company with fewer th;
cabs, effectively prohibiting independent operators from starting. Cleveland has issued fewer taxi
than either Cincinnati or Columbus.
. Mandated 24 Hour Service: Akron, Canton, and Dayton require full-time taxi service, 24-hour, 7
week, effectively prohibiting part-time cab services.
. Separate Dispatching Office Required: Cleveland and Dayton require cab companies to have a se
dispatching office. This drives up costs and ignores the possibility of independent operators usin~
phones.
. Proof of Public Need: Toledo and Cincinnati require cab companies to prove their business i!
public need. This provides the opportunity to existing cab companies to use their political power
new competition. Cincinnati, Columbus, and Toledo also require a public hearing on new license
burdening new companies.
. Price Competition Restricted: Toledo and Youngstown effectively set rates for all cab companies
eliminating price competition. Other cities restrict price competition by prohibiting flat rates and
prices to be submitted to city officials before going into effect.
. Cab Stands Regulated: Canton, Cincinnati, Cleveland, Dayton, and Youngstown require cabs to ,
officially designated cab stands. This limits cab owners' ability to negotiate individually with rest
bars, and theaters, and respond more quickly to customer traffic patterns.
. Cap on New Taxis: Columbus imposed a moratorium on new cab compantes in May 1990. Cleve
Toledo put caps on the number of taxis legally allowed to operate (although the cap has not been
Case Study: Dayton
A review of taxi regulations in Dayton found that the regulations increase the cost of starting a cab comp
least $67,000. Dayton requires 24-hour, seven day a week service from all cab companies. It also require
hour, seven day a week dispatching office. This effecttvely prohibits an independent owner-operator fror
a cab business. This may explain why there are 100 cabs licensed in Dayton, but only four taxi companie
operation.
_._._.-._-_.._--,._-,._._-_._-_..~_._----~--~-_.._~------_.._-~-_._-----~--------
c
c
c
3
--,--.'--_._,-_._-------~, -_.._,._~~-----_.--~-_._,-_._.'..,...- .._,-----_..._._..._._~-----
::11..1 The Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions is a public policy research and
~UCKe e education Institute, or think tank. As an independent, nonprofit, nonpartisan
. organization, its purpose is to provide Ohio's leaders and citizens with new ways of
. thinking about problems facing our state and local communtties. By widely
:OLUTIO. LlCY distributing and publicizing its ideas and research, the Institute encourages more
policymakers and opinion leaders to embrace new approaches to solving problems. The Institute's
work focuses 0 n five primary areas: education, taxes and spending, privatization, regulatory issues and
economic development, and health care. To maintain the highest level of integrity, the Institute
accepts no requests to conduct contract research or programs for businesses. All research projects and
programs are determined by the staff and Board of Research Advisors. The Institute receives no
govemment funding for its activities. All funding comes from the generous contributions of many
individuals and foundations, along with limited general support from businesses.
The Buckeye Institute gratefully acknowledges the following people for their
contributions to this report.
Project Supervisor: Samuel Staley, Vice Presidentfor Research,
The Buckeye Institute, and Adjunct Professor of Economics,
Wright State University
Research Coordinator: Amy Kirlin
Research Assistants: Derrick Johnson, Melissa Seckora, Doug Hyne, and Brandon
Lynaugh
Editorial Assistance: Andrew Little
Board of Research Advisors:
Dr. Douglas K. Adie, Department of Economics, Ohio University
Dr. Mark Altieri, Department of Accounting, Kent State University
Dr. Robert Baird, Department of Economics, Case Western Reserve University
Mr. Tom Bell, School of Law, University of Dayton,
Dr. William Bogart, Department of Economics, Case Western Reserve University
Dr. Michael Bond, Department of Finance, Cleveland State University
Mr. Jim Coons, Huntington National Bank, Columbus, OH
Dr. Gregory Delemeester, Department of Economics, Marietta College
Dr. James Child, Department of Philosophy, Bowling green State University
Dr. Gina Dow, Department of Psychology, Denison University
Dr. Michael Ellis, Department of Economics, Kent State University
Dr. David Forte, Marshall School of Law, Cleveland State University
Dr. Ralph Frasca, Department of Economics, University of Dayton
Dr. Janice Gabbert, Department of Classics, Wright State University
Dr. Lowell Gallaway, Department of Economics, Ohio University
Dr. James Gaston, Department of History, Franciscan University ofSteubenville
Dr. Melvin Greenball, Department of Accounting, The Ohio State University
Dr. William Irvine, Department of Philosophy, Wright State University
Dr. John Kelley, Department of History, Shawnee State University
Dr. Robert A. Kohl, Department of Economics, Defiance College
c
c
c
Dr. Robert Lawson, Department of Economics, Capital University
Dr. Brad Martin, Department of Criminal Justice, University of Findlay
Dr. David Mayer, Law and Graduate Center, Capital University
Dr. Abraham Miller, Department of Political Science, University of Cincinnati
Dr. Dennis Miller, Department of Economics, Baldwin Wallace College
Dr. Henry Moon, Department of Geography and Planning, University of Toledo
Dr. Andrew Morriss, School of Law, Case Western Reserve University
Mr. Dorien Nunez, Management Advantage Corp., Cincinnati, Ohio
Ms. Deborah Owens, College of Business Administration, University of Akron
Dr. William Peirce, Department of Economics, Case Western Reserve University
Dr. Robert Premus, Department of Economics, Wright State University
Dr. Henry Rennie, Department of Economics, Heidelberg College
Dr. John Rapp, Department of Economics, University of Dayton
Mr. Bradley Smith, Law & Graduate Center, Capital University
Mr. Michael Solimine, College of Law, University of Cincinnati
Dr. John Soper, Department of Economics, John Carroll University
Dr. Anthony Stocks, Department of Economics, Youngstown State University
Mr. David Swindell, Department of Urban Affairs, Wright State University
Dr. Bradley Thompson, Department of Political Science, Ashland University
Dr. Richard Vedder, Department of Economics, Ohio University
Dr. David Zimov, Department of Political Science, Northern Kentucky University
Mr. Joseph Zoric, Department of Business Administration, Franciscan University of
Steubenville
For more information on the Buckeye Institute, please contact:
The Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions
131 N. Ludlow Street, Suite317
Dayton, OH 45402
(937) 224-8352 . Fax: (937) 224-8457
BUCKEYElNS@AOL.COM
4
Table of Contents
I. Introduction
II. Taxicab Rel!Ulation: An Overview
III. The Taxicab Market in Ohio Cities
IV. Taxicab Rel!:ulations in Ohio
V. Rel!:ulatorv Burden of Re2ulation:The Case of Davton
VI. Increasin2 Economic Opportunity Throu2h Taxicab Re2ulatorv Reform
Appendix: Benefits of Taxicab Re2ulation
End Notes
I. Introduction
c
c
c
5
A taxicab business could be one of the easiest businesses to start up, The only
requirements would be a clean, safe automobile; a driver in good physical condition
without a recent criminal record; a driver's license; a simple, low-cost business permit;
and the proper insurance.
In practice, this is a business where local regulatory barriers impose powerful obstacles to
start-up companies, either by establishing unnecessary financial burdens and bureaucratic
rules, or outright restrictions on new businesses. I When regulations become too onerous,
would-be entrepreneurs, like other businesses, sometimes go underground and provide
their services iIlegally.2 Most importantly, many will never start at all. .
But everyone loses out in the long run when businesses do not get started or remain
underground. The health and vibrancy of cities depends on entrepreneurs creating new
businesses and growing successful enterprises. When regulations stifle business start-ups,
city residents are dependent on existing jobs in the area. Often these jobs are in
established businesses which are not growing rapidly. Thus, without entrepreneurial
outlets, job opportunities in cities are limited.
When businesses remain underground, this also limits economic growth in a city. The
mere fact they are illegal or unregistered means growth jeopardizes their existence. As
soon as a company grows, it becomes more visible. High visibility means underground
businesses run higher risks of being closed down by local authorities.3 Thus, when city
regulations keep businesses underground, it creates a perverse incentive for them to limit
their growth and contribute less to a city's economy.
So, creating opportunities for entrepreneurs to easily start new businesses and bringing
underground businesses above ground should be objectives of any city's economic
development strategy. This means keeping regulatory costs and burdens to a minimum.
II. Taxicabs Regulation: An Overview
Cities in the U.S. have regulated taxicabs for at least 75 years (see box below), In most
cases, regulations are developed on the local level, usually by a city. Taxicab regulations
are some of the most common in city ordinances, and may also be some of the most
restrictive.
This is ironic because a taxicab service may be one of the easiest business to start up. Car
ownership is widespread, even in poor and inner city areas. Start-up entrepreneurs face
some financial barriers -- a good, clean, used car may cost up to $4,000 or more and
insurance runs about $3,000 per car.4 But, local ordinances and regulations can
significantly increase the difficulty of starting up a new taxicab business.
6
c
Origins of Taxicab Regulations
Taxicab regulations can be traced to England, when Charles I restricted the number of horse-drawn carriages for
hire in London in 1635. The first comprehensive taxicab regulation was the London Hackney Carriage Act of
1831,
The first significant regulations imposed on the American taxicab industry emerged during the 1920s and 1930s.
Philadelphia placed its first restrictions on taxicabs in 1920. Milwaukee began regulating taxicabs in 1924,
followed by Los Angeles (1925), San Diego (1928), and Phoenix (1928).
Taxicab regulation became significantly more restrictive when New York City passed the Haas Act in 1937. This
Act restricted the number oflicenses, or medallions, to 13,566. Attrition reduced the number to less than 11,800
after World War II. This cap on taxis significantly restricted the supply of new taxis well below demand. As many
as 30,000 illegal taxis exist in New York, and the purchase price of a license, or medallion, runs $175,000 or
higher.
Taxicab deregulation began to pick up steam when Indianapolis, Denver and Cincinnati deregulated their markets
in 1994 and 1995.
Source: Historical background on taxicab regulation provided by the Washington, D.C.-based Institute for Justice. See "Challenging
Denver's Taxicab Monopoly," Litigation Backgrounder, and Is New York City Killing Entrepreneurship?, pp. 5-8.
c
Types of Taxi Regulations
Taxicab regulations generally take on 4 different'
types. While cities will impose many other types
of regulations - advertising restrictions,
language requirements, uniforms, etc. - the
following general categories are the most
common.
Types of Taxicab Regulations
. Caps on the number of taxis or
firms
. Health and safety
. Price regulation
. Types and levels of services
Caps on Taxis
First, cities limit entrepreneurial access to taxicab markets. Many ordinances limit the
number of companies that can legally provide taxi services at any given time. In some
cases, the city places a cap on the number of companies. In a survey of regulations in 25
cities, Price Waterhouse found that 10 cities placed limits on the number of taxis that
could operate within their cities.5
Cities can also restrict entry by simply not approving additional licenses or placing a
moratorium on issuing new licenses. This is the current case in Columbus.
c
Other cities may limit entry by creating onerous application processes. This is often done
by requiring an applicant to "prove" his or her company will serve a public purpose, or
that existing service is inadequate.
7
C Health and Safety
A second type of taxi regulation revolves around health and safety. A taxicab driver is
usually required to have adequate insurance and an acceptable driving record. Most
ordinances also deny driver's licenses to people convicted of serious offenses, such as
fraud, assault, burglary, or robbery. Rules about vehicle inspections also fall under safety
regulation.
Price Regulation
A third type of regulation is price regulation. Some cities legislate the amount a taxi can
charge. Before its market was deregulated, for example, Indianapolis's ordinance set taxi
prices at 95 cents for the first 1/5 mile and 30 cents for each additional 1/5 of a mile. In
other cases, local regulations simply place a maximum on the amount that could be
charged, leaving other rates to market activity.
Service Level Regulation
The fourth type of regulation sets standards for the quality of service. These regulations
require proper conduct, regulate vehicle appearance and cleanliness, and specify the types
of services provided by taxicab drivers and companies.
c
These regulations can create significant barriers to start-up taxi companies in Ohio cities.
The result, in most cases, is fewer companies, less competition 'and fewer entrepreneurial
opportunities. With less competition, service levels often decline,6 forcing customers to
bear the burden of longer wait times for taxis or loss of service as existing companies fail
to serve some areas of a city. By setting a cap on the number of new taxis, starting a new
cab company is difficult - if not impossibl e - regardless of individual effort, how well
one knows the city, or how prompt service will be. Those who want to drive a cab must
work for someone else, often paying thousands of dollars to a cab company to lease its
cars.7
The Push to Deregulate Taxis
Recognition of the beneficial impacts of a competitive taxicab market and increased
economic opportunities led some cities to deregulate local markets in the 1990s.
Indianapolis, Cincinnati, and Denver have made significant strides toward opening up the
industry to entrepreneurs and limiting government intervention.
c
In Denver, for example, no new cab companies entered the market between 1947 and
1995.8 A cartel of 3 cab companies operated in a tightly regulated market. Local
regulations required would-be entrepreneurs to prove inadequate service by the existing
cab companies.9 Thus, would-be entrepreneurs were forced to prove to a government
agency that the demand existed for their service before they could begin. More
importantly, start-up companies also had to show that the existing companies would be
unable to provide adequate service.1o
c
c
c
8
These rules effectively deprived Denver residents of an ability to pursue a trade or
business and "earn an honest living," II according to the Institute for Justice, a
Washington, D.C.-based public interest law firm. The Institute sued the State of Colorado
on behalf of four entrepreneurs turned down by the Colorado Public Utilities
Commission. The entrepreneurs won. On August I, 1995, Freedom Cabs became the first
new cab company in 48 years to open up in Denver as a result of the law suit and related
legislative activities.12 Freedom Cabs now employs 100 drivers that serve many of the
markets underserved by the cartel. 13
Cincinnati also opened up its market to entrepreneurs by eliminating an effective cap on
new companies, I and by clarifying the requirements for obtaining a license and
"providing" public need. IS While the cap was in place, more than 100 applications for
new licenses were pending before the city. 16 More than 237 new cabs started up in
Cincinnati in the wake of local deregulatory efforts.l?
Indianapolis's deregulation plan may be the most comprehensive and successful to date
(see Indianapolis). Its success in creating new opportunities for minority entrepreneurs,
increasing the number of cab companies, and using competition to reduce average rates is
quickly becoming a model for other cities. As of July, 1996, 158 new taxicabs have
entered the market. 18
Criticisms of Deregulation
,
Some argue that deregulation will actually result in a deterioration of quality and service.
Gene Stalians, former President of the International Taxicab Association, believes that
"open entry is not the answer to a community's legitimate desire to improve its taxicab
service. ,,19 In 1993, Price Waterhouse, in a study commissioned by the International
Taxicab Foundation, concluded "the effects of taxicab deregulation have ranged from
benign to adverse, depending on local conditions and markets." 20
Objections to deregulation range from broad concerns over the quality of service to fears
that wages will fall for current drivers (see Appendix). In a study of San Diego taxicab
deregula- tion, for example, driver eamings fell by 30% after deregulation.21 Drivers in
Cincinnati also complained about the r,::ssibility that new companies would reduce the
profitability of exist- ing companies.2 Of course, average driver incomes may fall if
more com- petitors are allowed in the market place. - Taxicab companies often operate in
'a regulated environment, protecting them from market competition.
Instead of deregulation, Stalians proposes that entry into a taxicab market be controlled
according to a mathematical formula that determines the "optimal" number of cabs in a
particular city. Stalians believes rates should also be regulated, although not as strictly as
d . d' 23
un er many CIty or mances.
Responses to Criticisms
9
c
Unfortunately, little work has been done to evaluate changes in quality before and after
deregulation (see Annendix). Most evidence relies on case studies and anecdotal
evidence.
Service Quality
Deregulation, however, can lead to service quality increases. "The primary benefits of
deregulation have been to increase service availability, to reduce telephone order
response times by a modest amount, and to give consumers a greater choice among
companies, some of which have different rates," observes Roger Teal after his study of
the impacts of San Diego's deregulation efforts.24
More importantly, deregulated cities typically have significant increases in the number of
independent cab companies and taxicabs. Deregulated cities in the Price Waterhouse
study, for example experienced a 23% tncrease in the number of taxis from 1985 to
1992.25 These increases were much larger than in cities that either remained regulated or
that re-regulated.26 Thus, cities interested in promoting economic opportunities for
residents can consider taxicab deregulation as tool for promoting this form of entre-
preneurship.
Demand for Taxis
o
The dramatic increase in the number of cabs operating in deregulated cities also
addresses another concern of regulators. Some argue that the demand does not exist for
higher levels of taxicab service. In fact, this is implied by regulations that require
potential applicants to "prove" a need exists for their services. Those, such as Stalians,
that argue for a formula-based approach to determining the number of cabs also suggest
that existing cab service is sufficient.
Yet, if this were true, cities that deregulate would not experience a significant increase in
the number of cabs operating in their cities. The demand would be insufficient to sustain
a larger number of cabs and cab companies. They would quickly go out of business. The
fact that almost all cities that deregulate their local taxicab market experience an increase
in the number of taxis in operation suggests that substantial unmet demand exists for
these services. More importantly, this unmet demand can expand economic opportunities
for central city residents.
Increased competition from new taxicab drivers and companies obviously prompts
renewed calls from existing drivers and companies to restrict entry. Deregulation may
result in lower wages and eamings for existing drivers and companies protected by the
closed entry system. As more firms enter the market, they will engage in price
competition. This means lower average fares and/or an increase in quality, both of which
occurred in San Diego.
r Driver Income
'-'
c
c
c
10
In fact, one of the primary arguments for deregulation is that existing companies keef
fares and wages higher by taking advantage of their monopoly over the taxi market.2 An
analysis of taxicab regulation in Toronto found that prices were 25% higher than if the
market were left unprotected by local regulations.28
Moreover, wages may fall as new jobs are created and entrepreneurial opportunities are
expanded in the taxicab market. Even though wages for existing drivers might fall, the
benefits of putting more people to work as taxicab entrepreneurs, increasing the
availability of taxicabs, and increasing the variety of taxicab services may more than
outweigh the income losses experienced by existing companies (see box on
Indianaoolis).29
More importantly, the mere fact new taxicab operators enter the market, providing new
levels of service, suggests that economic opportunities are better driving taxis than other
jobs. Many cab operators may be willing to accept lower wages for the opportunity to be
their own boss and give themselves a shot at even greater wealth as their business
expands. Otherwise, they would invest their time, money, and experience pursuing other
opportunities.
c
c
c
11
Indianapolis Taxicab Deregulation Creates Jobs
Indianapolis's deregulation of its taxicab market was subjected to fierce debate. Opponents consisted ma:
established taxicab companies. Richard Hunt, the owner of Yellow Cab, Inc., argued that deregulation w
, price wars, forcing some taxicab companies out of business. "You've got to have a level playin~ field," h
"[Deregulation] drives it down to where nobody makes any money and everybody goes broke."
Supporters argued that deregulation would increase service and provide economic opportunities. James (
an Indianapolis cab driver who wanted to start his own company, appealed to local government officials
his dreams of owning and operating his own cab company a reality. "All I'm asking from the City-Count:
Council," he wrote in a letter-to-the editor of the Indianapolis News, "is the right to succeed or fail based
my decisions, my service, my prices, and my hard work. ,,2 .
After extensive debate, the city's economic development committee presented Proposal 76, a comprehen
taxicab deregulation ordinance. The local city-county council approved the deregulation proposal in Ma)
The proposal made three major changes to the local taxicab ordinance. It
. eliminated the cap of393 taxicab licenses imposed by the controller,3
. replaced a set rate with a maximum rate, although all rates must be posted outside the taxi and wi
local govemment,4
. dropped a 24-hour dispatch service requirement, allowing companies to operate part-time.s
Within the first six months of deregulation, the city reports 32 companies started Up.6 Three quarters oft
companies were owned by minorities or women. Pick up rates were 12% lower for new companies com~
existing companies.' Average mileage rates were 3% lower, and the average rate for the first mile was 7~
As of July, 1996, 158 new taxis have entered the market.9
I. Greta Shankle, "Draft of Taxi Ordinance would Deregulate Industry," Indianapolis Business Journal, January 10-16, 1994.
2. James Chatman, "Cabbie Appeals to City," /ndianapolis News, April 16, 1996.
3. This was eliminated because the new chapter (Chapter 996) regulating taxi services repealed the earlier regulations. The ne
regulations do not permit a cap on the number of taxicabs.
4. Revised Code of the Consolidated City and County, Chapter 996, Section 996.81
5. See note 3.
6. Ordinance 76 Update, Regulated Competition in the Indianapolis Ground Transportation Marketplace, Economic Develop.
Committee, January 19, 1995.
7. Ibid.
8./bid.
9. Data compiled and provided by Institute for Justice, Washington, D.C., July, 1996.
c
c
c
12
III. The Taxicab Market in Ohio Cities
A more complete understanding of the complexity oflocal regulations and their impact
on economic opportunities is important before developing recommendations for local
policy makers. The Buckeye Institute collected taxicab ordinances from Ohio's largest
cities and analyzed them to determine the extent local taxicab markets were regulated.30
The Institute also used a case study of Dayton to illustrate the extent local regulations can
impose sub-stantial financial
burdens on start-up businesses.
The cities included in the analysis
are the eight lar~est central cities in
Ohio (Table 1). 1 Their populations'
range from 84,788 (Canton) to City
642,987 (Columbus). Similarly, the
number of taxicabs operating in
each city ranges from 40 in
Youngstown to 587 in Cincinnati.
The number of cab companies
varies even more. Only one
company services Canton, while
more than 114 service customers in
Columbus.
Taxicab Availability
Akron
Canton
Cincinnati
Cleveland
Columbus
Dayton
Toledo
Youngstown
Table 1
Taxicabs in Ohio's Largest Cities
Population
(1992 )
Companies
Licenses
(Taxis)
223,621
84,788
364,278
502,539
642,987
183,789
329,325
94,387
85
72
587
293
433
100
130
40
3
1
45
3
114
4
9
3
Source: Population data from U.S. Bureau oflbe Census, taxi
data from survey of individual cities.
One way to gauge taxicab service and availability is to look at the number of taxicabs per
1,000 population (Figure 1). Cincinnati has the largest number: 1.61 cabs for every 1,000
persons. Its closest competitor is Canton, which has fewer than one cab per 1,000 persons
living in the city. The most "underserved" city based on this criteria is Akron, with a cab
per 1 ,000 ratio of only 0.38.
Figure 1
Taxis Per 1,000 Residents
Taxis licenced per 1 ,000 population
13
c
t' "'~I~----~
.t-T;,rl
r:"1 I
!::i i
I.,.~.o---
1.5 .ld
:/1:
1:1
1 ti;
r-.
I
I
I
!.
T---'-""'~--'.-
1.61
~J.,
i
I
-- .~
(,:....
I
I'
!
.i
I 0.67
('!
I',:.U,~, : (,11;'1.1(. 'f =.'Jt1lj;.1,)wn D:n'k., C!r-'c'~!Plld (.;") llr-,bu::; COIlL'11 '~;In;,,;!nnf!"
Source: City taxicab licensing agencies and departments
C Taxicab Company Size
The average nwnber of taxis per company may be an indicator of the degree each city's
market is dominated by large or small fIrms. Cities with fewer taxicab companies will
have higher average fleet sizes, This suggests that the nwnber of independent operators
would be smaller in cities with larger average fleets. '
Many cities are dominated by established companies (e.g., Yellow Cab, Checker Cab,
etc.) with large fleets. In some cases, these fleets nwnber in the dozens or even hundreds
of cabs.
Colwnbus is on one extreme with the lowest nwnber of taxis per company on average
(3.8 per company). Cleveland is on the other extreme. Three taxicab companies (see
Cleveland) control the entire market in that city. The average size of a taxicab company
in terms of available cabs in Cleveland is 97.7.
Figure 2
Taxis Per Company
Average Nwnber of Taxis Per Company
c
14
c
. "
...:.L
f"
l-
! ,
::!~,~-,,~_._~--~---~-_..}----,---+--.._-- ----t,..
.'. i
S7~7
4
, p;,,-,~'
" "
,-,
-1 r I
. -.-.---.-r--..
.r,~.:'_~';I.' I
;",'<"
I
l . ~,; '- if; j ,
l;;~::t '::- , :--~-+-:~~~'+--~.,-..,- .~ . ...j ------.-~-"~~~.-
L::] , i. ':'
r,-;-,'): ._ ~_._~._.~ _~_:,,,~~,......._._,)._~,...___~__+_-:-----1_~________.
, I ,[
t 11 ! . ;";.0
.~ ., I _ ,'.
f: ",~~-"f"'~~;{/-,+-~:~.~~~~ 'i4/.~,-.J/~<~~j/
"'~," f'_~ ".1-1 l.-.f ,~--- 1 .','
-f---:.: _ .j:~ "',v :.'.:;<. ~ ,I: . i
.--------c' '~'1 . ~"'~ ' I
~, . r~~i~i:~ .:. ;~tl.~~~~~ .~"~ b
'-;-Rn~~:~:~~k~~~lll;t:'~W~~incL'~_~~,,,, ,,,,,~Lt.:;;:.'.;
..~----.,.--.--..-----.._._-----~-_._.__.~~--'
. ,
,
- . .."'.... -..~
t ~.-~
i
;
,.
i
r'
,
i--'
i
I
,~(-:;
,-,.,"
:,<,"
Source: City taxicab licensing agencies and departments
IV. Taxicab Regulations in Ohio
C Taxicab regulations in Ohio's largest cities can be grouped into three general categories:32
. Licenses and fees or charges levied on businesses unrelated to their level of
service. These licenses are necessary to operate legally within the city.
. Non1Jnancial mandates such as restrictions, limitations, and regulations on how
and when a business may operate or who qualifies to operate the business.
. Rate regulations that determine the extent of price competition allowed within the
city. Some cities set rates in their taxicab ordinances.
Others adopt maximum rates. Still others allow market-determined rates.
Licenses and Fees
Most cities charge fees for new taxicab companies and drivers. The fees range widely
among Ohio cities.
Fees for Drivers
For drivers, Dayton is the most expensive city to operate a taxicab in, charging $33 per
driver each year (Figure 3). The least expensive is Cleveland, which charges only $3 per
driver. In most Ohio cities, the fees are relatively modest, comparable to the cost of
C obtaining a driver's license.
c
c
c
15
Figure 3
Licence and Registration Fees for Drivers
D
5'~5 /f~----r---' '"'...---.---- . ---.--...--.----. -.---.--r------~----.---.-~-~-~T
T 1- ! I.
3Q 11 1 [ 1 I S25
25 J"C- i -! l i----
1..-. L-+
20 11 II I .
i ': I' SHi
1 S i~~--t---.-..-~~.-.-.. . .{1'$10 i .'
t..~.... ."..,....."-..~...
..t ,r-\ 1 _' '0: .5w - ~< ./;.
I U ) . -----::'I'
I. _$ . : / /,.
54" './----..~A
,-- .. fl.
~ "",
,
Ar."a'1 "~lU'!.-':o.I)''''f\ CUiLIn:'US Sir'C'''''ii.:I:anrO!l
~~V!17'
('j.::o",.<cil"'p(: '.'I-i~ Il
Source: Individual city ordinances and interviews
Fees for Companies
Cities, however, also charge fees to license and register taxicabs (vehicles) and
companieq. These fees are much larger. The cheapest place to begin a taxicab company is
Youngstown which charges only $25 (Figure 4). The most expensive cities are Dayton
and Akron, which each charge $250 per company. Dayton also charges $250 for each
additional vehicle while Akron adds a surcharge of only $10 per vehicle operated by the
company (Figure 5). Thus, for the sole proprietor of a company with one driver/owner,
the cost oflicensing and registering his company and car ranges from $25 in Youngstown
to $260 in Akron.
Some cities may not allow single operators to start new companies, even if they can
afford the licensing fees. This would occur if the city has a cap or has implemented a
moratorium on new taxis.
Figure 4
Licence and Registration for I-Car Cab Companies
c
c
c
..' 300-
25D
200
.'i :~n
16
, ,....,..,
: ~ i...
I
I
I
,
i
I
!
. I
----------_._--~_._-------------
. I.
I T $161
. I I
---.------~---,- ~-'--f'
, I
I
i'--- 1
I !. ..... i ...$5;; ! $60
I' ",,<; :..~.!/-
. ~-~'''.''~7 ~,:,,-.--'
__~ !. 11 ,.- 1 .,
,
~C~::)'
(
,.
.
, $2.5C:
$25V ! ..~._,
.'
. j- .._- - .._~. .------..
. .........----.,..._..~ ~"
J:
i
i .~
I.
"1
J
;::;.
.........
l_
!
r-----
i .
i-
i
I
,
___L~
-'.".;:'-:"1-
f: ~J
Source: Individual city ordinances and interviews
f 3CU
Figure 5
Cost of Licensing One Additional Car
2SG
/'1
i.,
f
j-
,
I
i__
I
!
,
,
,
......~~.... .._-'~.
'1
S250
_.~_I
r,'-"-'l
~;'-,
I
i
i
--r:.~..r"-.. .....-:..
2DC
i
i
,
!
\
,
..~.
"
I
GO
$75
S7S
!'-5-'3
Sfi-J
..----.-------.......-,.--.')...---.
: i ~>2:., '?
50 ; ,.....n I
"':t:J l~'~
.-,..'.-' .- I
~: 1/~~~2 "
'..,-j'.'!
.... ,,;,_~... ;.1' ,'"_j T:.,
...:,"
!, >;.-.~
;.1i,; ...,
,-' lI'l:-
Source: Individual city ordinances and interviews
17
C Non-financial Mandates
Licenses and fees are only one element of the regulatory system overseeing taxicab
drivers and companies in Ohio cities. City councils have erected numerous other barriers,
from requirements specifYing the hours the business can operate to caps on the number of
taxicabs operating in the city. A survey of Ohio's big city taxicab ordinances found
fifteen regulations that impact taxicab companies and drivers (Table 2).
Regulations of Taxis
All cities placed limits and restrictions on the taxis that operate within their city limit,-.
Cleveland, Columbus, and Toledo put caps on the numbev of taxis legally allowed to
operate in their cities. Cleveland has a cap of700 cabs.33 (see box on page 16). Toledo
has a cap of 300 cabs.34 (The number of taxicabs operating in each city, however, is
lower than the legal cap.) Colwubus imposed a moratorium on new cab companies in
May 1990, creating an effective cap of 433 taxis
(see box on Columbus).35
Examples of Regulatory Mandates
c
Caps and moratoria on new taxicabs are potentially.
insurmountable barriers. New taxicab drivers and
companies are allowed to enter the market only if
other companies fail or existing drivers stop
driving.36
.
24-hour service availability
Separate dispatching office
Caps and moratoria on
taxicabs
Physician's certificate
required
Prove public need
.
.
.
Four cities - Canton, Cincinnati, Columbus, and
Toledo - required city approval of color schemes
and insignia.37 Cleveland's ordinance imposes a
minimum size on cab companies (25 cabsi8 and maximum age for nev cars (3 years old
or newer).39
.
Regulations of Drivers
Most cities also regulate drivers. Four cities - Cleveland, Columbus, Dayton, and Toledo
- require a physician's certificate to operate a taxi. While this regulation seems
reasonable, it further increases the costs of obtaining a license. Even healthy drivers with
no history of serious illness have to palc for a physical exam and the doctor's office visit.
Canton imposes a minimum age of 21 0 and a maximum vork day ( 12 hours) for
drivers.41
c
c
18
Table 2
Non-Financial Mandates on Taxicab Companies
^,
. .
j ,
... V I
!
, ,
"
'"
,
"'r'-
.:.:r "," :i:.J7-::': e- t-':i~~':
.....
.'\: '"A-ii.1"':'; ',~'~'. .~,,:,::n;::,3 7;;' r..:;:'r_'
?"
,
,
,
':,:;
> '.:-~' .."
-'.;'};':i"'';.,:;.
",,':'
. .. . ;~ :
.,.-",.. t :,;l~rr:L ;~:,;
'"
'\f
,.
r,:.:."., n:;--:J.lJ":;\",,,"1
't'
'Ii'
'F(
,.
f
I
'j
.
i.
i
i.
,
,
I
\
,- ---
.-.-
'':.a~:;~;,,;
:"~;:"'"'(\Y ~ ~- "'" ,
,V,:":-
\1-~: :-'!:>1.:, ~r ftn,"j1Y:::i~i'r~f:W"tf
(! ~.:~.
j.~ .
C..."", .,.......~;r."~"^
- ~;; .:" ~..."_;..d...,..11ol j::f '-'l!i _.''''
. : -:;',':- ,: ~',. ....'::Xr~;;;;\:
,
I
. -"~
'j
,,-t.,::,;""
"
[
I
F ,.
,.
.j
"'1
...
'f'
~
1
I
"f'
'C"I
"",[
--~ '.
.'V' "'j'
'j
..HJ
... H ,j
I
'r;'"
"'"
,.,
.-.,
i
II"',':'!
;'-h"hrl'-.~i t~'..,)'o:i",.~: I CGI:Jn;::jJ: i
I ..,..," "'''I' +
!
!
D.~'--::(''''' ! -'-)(1:
H,
I
!
,::.~ '::.'
'_..",~,'-;',:;
. ;.".~,
: ?f' S1.", 'Y!:': r"'';;U~~):~1', ,:
i
.\
'\J~~ :',~' lr. mi-"';::! R r:.....~T/ --1
T_Y: 11
i
Iv
,
I
,
..,. I
,.
"'.
...
.'
.\
1
! ..,
....,.,.
i
I
I
I T
t ",
J..
'Itl"'-
~
~
j
- !
,
1
_'J
I
I
_1
Regulations of Company Operations
Local ordinances regulate aspects of the company's day-to-day operations as well,
influencing the technology used to run the business as well as facilities and earnings.
Akron, Canton, Cincinnati, and Toledo require companies to file annual financial reports.
r
'-
c
c
c
19
Other restrictions also make part-time and owner-operator taxicab companies almost
impossible to start-up. Two - Cleveland and Dayton - require cab companies to have a
separate dispatching office to handle dispatching. This requires companies to hire
dispatchers and rent office space, increasing overhead and start-up costs. Of course, to
cover the overhead, most companies need to have more drivers and cars under contract.
As the next section of this report details, this requirement can impose a substantial
financial burden on a start-up company.
The advent of paging devices, cellular phones, and voice messaging systems means that
taxicabs could operate completely free from within a cab. City regulations often do not
reflect these technological
breakthroughs,
The use of modem low-
cost technology is even
further restricted in cities
such as Akron, Canton and
Cleveland. These cities
mandate the technology
used to handle dispatching:
Two-wiry radios.
Cleveland Shuts Out
Independent Owner-Operators
_ Cleveland's taxicab ordinance has a unique entry restriction
compared to other cities in Ohio: It legislates a minimum
company size.
Sections 443.021 and 443.022 of Cleveland's taxicab
, ordinance prohibit the Commissioner of Assessments and
Licenses from issuing a license to any company with fewer
than 25 cars. The ordinance further prohibits the
Cincinnati and Toledo limit' commissioner from issuing a license to an independent
advertising: Their operator unless he or she is a member, and will operate as
ordinances prohibit cab , part of, an association approved by the Commissioner. An
compantes from generating , association is defined as a society organized for the purpose
additional revenues by of benefiting a group of hot less than 25 owners of "public
selling advertising space on hacks" (or taxis). No associations currently operate in
or in taxicabs. Cleveland. City taxi services are provided by only 3 large
taxicab companies - Cleveland Yellow Cab, Zone Cab, and
Americab.
Service Regulations
All Ohio cities in the
survey also regulated the
level and quality of service.
Five of the eight city
ordinances prohibited -- ____H' , ---
taxicabs from waiting for potential customers except at officially designated taxicab
stands.
This may explain why Cleveland's cap on taxicab licenses is
set at 700, but only 293 licenses have been issued, a lower
number than either Cincinnati or Columbus.
Akron, Canton, and Dayton require full-time service, 24-hours, 7-days per week,
effectively prohibiting part-time cab services. This ordinance effectively prevents an
independent, single-operator entrepreneur from entering the market. One person cannot
operate a business non-stop, 7 days a week, 24-hours a day without help. Thus, any start-
20
c
up company will immediately have to cover the overhead of additional employees, either
more drivers or administrative support,
Columbus Places
Moratorium on New Cab
Licenses
c
The City of Columbus
imposed a moratorium on
new taxicab licenses in May,
1990. The moratorium on
new licenses effectively
capped the number of
taxicabs at 433. The City's
Vehicle for Hire Board
declared that the number of
taxicabs in the city was
excessive after conducting a
need and necessity study.
More cabs, they believe, will
harm the public and
compromise "the public
health, peace, property,
safety, and welfare" of the
citizens of Columbus.
The result has been an
increase in the black market
price of taxicab licenses.
While, officially, a taxicab
operator's license would cost
only $75, prospective cab
operators have reportedly
paid thousands of dollars for
the privilege of operating a
taxi in the City.
Many inner-city neighborhoods and low-in-come residents
might benefit from companies that service only high
volume times (e.g., Friday or Saturday nights) or serve
customers only on an on-call basis. This is one of the
primary reasons Indianapolis dropped its regulation
.requiring 24-hour availability for taxicab operators. In
Washington, D.C., entry is relatively unrestricted. Ninety
percent of the taxicabs are owner operated, and half are
part_time.42
Proof of public need is almost always an onerous
regulatory barrier because the presumption is against new
:entrants. This standard arose because taxicabs were
originally regulated as a public utility.43 Criteria for
.determining public need are often ambiguous and subject
to wide interpretation by regulatory authorities. The
:burden of proof is also almost always shifted to the new
'entrants who must "prove" a "need," or unmet demand,
exists for new taxicab companies and operators. Often, exi
.sting companies have an opportunity to show local
authorities how they will meet the need discovered or
identified by the applicant for a new taxicab company
license. Denver's requirement created a burden impossible
to overcome without expensive litigation. These
restrictions allowed existing companies in Philadelphia in
:the 1970s and 1980s to keep the number of operating cabs
. . 44
to a mlrumum.
Toledo requires applicants to prove their company wtIl
.serve a public need. Cincinnati has a similar provision, but
criteria approved with the deregulation ordinance in 1995
significantly reduced the burden of proof for applicants.45
In fact, a critical component of Cincinnati's deregulatory
---efforts was defining public need clearly to reduce the
burden on new taxicab companies. By reducing uncertainty over whether new
applications would be approved, this reform was partly responsible for a significant incre
ase in the number of cab companies starting up after deregulation (see cincinnati).
Rate Regulations
The final area of regulation concerns rate regulations. All the ordinances examined in
C Ohio cities regulate how and when taxicab companies can set rates or fares.
c
c
c
21
In Toledo, the taxicab ordinance sets a maximum and minimum rate, effectively requiring
a set price for all taxis.46 A similar restriction exists in Youngstown, where the local
ordinance specifies that the rate must be $1.50 for the first 1/10 of a mile and 10 cents for
each additiona11/1 0 mile.47 Thus, in both cities, negotiating for a lower fare would be
illegal.
Four cities - Cincinnati, Cleveland,
Columbus, and Dayton - set a maximum
fare.
Taximeter Rate Setting Policies
Akron.. ....... market determined
Canton ........ market determined
Cincinnati ......... maximum rate
O I .. Akr d C Cleveland .......... maximum rate
n y two cItIes, on an anton,
. Columbus ....."...... maximum rate
alIowed market-determined fares. Each of Dayton.... . . . . . . . .. maximum rate
these cities, however, requires cab Toledo ......... set by ordinance
companies to submit fares and rate changes' Youngstown ..... set by ordinance
to city officials before they go into effect.48 - . .,. '---
In Canton, rate changes must also be advertised three times in "a publication of general
circulation. ,,49 These procedures are administrative, however, and less likely to distort
markets.
Rates can also be regulated by specif'ying how the fare will be caclulated. Most taxi fares
are calculated using taximeters, devices that track the distance traveled and time sitting
idle (e.g., in traffic, at traffic lights, or waiting for customers). Fares are determined by
multiplying the rate by the distance traveled plus waiting fees.
Six of Ohio's largest cities require that fares be calculated using a taxi-meter. Cleveland
and Columbus set maximum rates, but also officially allow alternative forms of charging
hfl ti ..50
customers suc as at rates or certam trIps.
In most cities, charging or negotiating fares other than the amount registered on a
taximeter would be illegal. Taxicab owners or drivers could not legally charge a flat fee
for specific trips, or set different fee levels for peak times or special hours.
Rate regulation can mean higher overall rates for consumers. Average fares for a I-mile
trip in the two cities (Akron and Canton) that allow the market to determine rates have
fares 11.8% lower than cities that regulate rates. 51 The average fare in the cities that use
markets to determine taximeter prices for cab services was $2.59 for the first mile (Figure
6). The average fare for the cities with a maximum rate ceiling was $2.85, and $3.1-0 for
the two cities that have rates set by ordinance.
Figure 6
Taxicab Fares for I-Mile Trip in Ohio's Largest Cities
Average Fares ($)
c
c
c
r--'
/i
,
i
';--. _.._..._---,~-.~~~.._~---_.._~~--_...-.. .--.
S 3.5
[
,
3 :.j
i j
,
r, 5 J i
... I..
iS3~ lu
~-~.._-S~-._--- ....-.-----;>'..
r,
L..
$2..59
./ t---
I
~.
~---,.'
i.5
., t I
i,
J I
r _ ! !
~; .;:, --
~"l<::i- x ....'"I,..J:i,;I~.J.,: H:..I.:'-;
:-,l~ < '",;,_ ...ir-'.;lr""" r :r, "f'!..,
R?-",.' ,',..,! b~ {h .' ;1:'>
Source: See end notes
22
,/!--, -j
I
1'---.
!
I
f-
I
I
!
i
f---"
. I
I I
.iff),:,,:.' }'"
Cab company fares are also competitive for longer distance trips in cities using markets
to determine trip prices (Figure 7). The average fare in Akron and Canton was $7.53 for a
5 mile trip, higher thim the average of $7.49 for the cities with rate ceilings. These rates
were still lower than in cities with rates set by local ordinance ($8.00). Overall, the
average market-determined fare was 3.4% lower than the average fares in regulated
cities.
Many factors will determine taxicab fares, including the level of demand and the number
of suppliers. Nevertheless, these data suggest that legal restrictions on prices do not
necessarily translate into lower average fares.
Figure 7
Taxicab Fares for 5-Mile Trip in Ohio's Largest Cities
Average Fares ($)
c ~. 1 (j ,.
f
I
f I
,
I
EO
Ii
"
c..
~,
'.'
.--_..._._..~---_._.._._-.
'''S;7;5'J
,.I"
'.
, ~', ,.. II _, .: i...,; - "':"
Source: See end notes
23
5&.00
S';".~$
).
,.'''0
"
I
,
i-.
I
~
I
I
~.
,
..'
U 1',-.,_;....' -i"~,':
;'.;--C::,:',:";..-:_:I;,1';'''101
Summary of Local Taxicab Regulatory Policies
C The most common regulations effect price and fares.52 Six cities set a maximum price
and allow only metered fares. In most cases, alternate fares and prices, cannot be set
based on the type of trip or the time of day.
Half of Ohio's largest central cities require physician's certificates for drivers, mandate
financial reports for cab companies, and regulate colors and insignias;
table 3
Most Common Taxicab Regulations in Ohio's Largest Central Cities
c
24
.';: lCn
c
{ ;:~:::~~J~i:ri'('"
1 /'/:..'i~'i'.f:";:../!:; Vfj::.~;;;.' rES'i...:'iated
! ",':,-;'-"'!O!C'TC:' ;:.,n.:'c ;'~'-::',"1~DttCC1
C"'\I'" ~t.""'l-i+~ ...- ....,/~t,Zld
':"'4..1 .~~;::.: ~"',.., '!"":'~<,li,n.~,_
:-"! '::;:::)C_..'~L"~- (~c.r7/;':'.r::.;,JiC IE':;Urre::;-"
r-~:::,'-'.r"::'::-'''lrv -r(n~-->"":"; ''"''~ rt..
i~, ....'_.~"'" -J i',.j.:...'~VJU, '(;.,1'0,0,.0
~-:.:': CQ{C/::,: 'i.i::.iP.:i'.:]
:::~:3p C.'D nUP~bt!r r~,d iaxJS
.:".: ~(C\.J :Jcr,.-'}('::-:, rtJ:).'jirA(/
..:: " f:1.
. ",'
rl:'I.:::,',-' tC-,:rtteS
,'e h~;fvirj.C1 ).":: ni:~i'(/ i)~cen$2S
;""l\"!ti<:Y th:~.:'"1 r~~gai e9(::' reaulre;}
:::":-:\"'.0. " !/;,'!C n~'i:'?'d 8: '1eC,t,.::?SS',':tl
.....")."""0 d'c:~~'-"';n'" o"JC' e
-~ci' .:::,. _~_- l""&.<-'dL.....' II ~.""1 UJ'-
c
.',,~~},~J'l:rTI 0,"",1(.[.: :'caulr(Jtc j
t --I"~-","i~~~.., C'" 'p-' ..:;.,/..~..J
",-.\<!~J~I..."ff':;:: .....r" 0; 1;...IHJJ..J ~.{,;.tJ'
\''';',,'':(.)'1' ~'d~_1 c:)nl.~;U:'~~" size
.:}t"'f!1':i- "'J~ nt'",ru,"'""!_~ ~.rurl."'H''''d
.~~-("'.....: _.y~' t..:i,.,...; ,;...~-l"lIU-..t...:
r ,r f-:'CJU"-S repLljfi!ed
~-,
I
J Nu~~'}.~~~' 0'; C~t~f-:"::,
,
,
i
I
,
I
6
i
I
r
I
1
I
i
t
I
I
i
i
t
!
I
<
n ~~
'... ..~
fj
.
.'
.~,
,- !\
c -
"
.'
" .,
j -
- '.'
~
i ,-
,
I ''', - r,
'- - -,
I ,--\ " "
! r - ~
0:..'::'
I
I ~ .., 'i
, , .
. , c-
o
I . ,.,,,
, L.-.1
! i lC
- .'
4
,j
"'
~'
.:
n
:::.
"
~
..,
""
1
v. The Regulatory Burden of Regulation: The Case of
Dayton
This section estimates the costs imposed by local regulations on start-up taxicab
coinpanies and drivers in Dayton. By estimating the financial burden of complying with
the city's taxicab regulations, a more complete understanding of the role these regulations
play in limiting entry becomes possible.
Drivers in Dayton, like their counter-parts in other Ohio cities, are not entrepreneurs. In
fact, while 100 cars are licensed to operate as taxis, the city has only 4 licensed taxicab
companies. Drivers usually do not own their cars. They usually work as independent
contractors for large cab companies_
c
25
C The following analysis helps explain why.
Cost Impacts of Regulations
In Dayton, an important barrier to sole proprietorship is a regulation requiring a separate
business office open at all times to receive and dispatch calls.53 This regulation adds at
least two additional cost items.
First, the taxicab company must now rent commercial office space since local zoning
laws do not allow a taxicab company to operate as a home-based business.54 Renting
office space will cost the firm about $1,750 annually.55
Additional Employees
Second, the firm will need to hire employees to cover the 24-hour dispatching service. At
least four additional people would be needed to run the business/dispatching office on a
full-time basis.56 Since dispatching will require some skill, wages will probably be above
minimum wage. Combined with social security, workers compensation and
unemployment insurance, labor costs from this regulation could approach $50,000 for
four employees. 57
Cost Impacts of Restrictions on Hours
c
Other elements of Dayton's ordinance virtually eliminate the single owner/operator from
the local taxicab market.
The ordinance also requires all companies to provide taxicab services 24 hours a day, 7-
days per week. 58 Thus, any new company will need more than one driver, since one
driver is unlikely to be available at all the times required by law.
In Dayton, this means each company will have to add cars to accommodate a larger
number of drivers. More cars are necessary to ensure at least one operates at all times. If
one car breaks down, or needs to be serviced, the company would violate the local
ordinance since its services would not be accessible at all times.
If the company needs 3 cars to ensure 24-hours, 7-day a week service, it would have to
purchase and maintain at least two cars in addition to the one the entrepreneur uses ifhe
or she were a sole proprietor owner/operator. Combined with insurance, this would add
$14,570 on to the first year costs ofa start-up a business if the company owned the cars
and insured them.59
Costs of Licensing and Fees
c
The taxicab company is charged $250 per cab annually to operate.60 Thus, licensing the 3
cabs will cost $750. Each driver incurs an additional cost of$33 annually, $25 for the
license and $8 for ID processing. This means expenses could run as high as $915 each
c
c
c
26
year just to license 5 drivers that would cover the days and hours of operation required by
law.
Restrictions on Fares
Another local regulation requires taximeters, approved by the Police Department, in
every taxi to calculate fares.61 A taximeter is a device that records the distance traveled
and the total cost of the trip. A taximeter costs between $150 and $450, according to local
cab companies and public officials, and must be placed in every operating taxicab. This
would be a onetime expense.
In addition to the maximum price regulation, however, the taximeter imposes another
type of price control. Taxicabs are required to set their fares based solely on distance
traveled. Since the fare is regulated by the City, price competition is discouraged. It
would be illegal, for example, for a company to offer downtown taxicab transportation
for a flat fee of $3.00 as an established service. The total cost of the trip is based on the
published fare (not to exceed $1.60 for the first 1/6 of a mile and 20 cents for each
additional 1/6 mile)
multiplied by the distance
traveled.
This policy discourages
efficient pricing policies
and price competition. By
prohibiting other forms of
pricing (e,g., flat rates,
reduced rates on certain
routes, etc.), local cabbies
cannot price according to
peak times, special trips, or
other criteria other than
distance.
Restrictions on Service
Availability
Table 4
Regu1atory Costs of Startinq a
Cab Company in Dayton
Cost
Taxi cab operators
Clerical/support (4)
Base salary
Social Security
Workers Comp
Unemployment Insurance
Additional Cars (2)
Insurance for Cars
Separate office space
Licensing
Vehicle Licenses (3)
Taxi driver's Licenses
Taximeters (3)
Taxicab operators are also
not allowed to solicit
passengers except at
"lawfully designated
'b d ,,62 Th'
taxlca stan S. IS Source: The
restricts the demand for cab 'indicates a
services and, as a result,
opportunities for taxicab entrepreneurs.
Total estimated Burden
Estimated Burden
Contract work
$ 42,000
$ 3,150
$ 3,069
$ 1,080
$ 8,570
$ 6,000
$ 1,750
$ 750
(5) $ 165
$ 450'
$ 66,984
Buckeye Institute, see end notes.
one-time expense.
c
c
c
27
This restriction makes it illegal for cabs to wait outside bars, restaurants, and other
establishments without approved taxicab stands, further restricting their use as an
everyday means of transportation. Thus, consumers also experience a lower level of
service than would exist of taxi drivers were allowed to tailor their services to the needs
of individual consumers and peak demand locations and times.
Summary of Regulatory Burden in Dayton
What is the cumulative impact of these regulations in Dayton?
The fiscal impact alone of these regulations arnounts to $66,984 in additional costs during
the first year of operation (Table 4, Figure 8). This means that for a new company to start
up, it must generate almost $67,000 to cover the costs imposed by the loca I ordinance,
irrespective of the compensation to the entrepreneur, More than 95% of these costs, are in
added personnel, cars, and equipment as a result of the effective prohibition on part-time
operators.
The impact oflocal regulations on entrepreneurship can be seen when the burden is
compared to the earnings from operating the business. The average annual income of a
taxicab operator in Ohio is about $20,000.63 This means, for a taxicab company, local
regulations create operating costs in the start-up year that exceed 3 times the average
annual earnings of a taxicab driver.
Figure 8
Cost of Regulatory Burden on New Taxi Companies in Dayton
~!~erlse:::, "1 ~:~)
// Oi"~ic{:' SPBCC :i(~~.
-""....-..-...
A.c1c18C; C;ns 22~.t:
..~- Ta~.imete,,: jC"
.,...-.,:....-
. "".
.
"
,~.:~:'J',"i~,:,:'::.2~;,.>l
_,' .,....,;j:...m.\~;3}'~~;~.'fti'>:;;V "'-.....
. ,,-;- - . ,,'.' ". . -.~ .
~' ~:::;:"~;::~ :~-r:~;?r'
Additional
Personnet '7 ~r;"t)
, . >,'~,--.:.
28
c
Source: The Buckeye Institute. Percentages do not add to 100 due to rounding.
Thus, the taxicab company is no longer a low-cost business accessible to the semi-skilled,
low-skilled, or start-up entrepreneur. A cab company requires a substantial financial
investment. This means the start-up company will need third party financing from a bank,
development corporation, or private individual, substantially reducing economic
opportunities for neighborhood residents.
In Dayton, most taxicab drivers work for someone else. Only 4 cab companies operate
100 taxicabs (legally) in the city. Given the costs of starting up a new company under
local law, the reasons for the low number of independent companies are even more
Regulation Mandates Inefficiency
lded impact of these regulations is to force entrepreneurs to invest money inefficiently.
he analysis of the Dayton ordinance shows, regulations require entrepreneurs to spend money in areas
lay not be most productive. For example, companies in Dayton, Cleveland, and Toledo are required to
ley to staff a dispatching office, even though modern technology would allow a company to operate
d efficiently without one (e.g., paging, voice-mail,cellularphones, etc.). This is money that could be
'(:, the quality of cars or increasing the number of drivers t 0 service other areas of their respective
: regulations, taxicab services are more costly to operate than in a market-driven industry, In fact, while
does not calculate the impact on the rate of return for investors and entrepreneurs, the regulatory burden
,dates an inefficiently large cab company.
! Smaller, more efficient, and potentially more profitable companies cannot operate effectively. These
s give established, large companies an even greater advantage in the market place,
__.______________ _n___'_ _._ __ __..n __ ._. ....__..____'___' __"U _'_ _.___ __ _,__._____ _...____.____.__._..._..___~________._._ -- .-.-..------.~
evident.
VI. Increasing Economic Opportunity
Through Taxicab Regulatory Reform
c
The impact oflocal regulations on start-up businesses are significant and important. In
Dayton, Ohio, for example, entrepreneurs face burdens that effectively require them to
29
c
begin a business with almost $70,000 in start-up capital just to satisfY the regulations,
Burdens this high clearly constrain economic opportunities for local residents.
Similar burdens have led several cities, including Cincinnati (see below), to deregulate
large parts of their taxicab markets.
Specifically, what can city officials do to break down regulatory barriers and increase
economic opportunities in the taxicab market?
This research and the experience of other cities with deregulation suggest several
"principles" for regulatory reform:
Adopt Streamlined Licensing and Registration Procedures.
Cities should depoliticize the licensing process, reducing the role of licensing boards in
granting taxicab licenses. This can be accomplished by making licensing an
administrative process. Cities should avoid broad, politically driven criteria such as
"public need" or "improve service quality."
This means using concrete, identifiable criteria for granting licenses, such as ensuring the
taxicab operators:
c
. have a good safety and driving record.
. are of legal age,
. have a legal driver's license.
. have no recent criminal record.
.....------.----.--.----------..--.---..---.-.-- .._-----_._---_._-_.__...__.~. -.--- ---.- ---.--.----.---"
Cincinnati Pushes Forward on Taxicab Deregulation
) deregulate the taxicab industry in Cincinnati built up over several years.
) to 1994, the city imposed an unofficial cap of 348 licenses issued. In 1994, in the first step toward
In, the city lifted the cap and distributed 170 new licenses. By late 1994, in the wake of Indianapolis's
Llblic officials in Cincinnati were again holding hearings on taxicab deregulation.
of 1995, the taxicab industry was deregulated further by the city council. The council would not place
limit on the number of licenses issued, but it retained the provision that applicants prove "public
ce and necessity" in order to obtain a license. The revised ordinance however prohibits local authorities
.ding the economic impact on existing taxicab companies in granting the licenses. Criteria such as
Ie new company will serve underserved areas, whether t he quality of service will be enhanced, the
:ord of the applicant, and any past criminal activity are considered in determining whether a new license
mted.
HCH-
--------------------.-------..-------------- ---- -----_._---,_.._._--~---
. have a clean and safe car.
c
c
c
Preserve Open Entry
30
Consumers are served when new competitors enter the market to challenge existing
companies with lower fares or better quality. Open entry can be ensured by:
. removing caps on numbers of taxis and licenses.
. streamlined licensing process.
. automatic renewal oflicenses.
. lowering fees.
. removing minimum cab company size
Maximize Flexibility
Customers have varied needs and wants, and the
taxicab market should reflect this. Taxicab companies
should be allowed to:
. operate on a part-time basis.
. serve specific needs and peak demand times.
. serve particular routes.
. provide niche services (e.g., after hours
transportation for bars).
. determine acceptable pick-up and drop-off sites.
Minimize Fees
Key Features of a
Pro-Entrepreneur
Taxicab Ordinance
. Streamlined licensing
process
. Open entry.
. Maximum flexibility
. Minimal fees
. Restructured zoning laws
Taxicab licensing fees should reflect the administrative costs of processing the
application and running criminal background checks on the applicants.
. limit taxicab operator fee to $25 or less.
. exempt start-up businesses from licensing fees in the early years of their
operations.
Restructure Zoning Laws
Classify taxicab companies as home-based businesses for zoning purposes unless they:
. create a perceptible and quantifiable burden on their neighbors and neighborhood.
. out-grow their existing space within the home.
31
c
Adopting these principles, and translating them into legislative action, will help create
economic opportunities for urban residents while providing a higher level and quality of
service to everyone.
Appendix: Benefits of Taxicab Deregulation
Despite widespread regulation of taxicabs, relatively little research has been published on
the subject. An electronic search of more than 300,000 articles, books, and dissertations
generated only 9 "citations relating to the taxicab industry and taxicab regulation.
One of the more recent studies was commissioned by the International Taxicab
Foundation, an organization servicing the interests of the taxicab industry. The study,
performed by Price Waterhouse, analyzed taxicab deregulation, re-regulation, and
regulation in 29 cities. Generally, the study concluded that deregulation I) did not reduce
prices, 2) did not significantly improve service quality, and 3) did not lower
administrative costs. The study then concluded that all but four of the 21 cities that
deregul ated have moved to re-regulate their taxi industries as a result of dissatisfaction
with the effects of deregulation.
c
The study's findings and conclusions, however, are questionable. First, the analysis relies
to a significant degree on case studies, some of which have conflicting results. For
example, Price Waterhouse uses data from San Diego to show that service quality
declined, while other data found that service quality may have increased (see discussion).
The study also uses Indianapolis as an example of a city that deregulated and then re-
regulated as a response to poor market performance. Indianapolis, howe ver, is now used
as an example of comprehensive deregulation as a result of its 1994 deregulation efforts
(see box on p. 7).
More importantly, the Price Waterhouse report ignores the role politics may have played
in pushing cities to re-regulate. Existing taxicab owners are often the most vocal
opponents to deregulation. In many cases, they stand to lose significant amounts of
money if the market were opened up. In Indianapolis, for example, the cap on taxicabs
created a black market for licenses. The only way someone could operate a taxi was if
they purchased a license from an existint company. The going black market rate for a
I icense before deregulation was $5,000. Once the market was opened up, the price of a
taxicab license fell to just $100. One of the city's principal taxicab owners owned 300
licenses. Thus, the cab company owner effectively lost $1.5 million as the value of his
licenses fell as a result of deregulation!
c
Many of the cities that remained deregulated were growing cities, where an expanding
economic pie could satisfY existing and new entrants. Many of the cities that re-regulated,
or remained regulated, were slow growth or declining cities. These cities would
experience the most intensive lobbying by existing taxicab owners to restrict entry and
increase regulation,Existing cab company owners could lose substantial amounts of their
investment if the market were opened up.
c
c
c
Another problem with the Price Waterhouse report is its imprecise definition and use of
"re-regulation." While many cities re-instituted caps on taxicabs, others went from
allowing fares to be set in a free-market to instituting maximum fares. In many cases, the
price system was still more mar-ket-oriented than when the city was fully regulated.
In addition, while median fares increased faster in deregulated cities compared to
regulated cities, average fares increased more slowly. The median would be the price
charged by the taxicab company halfway down the list if each company were listed from
slowest to fastest growth in fares. The average fare would measure how fares in the entire
market responded. The average incorporates fare changes of all companies operating in
the market. On average, fares between 1985 and 1992 increased by 17 .4% in deregulated
cities and by 17.3% in regulated cities. (The Price Waterhouse study only reports median
data.)
The Price Waterhouse study also ignores the important public policy goal of increasing
the number of jobs for local residents. The study observes that the increase in the number
of taxicabs following deregulation resulted from a substantial increase in the number of
small and independent cab companies, Thus, even if deregulation were not accompanied
by clear improvements in quality, deregulation could be justified for the widely
acknowledged impact of increasing economic opportunity for local residents, par
ticularly those in poor inner-city areas.
End Notes
I. For an overview of the potential barriers, see Walter E. Williams, The State Against
Blacks (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1982),75-88. For a more recent analysis of the impact
oflocal policy on taxicabs, see Bill Styring, "Taxicab Licensing In Indianapolis: The
Situation and Economics," paper prepared for Regulatory Study Commission, City of
Indianapolis, January, 1993.
2. Also called Gypsy cabs, these illegal operations already exist in many of Ohio's
neighborhoods, particularly underserved and poor areas. The ways red tape and laws
drive businesses underground has been explored extensively in the academic literature.
See Hernando De Soto, The Other Path (New York: Harper R Row), 1989; Saskia
Sassen-Koob, "New York City's Informal Economy," in The Informal Economy: Studies
in Advanced and Less Developed Countries. ed. Alejandro Portes, Manuel Castells and
La uren A. Benton (Baltimore, Md: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1989), pp. 60-77;
and Sam Staley, Drug Policy and tbe Decline of Ameril.:an Cities (New Brunswick, N,J.:
Transaction Books, 1992), pp. 18-26. Drug Policy and the Decline of American Cities,
and Peter Reuter, Robert MacCoun, and Patrick Murphy, Money from Crime: A Study of
the Economics of Drug Dealing in Washington, D. C. (Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND
Corporation) 1990.
4. Estimates based on the used car market in Dayton, Ohio (see Section V) and interviews
with representatives of companies that insure taxicabs and taxicab operators,
32
~
.
c
c
c
33
5. Cities limited the number of taxi-cabs, froze the number at the existing level, or used
population ratios to regulate the number of taxis. Only 6 cities in their study allowed open
entry without inquiry into "public convenience," number of taxicabs, etc. Price
Waterhouse, Analysis of Taxicab Deregulation and Re-Regulation (Kensington,
Maryland: International Taxicab Foundation, 1993), Appendix A. Indianapolis had an
ordinance imposed cap of 600 taxis before it deregulated its taxicab industry in 19 94.
The controller, however, was required to determine the number of taxis that could operate
within the city within the 600 limit imposed in the ordinance, The effective cap, then, at
the time of deregulation was 393.
6. See Williams, Tbe State Against Blacks.
7. In New York City, cab drivers pay between $75 and $100 per 12-hour shift to a legal
cab company to drive a cab. See William H. Mellor, Is New York Killing
Entrepreneurship? (Washington, D.C.: Institute for Justice, 1996) p. 6.
8. See Dwight Filley, "Taken for a Ride: How the Taxi Cartel and the State Are
Disserving Denver's Economy," Issue Paper #6-93 (Golden, CO: Independence Institute,
April), 1993; "Challenging Denver's Taxicab Monopoly," Litigation Backgrounder,
Institute for Justice, Washington, D,C., n.d., n.p.
9. Institute for Justice, "Challenging Denver's Taxicab Monopoly. "
10. Ibid.
11. The Fourteenth Amendment protects "privileges or immunities of citizenship," which
include the right to contract and engage in trade, by guaranteeing equal protection under
the laws.
12. Media Advisory, Institute for Justice, August 1, 1995. The taxi market was opened up
through legislative activity prompted by the law suit.
13. Data as of July, 1996, provided by the Institute for Justice, Washington, D.C.,
September 3, 1996.
14, See Jeff Simmons, "Compromise Means City Still Regulates Taxicabs," Cincinnati
Business Courier, February 3,1995.
15. The ordinance retained language requiring proof of public convenience and necessity,
against city staff recommendations to eliminate this language, but explicitly prevents the
city from considering "the impact an applicant's business may have on the business of
existing license holders."(Section 407-8(i)). The ordinance further specifies that the city
"shall consider" criteria such as whether the applicant will service underserved areas of
the Cincinnati or whether the new company will result in service improvements. These
criteria will not necessarily determine whether the applicant's license will be approved or
denied. See Ordinance 33, Section 407-8, paragraphs (a) through 0). For administration
c
c
c
34
comments, see the memorandum from William M. Gustavson, Director of Safety for the
City of Cincinnati on Taxi Regulation Ordinance Proposal, January 10, 1995.
16. Memorandum from Gustavson, January 10, 1995.
17. Data as of July, 1996, provided by the Institute for Justice, Washington, D.C.,
September 3, 1996.
18. Data as of July, 1996, provided by the Institute for Justice, Washington, D.C.,
September 3, 1996.
19. Gene Stalians, "Regulatory Revision and the Taxicab Industry: What We have
Leamed," paper presented to the 50th Annual Convection, The New Zealand Taxi
Proprietors' Federation, Wellington, New Zealand, August 30, 1988.
20. Price Waterhouse, Analysis of Taxicab Regulation and Deregulation, p. iii.
21. Roger F, Teal, "Taxicab Regulatory Change in San Diego," Taxicab Management
(Fall 1986), p. 32.
22. Simmons, "Compromise Means City Still Regulates Taxicabs."
23. Specifically, Stalians argued for a "zone of reasonableness" standard to govern rate
changes. See Stalians, "Regulatory Revision and the Taxicab Industry," pp. 10-1. Many
cities have moved toward this standard anyway by setting rate maximums rather than
specifYing precise fares in ordinances.
24. Teal, "Taxicab Regulatory change in San Diego," p.32
25. Price Waterhouse, Analysis of Taxicab Deregulation and Re-regulation, p. II.
26. Ibid. See R.F. Teal and M. Berglund, "The Impacts of Taxicab Deregulation in the
USA," Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, January, 1987, p.41.
27. See Williams, The State Against Blacks.
28. D. Wayne Tailor, "The Economic Effects of the Direct Regulation of the Taxicab
Industry in Metropolitan Toronto," Logistics and Transportation Review 25, no. 2 (June
1989), pp. 169-82.
29. Importantly, new drivers will enter the market because they expect their earnings as
taxicab operators to be greater than their current wages. In many inner-city areas, this
could mean unemployment or unskilled minimum wage jobs. Thus, for these employees,
owning and operating a taxicab company will be a significant step upward, economically.
The increased wages to new entrants into the taxicab market is rarely considered in
assessments of the benefits/costs of deregulation.
c
c
c
35
30. The Buckeye Institute used] 992 population data to identify cities with populations
over 80,000 people.
3]. Central cities excluded from the analysis are Lima, Mansfield, Zanesville, and
Springfield. Central cities are defined by the Census bureau as cities with at least 50,000
in population that serve as the employment center within a metropolitan area of at least
100,000. Since each of these cities has a population below 80,000, we excluded them
from our analysis.
32. Follow up telephone calls were made to each of the cities to verify our interpretation
of the ordinance and to gather additional information about how regulations were
implemented, the size of the taxicab market, and the number of applicants for new
licenses.
33. Cleveland taxicab ordinance, Chapter 443, Section 443.03.
34. To]edo taxicab ordinance, Chapter 77], Section 77] .0].
35. City of Columbus, Ordinance No. 1385-90, approved May 22, ]990.
36. This is why the black market cost of taxicab licenses is higher than the legal rate.
Licenses in New York City, or medallions, can cost $] 75,000 or more. Banks will even
loan money for entrepreneurs to purchase the medal-lions. See Mellor, Is New York
Killing Entrepreneurship?
37. Most cities require companies to register color schemes, names, and inisgnia. This
was counted as a "regulation" only if the ordinance required city officials to approve
them.
38. Cleveland city taxicab ordinance, Chapter 443, Sections 443.0]],443.02], and
443.022.
39. Ibid., Section 443.05.
40. Canton city taxicab ordinance, Chapter 763, Section 763.05(b)(]).
41. Ibid., Section 763.12(e).
42. Williams, The State Against Blacks, pp, 82-3.
43. Interview with William H. Mellor, attorney, Institute for Justice, Washington, D.C.
Mellor was the lead counsel in the court case that led to opening up the Denver taxicab
market.
44. See the discussion in Williams, The State Against Blacks, pp. 80- I.
c
c
c
36
45. See the discussion in note 15.
46. Toledo City Ordinances, Chapter 781.05.
47. Youngstown city ordinances, Section 785.06.
48. Akron city ordinances, Section 111..544(B), Canton city ordinances, Chapter 763.04
(E).
49. Canton, Ibid.
50. Some city ordinance allow flat fares for special events (e.g., concerts or other major
public gatherings at a specific location). These alternative fares are allowed only at the
discretion of city officials, and are not market driven. Cleveland and Columbus were the
only cities that appear to allow taxis to set different fares from the standard taxi-meter
rate independently of specific events authorized by public officials or otherwise
sanctioned by the city.
51. Average fares determined by telephone interviews with taxicab companies in each of
the cities in this report. The fares are unadjusted averages, and do not account for fleet
size. Price Waterhouse found that independent drivers and companies tended to have
higher fares than large fleets. See Price Waterhouse, Analysis Taxicab Deregulation and
Deregulation. Using an unadjusted average, then, might distort the citywide averages in
cities with a larger number of independent drivers.
52. This index excludes insurance and bonding requirements. All cities require cab
companies and drivers to be insured and bonded. These requirements help prevent "fly-
by-night" companies that operate risky operations.
53. Dayton city ordinances, Section 115.44(B).
54. A taxicab company would not qualify as a home business because it would require a
full-time paid employee, or someone who is not an occupant of the residence, and require
daily services and traffic not normally found in the adjacent residential area. See Dayton
Zoning Code, Section 150.342, paragraphs G and J,
55. Based on 250 square feet of office space, rented at $7.00 per square foot. This is a
conservative estimate because commercial office space is not readily available in many
low-income areas. Thus, the rent could be much higher. Data on office rent and lease
rates were compiled from 1995 greater Dayton Office Market Study (Dayton: The GEM
Real Estate Group), submarket surveys by Leasetrends, Inc., and interviews with real
estate agents and brokers.
56. A 24-hour' a day operation means that a workers would have to cover 168 hours each
week. This means at least 4.2 people would be required to cover the dispatching office on
a full-time equivalent (FTE) basis (4.2 people x 40 hours per week = 168 hours).
c
c
c
37
57. Assuming 4.2 (FTE) positions averaging $5 per hour. The entrepreneur is assumed to
be a cab driver, and does not work in the dispatching office. The Ohio Bureau of
Employment Services estimates that workers in transportation services and utilities
averaged $15.24 per hour in June, 1994. Many of these workers have specialized skills
that are not necessary for dispatching services. Retail wage rates averaged $7.76 per hour
in the same month, which is probably closer to the skill level needed for this busi ness.
Nevertheless, interviews with cab company operators in the Dayton area indicated that
most dispatchers eam substantially less. See Ohio Bureau of Employment Services,
Labor Market Reviece, June 1994, p. 37.
58, Dayton Taxicab Ordinance, Section 115.44 (A).
59. The price of a used car was estimated using the N.A.D.A. Official Wholesale Used
Care Trade-In guide, July 22, 1996. Case studies of taxicab deregulation in San Diego
and Seattle suggest that smaller, independent companies have older cars, averaging about
6 years old (Price Waterhouse, Analysis of Taxicab Deregulation and Re-regulation, p.
15). We used the average price of a 1990, basic, 4 door sedan for the following makes
and models: Buick Skylark, Cheverolet Caprice, Chrysler leBaron, Ford Tau rus, and
Oldsmobile Cutlass. Foreign makes (e.g., Honda, Toyota) typically run $2,000 to $3,000
higher. The average cost of the Domestic models for 1992 models (only 4 years old) was
$6,475. Insurance agents indicated insurance would cost about $3,000 per car. Thus,
adding two cars (1990 model average), and insurance for each, would add costs of about
$14,570. The cost of acquiring the cars would be a one-time expense while insurance
would be an annual expense.
60, Section 115.39(B).
61. Section 115.47.
62. Section 115.56(A).
63. This is the estimated average annual wage of an employee in the transportation
industry in Ohio according to the Ohio Bureau of Employment Services. This estimate is
consistent with the experience of cab company operators interviewed for this report.
64. This information and example were drawn from an interview with an economist
involved in the Indianapolis deregulation effort.
o
o
o
'C
SCARED YELLOW:
AN ANALYSIS OF TAXICAB
COMPETITION IN ALLEGHENY
COUNTY
Eric Montarti, Research Associate
Allegheny Institute for Public Policy
Allegheny Institute Report #00-03
January 2000
c
@ by Allegheny Institute for Public Policy. All rights reserved.
Note. Nothing written here is to be construed as an attempt to aid or to
hinder the passage of any bill before the Pennsylvania General
c
1
c
TABLE OF CONTENTS
KEY FINDINGS
2
INTRODUCTION 3
TAXICAB REGULATIONS 4
PROCESS OF COMPETITIVE ENTRY 7
MARKET CONCENTRATION IN
THE PITTSBURGH AREA 8
ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF CONCENTRATION 10
THE INFORMAL ECONOMY 12
C ACHIEVING COMPETITION IN CAB SERVICE 14
REFERENCES 15
c
2
c
KEY FINDINGS
· Pittsburgh and the surrounding communities in Allegheny County are, by and
large, not referred to or thought of as "cab towns". There are several reasons for
this characterization, one of which may be regulations that stifle competition and
thus inhibit new entrants into the taxicab business.
· Taxis are regulated by the Public Utility Commission (Puq. The PUC inspects
cabs on both a random and an annual basis to ensure that they are in proper
working order, meet safety standards, and that the meters conform to stipulations
in the company's tariff.
· The process of competitive entry into the legal taxicab market is overly slanted
toward protecting incumbent companies. Competitors must show a "proof of
need" in order to commence operations.
c
· Regulations keep cab companies from competing head-to-head on the more
lucrative routes. These regulations produce similarities in the fares that cab
companies charge regardless of the area of operation, and economic disparities
between the large and small incumbent companies in the legal cab market.
· The barriers to legal entry has proliferated the "jitney" market in certain areas
around Pittsburgh. This market, albeit highly dangerous and illegal, is the free-
market response to a strong demand for transportation in an underserved area.
.
The PUC and the Pennsylvania General Assembly should amend the regulation
of the taxicab industry so that entrepreneurs that want to start a cab company can
do so with minimal government restrictions.
c
3
c
INTRODUCTION
The recent flap over New York City taxicab drivers refusing to pick up actor Danny
Glover as he waited for a ride highlighted an important fact that most citizens in the
Pittsburgh area know all too well: taxis are not responsive for some groups. I Although
the issue with Glover delves deeper into race issues, almost anyone who has tried to call a
cab--regardless ofrace--has a horror story. Whether calling for a cab from home only to
have the request ignored, relying on a cab when the patron has automobile trouble, or
being bypassed when hailing one on a busy street, the tales often reach mythical
proportions.
Pittsburgh and the surrounding communities in Allegheny County, by and large, are not
"cab towns". Typical explanations ofthis characterization include the fact that downtown
is relatively easy to transit by walking and many neighborhoods are close enough to
town that a cab is not required. Another line of reasoning is that cabs stay around the
downtown hotels and at the airport and are not around the spots where populations and
potential patrons congregate.
c
On the other hand, there is a significant population that relies on passenger service to get
them from home to the store and back. This population, usually low-income and heavily
African-American, has come to rely on a Pittsburgh institution; the jitney. This mode of
transportation is quick, inexpensive but often dangerous and always illegal. It is the
rational response of the free-market to a need that is not being served by regnlated
companies that grab the most profitable routes, most notably the one that runs from
Pittsburgh International Airport to downtown and back.
The purpose of this paper is to illustrate the fact that regulatory guidelines and a
burdensome approval process are hindering taxicab competition in the Pittsburgh area,
perpetuating a lack of cab usage and the growth of an "underground" network of jitney
drivers. Eliminating the current regulations that shield incumbent companies and prevent
new entrepreneurs from entering the cab business will bring benefits to consumers in the
Pittsburgh area in the way of improved service, lower rates, and the potential for greater
usage of this often overlooked service.
I Lou Ransom "Taxicab Redlining a City Tradition". Pittsburgh Tribune-Review, November 20, 1999.
c
4
c
TAXI REGULATIONS
Taxicab operations are governed by two main sources. One source is rather general and
describes the role of the taxicab as a regulated carrier of passengers. The second source
is more specific as it prescribes the day-to-day operations and regulations a cab company
and its drivers must follow.
First, Title 66 ofthe Pennsylvania consolidated statutes, the Public Utilities Code, defines
the term "common carrier". 2 In essence, a common carrier provides "transportation
services to the general public in return for compensation, and are required to serve
everyone who is able to pay. Common carriers are often held to service standards and are
accorded protection from competition through restrictive licensing criteria". This
restrictive licensing criteria shields established companies from new entrants and allows
cabs to operate as regulated monopolies.)
Second, taxicab operations are governed by regulatory guidelines established in Title 52,
Chapter 29 of the Pennsylvania Code. These guidelines involve record-keeping
responsibilities, inspection requirements, and general rules of operation.
Taxicabs provide what is classified as "call or demand" service. This type of service is
defined as
c
"Local common carrier service for passengers, rendered on either an exclusive or
non-exclusive basis, where the service is characterized by the fact that passengers
normally hire the vehicle and its driver either by telephone call or by hail, or
both" .4
Continuity of Service
Regulations governing the continuity of service and any deviation from such continuity
are outlined in Sections 61 and 62 of Chapter 29. Taxicab companies have a rather short
period (thirty days) from the time the franchise is granted to the time service must
commence. If the company does not begin service with this period, the franchise is
terminated unless the PUC rules otherwise. Any interruption of service must be reported
to the commission; if service is discontinued for five consecutive days within prior
notice, the franchise is terminated.s
Cabs cannot travel the route of a fixed time passenger carrier, such as a bus, when
looking to pick up a fare on a non-exclusive basis when the route is in operation. In other
words, call and demand service cannot interfere with scheduled time service.6
, Pennsylvania Consolidated Statutes, Title 66. (1993 Edition). Conunonwealth of Pennsylvania,
Legislative Reference Bureau, Harrisburg, P A.
3 Boroski, John W. and Gerard C.S. Mildner: "An Economic Analysis of Taxicab Regulation in Portland,
Oregon". Cascade Policy Institute, Policy Perspective 1007. (,,,,,v.cascadeoolicv.org).
4 Pennsylvania Code, Title 52, Chapter 29, Section 13.
'Pennsylvania Code, Title 52, Chapter 29, Sections 61 and 62.
6 Pennsylvania Code, Title 52, Chapter 29, Section 312.
c
5
c
Inspections
The regulations entail inspections by the Public Utility Commission (PUC) of the cab on
both random and annual instances, the investigation of complaints against taxi companies
and their drivers, and ensuring that meter rates (flag-drops and mile intervals) are in line
with the company's tariff. The PUC must monitor the cab company to make sure that the
driver of the cab is an employee of the company, that drivers maintain daily log sheets
that detail times and places of origin, number of passengers, readings of meters, and the
like, unless this requirement is substituted by some other method approved by the PUC.
The cab company must also report gross operating revenue from service provided under
their certified authority. 7
Items to be Contained in the Daily Log Sheet of a Cab Driver
. The date
. Time the shift commenced and ceased
. Vehicle ID Number
. Times and places of origin and destination of each trip including the ntileage at both points
. Number of passengers and the fare collected on each trip
. Each trip on which packages were delivered and the charge
. Meter readings at beginning and end of shift
. Name and number of the driver
. Silmllture of the driver attestin2to the accuracv of the data'
c
Vehicular Requirements
Vehicle and equipment requirements are quite restrictive as well. Only vehicles with
seating capacities of eight passengers or less, excluding the driver, can qualify for call or
demand service. Meters are required for vehicles operating in a municipality with over
20,000 residents. The meter must be installed in the front of the vehicle so that it is in
clear view of the passenger and the cost for installing the meter is borne by the company.
Vehicles must comply with standards set forth by the Department of Transportation: all
door hinges and latches must be in working order; all advertisements must be clearly
fastened and not obstruct the view ofthe driver; clean and sanitary condition must be
maintained in the seats and in the trunk of the car; and vehicles must have snow tires or
all-weather tires from October I to April I of the following year.9
These regulations take a great degree of flexibility away from the companies that do enter
into the legal taxicab market while at the same time drive prospective competitors away.
The safety requirements are perfectly understandable. Cabs should meet the same level
of standards as other vehicles in the Commonwealth. Since passengers are involved, a
higher degree of cleanliness for the vehicle should also be achieved.
However, the meticulous record keeping and continuity of service requirements place
significant stipulations on the freelancing entrepreneur that may want to target call or
demand service to particular times or events. A vehicle that holds more than seven
7 Pennsylvania Code, Title 52, Chapter 29, Section 101
, Pennsylvania Code, Title 52, Chapter 29, Section 313
9 Pennsylvania Code, Title 52, Chapter 29, Section 314, 402-3
c
6
.c
passengers is disqualified from entering into call or demand service. This distinguishes
call or demand service from group or party service, but it also removes the flexibility of
cab service from large events or groups of people who do not pre-arrange the service.
These regulations curtail innovations that can lead to new and improved services from the
taxi companies.
.c
c
7
c
PROCESS OF COMPETITIVE ENTRY!O
If the PUC regulations appear to leave the back door open for abuse (or mistakes), the
process by which a prospective cab company establishes itself slams that door shut. This
process places competition into the hands of fate and is a major reason for the current
state of taxi service.
A prospective cab company applies for a franchise by filing a $350 fee along with an
application that describes the territory the company wishes to serve and a commitment to
serve the stated area. The company must demonstrate that there is a need for service in
the area, thus placing it in the position of determining that the incumbent cab company or
companies are not responsive. In short, the burden of proof lies with the newcomer.
The application is published in the Pennsvlvania Bulletin (a PUC publication) and is
subject to a IS-working day period in which the application can be contested. When the
application is contested, it is often an incumbent cab company challenging the new
company's "fitness" or ability to serve the area and will argue that they, the incumbent,
will adjust and commence service there. The contesting parties are sent to a mediator
within the office of the Administrative Law Judge (AU) in order to solve the dispute
without litigation. If mediation does not work, the Judge will hear the case.
c
The end result of the AU proceedings is an opinion and order that may resolve the
dispute. If there is a disagreement by either party, an exception to the order is filed. The
opinion and order is then delivered to the Public Utility Commissioners who deliver a
commission order that adopts, slightly modifies, or changes entirely the ALJ opinion and
order.
It is plain to see that the process of competitive entry is slanted toward the incumbent
providers because the competitor and the incumbent engage in a game of "one-
upmanship" in which the new company must prove that there is a service failure on the
part of the established company. Obviously, the cab companies that were franchised first
have no quarrel with this process for the fact that when they were franchised, more areas
"needed" service. Now the process has become twisted: instead of the new company
responding to a market demand and commencing cab service, they are forced to "accuse"
the company that has "failed". Since this regulated monopoly model favors incumbents,
they are given the benefit of the doubt that they can serve "neglected" areas.
10 Interviews with Denise Cohen and Tim Ziegler, Pennsylvania Puhlic Utility Commission, Bureau of
Transportation and Safety.
c
8
c
MARKET CONCENTRATION IN THE PITTSBURGH AREA
Imagine a private business limiting the size of the pool from which it could draw
customers in exchange for shutting similar businesses out of competing with them. This
business would experience significant economic hardship should that pool of customers
ever dissipate. This is exactly how the taxicab industry operates: in return for providing
service in a specific geographic area, the company is shielded from competition. II The
difference is that the territorial reach of most cab companies is large enough to prevent its
demise.
Territorial Assignment
Regulations specifY geographic areas of service and, as a result, head-to-head taxicab
competition in the Pittsburgh area is largely non-existent. Companies may overlap the
communities they serve in some instances, but that is the exception rather than the norm.
In these instances, the competitive effect is nullified because of the differences in size of
the carriers.
Take the example of Pittsburgh: the three cab companies with the oldest franchises all
serve within the city limits. One of these three, People's Cab, has operating authority for
a lO-mile radius outside the city limits. Yellow Cab enjoys this range as well; the
difference here is that Yellow Cab has 248 more cabs than this competitor. The operating
authority similarity is quickly dissipated when one considers the lopsided market share of
the franchised companies. 12
c
Keeping New Companies Out
Entrance into the cab business by new companies has been stifled as well: the last time a
cab company received a franchise from the PUC was in 1995 for a carrier with three cabs
in its fleet. This carrier, Legg Transportation, along with S&S Taxi, which was
franchised in 1982, have been shut out from competing within the city limits. Instead,
they cover portions of eastern and southern Allegheny County, respectively. 13
The entrenchment of the established companies allows for expansion while discouraging
new entrants into the business. For example, in November of 1998 an amendment was
made to Yellow Cab's operating authority to include several communities in the northeast
comer of the county, where their service had not previously extended. The company's
authority was also extended to Findlay Township, the present site of Pittsburgh
International Airport. This type of regulated expansion demonstrates the fact that
regulations ensure that service needs normally are solved by extension of established
authority rather than encouraging new business start-ups as in private industry .14
\I Sam Slaley "How Cities Put the Breaks on Taxicabs". The Freeman, March, 1998.
12 Public Utility Connnission, Bureau of Transportation and Safety
"Ibid
" Ibid
c
9
c
TAXICAB COMPANIES IN THE PITTSBURGH AREA1S
c
Cab Company # of Cabs in Fleet % Concentration Operating
(Year Franchised) Authority
Includes.. .
Yellow Cab (1946) 260 91% City of Pittsburgh,
and 10 mile outward
radius, including
Pittsburgh
International
Airport, and
T arenturn,
Brackenridge,
Fawn, Harrison,
Springdale
People's Cab (1951) ]2 4% City of Pittsburgh,
10 mile outward
radius
Eag]e Taxi (1981) 10 3% City of Pittsburgh
limits
Legg Transportation 3 1% Chalfant, Churchill,
(1995) East McKeesport,
East Pittsburgh,
Forest Hills,
Monroeville,
Oakmont, Pitcarin,
Plum, Turtle Creek,
Penn Hills
S&S Taxi (1982) 2 .6% McKeesport,
Duquesne,
Glassport,
Versailles, Clairton,
Elizabeth
" Ibid
c
10
c
ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF CONCENTRATION
Since taxicabs are a regulated industry, the PUC oversees rate applications and increase
requests upon existing rates. A taxicab's fare is based upon operating expenses of the
company and the need to derive a profit from the operations. The profit, also known as a
"rate of return", is taken into consideration when the company seeks PUC approval for a
rate increase.
Given the fact that direct taxicab competition is non-existent, either because of fleet size
or separate territories, the cab companies that do pass through the process of approval
essentially operate as an effective monopoly. As a result, fares do not vary as they would
under an open-entry system with multiple cab companies.
FARES FOR CAB COMPANIES IN THE PITTSBURGH AREAl6
c
COMPANY FLAG DROP ADDITIONAL WAIT FEE
MILE
Yellow Cab $ I. 80 for first 117 $.20 per additional $.20 per minute
mile or less 117 mile
People's Cab $1.40 for first 117 $.20 per additional $.20 per minute
mile or less 117 mile
Eagle Taxi $1.80 for first 117 $.20 per additional $.20 per minute
mile or less 117 mile
Legg Transportation $ 1.50 for first 1/8 N/A N/A
mile or less
S&S Taxi $ 1.50 for first 1/6 $.25 per additional $.25 per minute
mile or less 1/6 mile
The similarity in rates for each of these cab companies demonstrate the fact that there is
no real competitive effect on rates because regulations have kept the legal cab companies
out of direct competition. Since the process of entry puts the burden of proof on the
incoming cab company, any head-to-head competition would be discouraged because the
incumbent will prevent the competition under the proof of need criterion. In other words,
the established company will assume the responsibility for serving customers in an
"under-served" area before they would allow a new company to take on such an
opportunity.
The similarity is set apart when compared in relation to the reported revenue of these
companies. It goes without saying that the more cabs a company owns and the more
profitable routes the company possesses, the greater the profits. However, the disparity
should send a signal to public officials that regulations are skewing profits for large
incumbents at the expense of smaller incumbents in this industry and that arc-evaluation
of competition is required.
"Ibid
c
II
c
1999 REPORTED REVENUES FOR COMPANIES
IN THE PITTSBURGH AREAI7
COMPANY 1999 REPORTED REVENUE
Yellow Cab Comnanv $8,627,244
PeoDle's Cab $192,566
Eallle Taxi $0
Lellll TransDortation N/A
S&S Taxi $491,492
The assignment of cab companies into distinct territories in which those companies have
a market concentration has two revenue effects. One is a "non-effect" on fares in which
consumers in each area of operation pay the same amount they would pay in another area.
This situation would change if regulations promoted head-to-head competition by new
companies in areas of service rather than guaranteeing territories of monopoly control to
the established cab companies.
c
The other is an effect on the gross revenues of entrenched companies. Of the five cab
companies, the dominant carrier accumulated revenues nearly 17 times its next closest
legal competitor this year. In other words, the cab company with the longest history of
service, the most cabs, and the most profitable routes made the most money. Nothing is
shocking in this revelation other than the fact that protective regulations have not only
kept prospective entrepreneurs out of the cab business, those regulations serve to protect
the large companies at the expense of their closest legal competitors.
17 Ibid
c
12
c
THE INFORMAL ECONOMY
Since tariffs dictate the areas in which the cab companies operate, a double bind occurs:
incumbent cab companies take the most profitable routes at the expense of competition,
and the tariffs eliminate the need for responsive service at a competitive price.
The attention to profitable routes comes at the expense of the prospective fare that may
want to go a few blocks downtown, the broken-down motorist that needs help on Route
51, or the elderly citizen in the Hill District that wants to shop at the grocery store in
South Side and return home. With the exception of the first two cases, the last example is
increasingly served by a jitney driver.
The regulatory process also may hinder those who may want to explore new business
opportunities for transporting customers to and from certain events as well as routine
occasions.
Jitneys
The jitney driver is an illegal and often dangerous occupation. It is also the free-market
solution to a need for transportation service for certain citizens in certain communities.
At present, Pittsburgh reportedly has over 1,000 independent jitneys.
c
Encouraging the operation of jitneys in the legal cab market would bring legitimate
competition to the established companies, forcing established companies to improve
service and possibly lower their fares. It would also bring a revenue stream into the
public coffers that had been avoided by these underground operations. Given the fact that
even the most efficient of monopolies will become better through competition, this option
should be explored.
However, not all jitney drivers would seek to enter the legitimate market, nor would their
regular customers want them to. Entering the legal market may require significant
alterations in the way jitneys conduct business, including, but not limited to the purchase
of two-way radios, renting or leasing dispatch office space, or operating a 24 hour
service. This option may not be conducive for all cab companies because of the large up
front capital investment they require and the fares that would inevitably rise as costs were
passed on to the consumer.
Creating Niche Markets
Allowing more cab companies to compete does not end the regulatory and oversight
duties of the Public Utility Commission. All vehicles will still have to meet health and
safety standards. All drivers will have to possess insurance and a valid driver's license.
Perhaps all vehicles would have to be outfitted with a PUC identification number or a
complaint hotline.
c
I3
c
This deregulation could lead to the creation of new niche markets that could be served by
entrepreneurs. Perhaps a small company would utilize three or four minivans to pick up
senior citizens at the grocery store after they had completed a day of shopping and could
return the shoppers home. Or maybe a fleet of cars would exclusively serve sporting
events or entertainment venues. The possibilities of specialization are limitless, and are
made possible by simply changing the standard of competition that presently governs
taxicab service.
,
c
c
14
c
ACHIEVING COMPETITION IN CAB SERVICE
Pittsburgh and the communities in Allegheny County may not utilize taxicabs for a
multitude of reasons, some of which were discussed at the outset of this piece. The point
here is to suggest an alternative explanation, namely that regulations and the process of
competitive entry may be driving prospective competitors away from entering the cab
business. The legal obstacles have been supplemented by a rational marketplace
response of an illegal network of jitney drivers. . If regulations are relaxed and the process
is made neutral, Pittsburgh's taxicab industry may become an entrepreneurial success.
Needless to say, the time has come for a thorough review of the regulations pertaining to
the taxicab industry in this area. Change may come from the General Assembly to amend
sections of Title 66 that pertain to common carrier designations. Or there could be an
extension of the Medallion Act, which authorizes the sale of 1,600 taxi medallions in
Philadelphia, to Allegheny County. The legislative change is the necessary first step in
de-regulating the cab industry.
c
The Public Utility Commission itself needs to either build upon a legislative
recommendation or initiate changes to the regulations themselves. Commission action
needs to streamline taxicab operations and bring flexibility to the system. There are
essentially three actions for the commission to take:
I. Alter the process so that the proof of need requirement is no longer in place
2. End the restrictions on territorial assignment
3. End size restrictions (number of people in a vehicle under call or demand service)
and continuity of service stipulations
Regardless of the type of action that occurs, the end purpose is to make the process of
starting a cab company easier. Whether the prospective entrepreneur has two cars in a
fleet or two hundred, and as long as the cars pass inspections, conform to relevant health
and or safety regulations (similar to a restaurant), and have an identifiable PUC number
or a complaint hotline on the side of the car, the entrepreneur should be able to
commence operations. This change will lead to tremendous innovations in taxicab
service.
c
15
c
REFERENCES
Boroski, John W. and Gerard C.S. Mildner: "An Economic Analysis of Taxicab
Regulation in Portland, Oregon". Cascade Policy Institute, Policy Perspective 1007.
(www.cascadcpoJ icy.org).
Pennsylvania Code, Title 52, Chapter 29 "Motor Carriers of Passengers".
Pennsylvania Consolidated Statutes, Title 66. (1993 Edition). Commonwealth of
Pennsylvania, Legislative Reference Bureau, Harrisburg, PA.
Public Utility Commission, Bureau of Transportation and Safety, Selected Documents
and Tariffs on Motor Carriers in Allegheny County.
Lou Ransom "Taxicab Redlining a City Tradition". Pittsburgh Tribune-Review,
November 20,1999.
Sam Staley "How Cities Put the Breaks on Taxicabs". The Freeman, March, 1998.
c
c
16
o
o
c
c
c
c
1998
Public Convenience and Necessity
Hearing Report
for
Taxicab Medallions
to the
Police Commission
City and County of San Francisco
Submitted by
Captain John Ehrlich
Table of Contents
Introduction
History
Current Industry Operation
Theories of Regwation
Summary of Testimony
Analysis of Evidence
Alternatives
Recommendations
Introduction
The Police Commission is mandated to hold Public Convenience and Necessity (PC&N)
Hearings to determine if there are a sufficient number of permits or medallions (metal
plates that must be carried by all operating taxicabs) issued to assure adequate service to
the public. As the Hearing Officer for the Police Commission I have held PC&N hearings
on May 19, 1997 and April 27, 1998. I read the transcript of the November 14,1996
PC&N hearing held by Captain Dave Maron. As the Captain of Support Services I was a
member of the Mayor's Taxicab Task Force which met from August of 1997 until April
of 1998. The transcripts of the PC&N hearings, the final report of the Taxicab Task Force
c
c
r
'-
and all the written submissions are included with the exhibits. Given all the input I have
received I shall try and analyze the situation to give you the tools to make an informed
decision. I realize that most of the police Commissioners have not studied the industry so
I will cover some important background information.
First I will give a short history of the taxicab industry. Next I will cover the current
operation of the industry. Then I will explain theories of regulating taxicabs. The fourth
section will outline the major points raised bearing on issuing more medallion and I will
analyze economic and policy factors on the issues. Alternatives have been raised to
issuing more taxi medallions and these issues will be examined. Finally I will make my
recommendations.
History
The history of the taxicab industry starts with the hackney coaches of 16" century Europe
(Gilbert &. Samuels, 1982). Taxicab regulation started in 1635 in London when King
Charles I restricted horse drawn carriages because of congested streets (LaGasse 1986).
With the advent of the automobile at the turn of the 20'" century, the taxi industry
flourished. Taxi fleets owned by large organizations had high driver standards. John
Hertz owned both a cab manufacturing plant and several large fleets. He was the first to
paint taxis yellow and start telephone dispatch (Gilbert L Samuels, 1982). Even in these
eras regulations existed in some jurisdictions in the following areas: maximum fares,
posted fares or meters, insurance, drivers' licenses and limiting jitney operation (Kertz,
1986).
The start of the Great Depression led to large numbers of drivers entering the market.
New car dealers would let people rent unsold cars. Many people lost their jobs and used
their cars as taxis. The demand went down as the supply went up. This led to rates falling
to levels that could not produce a return on investment. The public called for more
regulation after severe problems with service surfaced: drivers with no insurance, fare
gouging, unsafe driving and unsafe vehicles. Laws were passed in most cities controlling
entry, fares, financial responsibility, condition of vehicles, and standards of service
(Gilbert & Samuels, 1982). Some laws dealt with livable wages, setting fares to provide
adequate return on investment and prohibiting leasing the cabs (Kertz, 1986).
The World War II years saw an expansion of the industry. After the war the economy
initially contracted. Returning servicemen got the first chance at buying new
automobiles. Many having no civilian jobs went into the taxi industry. Politicians could
not order a crack down without suffering at the ballot box. This led to another period of
disruption in the industry leading to more regulation. After the post-war regulation the
industry stayed the same through most of the 1970's.
In the late 1970's and early 1980's following airline and trucking deregulation a number
of cities and the state of Arizona deregulated the cab industry. In Arizona there were no
regulations except for insurance. Teal found that except for some contract service price
c
c
c
reductions there was no decrease in price or increase in service in Arizona (1986). The
results of deregulation were disappointing and many of the cities reregulated.
Existing alongside the official industry is a shadow system. Peter Suzuki did a study in
1995 of illegal taxicab operations in various cities in the United States. He found that
most of these operated by and for minorities. They might operate out of a gathering place
for members of that community like a barbershop, supermarket or via telephone. They
would handle runs the official companies would refuse either because they were in
undesirable areas or because the short hails were not profitable. With their lower costs
and standards the illegal. operators were able to operate and make a profit.
San Francisco
In San Francisco medallions were legally bought and sold. People could own more than
one permit. The industry was dominated by the Yellow Cab Company that had 503 of the
711 permits to operate taxis. Yellow Cab of San Francisco was owned by a holding
company, Yellow Cab of California, which was purchased in 1962 by the Westgate
Corporation ofC. Arnholt Smith. When in 1976 the Westgate Corporation went bankrupt
the taxicab industry in San Francisco was sent into a crisis as two thirds of the service
stopped. The Yellow Cab Cooperative of drivers purchased 185 of the permits and sold
the rest to various other organizations and people.
This crisis led to two competing propositions on the November 1978 ballot. Proposition
J, which was defeated, would have limited prices of medallions to $7500 unless the seller
had paid more. Prop. J also required new permits going to drivers. Proposition J was
defeated.
Proposition K passed and continues to control the industry. All medallion permits owners
had to turn them in to be replaced by permits owned by the City. The new permits could
be held the same way as the old permits except that they could not be bought, sold or
transferred. Corporate ownership of medallions would be allowed until more than 10% of
the ownership changed at which point the permits would be revoked. New permittees
could only hold one permit. They would have to drive the taxicabs at least four hours a
day for 75% of the days in the year oftbe cab's operation. People who held the old
permits would not have to comply with the driving requirement. The Police Commission
would issue more permits when the Public Convenience and Necessity (PC&N)
mandated it.
In 1968 there were 849 authorized medallions. In 1976 the number fell to 711 after the
former Yellow Cab Company was ordered to surrender 138 medallions by the bankruptcy
court. Fifty more medallions were issued in both 1984 and 1987 bringing the number to
811. In 1994 forty-five more medallions were issued and an additional five Ramp taxi
medallions. Ramp taxis are vehicles that have ramps that allow for wheelchair access. In
late 1996 the Police Commission created 100 more standard medallions and 20 mote
ramp taxi medallions. The decision was made just before the 1996 PC&N hearing in
c
c
c
November of 1996. It was decided to delay any decisions on more permits until the
per: 's had been issued.
I h. . PC&N hearing on May 19, 1997. Before I made recommendations to the Police
Commission Mayor Brown held a town hall meeting, which I attended, on taxis. As a
result he asked that no decision be made until the entire industry could be studied. He
created the Mayor's Taxicab Task Force that was actively chaired by Supervisor
Newsom. I was one of the members who met weekly from August 1997 until April 1998.
I held a PC&N hearing on April 27, 1998 that lasted from 6:30 P.M till almost midnight.
Over 60 people spoke at the hearing and there were over 90 written submissions on this
year's hearing.
Current Industry Operation
There are currently 981 medallions issued in San Francisco. There are 35 companies
ranging in size from 314 permits at Yellow Cab to several companies with one permit. A
company is also called a color scheme as all cabs are required to have distinctive
markings indicating their company. Each cab has a number on it that indicates the
number of the permit. Every company is required to have a 24-hour dispatch service.
There are ten dispatch services, half serving more than one company. Most of the latter
five dispatch companies are dominated by one color scheme. City Wide is an independent
dispatch service serving 14 companies and 149 medaltions.
All drivers must have a Driver Public Vehicle permit issued by the Taxi Detail of the
Police Department. The drivers must take an independent class and then pass a class
offered by the Police Department. Drivers are tested on geography, rules of the road, and
the regulations pertaining to the taxi industry. Drivers in San Francisco may not refuse a
fare unless the person is too intoxicated or too obnoxious.
While drivers were once employees of the companies most now have independent
contractor status. The companies have limited control over independent contractor-
drivers and the companies do not have to pay social security or benefits. Drivers lease the
cabs for period of time usually a shift, a week or a month depending on the terms of their
contract with the company. Drivers pay a "gate" fee ranging from $65 to $110 a shift
depending on the company and shift. The drivers pay for gas and keep all money they
collect during the shift.
Most medallion holders lease the operation of their medallions to companies or
individuals. The price is set on the open market and ranges from around $1800 a month
to above $3,000 a month. The leases vary greatly in the terms. A company will usually
provide the car, its maintenance, drivers, administration and the dispatch service. Several
individuals might lease directly from a medallion holder and split the driving between
them. They will pay some amount to associate with a color scheme and dispatch service.
A medallion holder who drives usually will get a higher quality vehicle and priority on
shift assignments. Some companies will not charge them as high a gate fee but will figure
c
c
c
that into the monthly lease fee. Medallion holders may also be allowed to own part of the
company.
In San Francisco many different government agencies affect the taxicab industry. The
Board of Supervisors sets fares and passes legislation controlling the industry within the
guidelines of the voter approved Charter Amendment of Proposition K. The Chief of
Police issues rules on the conduct of the industry, directs the Taxicab Detail and makes
decisions on permits except for the medallions. The Police Commission decides who
holds the medallions and how many there should be. Any permit decision may be
appealed to the Board of Appeals. The Airport Commission decides on rules for taxis at
the airport. The Bureau of Weights and Measures checks the taximeters. The Mayor
appoints the Board of Appeals, the Airport Commission and the Police Commission. The
California Public Utilities Commission has exclusive jurisdiction over the limousines that
are competition for the taxi industry.
The Taxicab Detail of the Police Department has the most day to day regulation of the
industry. They investigate complaints by the public, handle the administrative duties of
issuing the various permits, go out on the streets and check to see if the cabs are in fact
being operated correctly. They check that drivers have completed their waybills and that
vehicles are in good working order. They enforce traffic violations. They train other
police officers to enforce regulations.
Theories of Regulation
ODen Markets
In economic theory a free market is in general preferred over regulation. The law of
supply and demand will determine the cost and number of the goods and services in the
market. If the demand for a good or service increases the price will go up. If the price
goes up more people will be willing to supply the good or service at that higher price. In
a perfect market buyers have enough information to choose to buy goods and services
from those sellers who give them the best value. There should be government regulation
only when there are imperfections in the market (Frankena & Paulter, 1986). Those
imperfections might be the result of a monopoly, collusion, or the consumer not having
enough information (Gilbert, 1992).
Pumose of Rel!ulation
Gorman Gilbert is a University of North Carolina professor, the former Chairman of the
New York City Taxi and Limousine Commission, and the past President of a large Los
Angeles taxi company. In 1992 he talked about the goals of regulation. First, minimize
the public expense of determining the regulatory levels and the cost of enforcing the
regulations. Second, protect the customers from market imperfections so that they are
safe and not cheated. Third, improve the city's public image with special attention paid to
visitors. Next, give a fair rate of return to both drivers and companies or owners. Finally,
allow it to be a way for disadvantaged people to join the mainstream. He goes on to say
c
c
c
that good regulation enhances competition and encourages self-enforcement of good
service (1992).
Dr. Jeremy Toner writes about the purposes of regulation as being the "optimal economic
performance of the industry alongside public safely, consumer protection and congestion
management" (1993,p I). Public safety includes vehicle standards and driver licensing.
Congestion concerns might limit the number of taxis or manner of service at an airport.
Consumer protection looks at the relationship between a cab driver in a strong bargaining
position versus a consumer who might be exploited (Toner & Mackie 1992). There may
be several different price/service levels available in the open market. By controlling fares
and the numbers of taxis the government might obtain the optimal price/service level for
the public (Toner, 1993).
Tvpes of Service
Before looking at the particular issues it is important to realize that there are five different
kinds of taxi service: radio dispatch, cruising, taxi stands, airport, and contract service.
Contract service means an individual or company contracts with an individual or
corporate customer to provide a certain kind of service according to contract terms. This
might be a senior citizen center for shopping, a convention for rides to a party, an airport
for a franchise, or a government agency providing subsidized rides for the disabled. In
theory there is little need for the government to regulate this type of service because the
buyer is free to seek out another vendor. This service may still be regulated by other
codes governing the transportation such as school children.
Radio dispatch is where a customer telephones in a request for a taxicab to respond to a
particular place at a certain time and a taxicab is dispatched. What this means in San
Francisco is that a run or order will be broadcast either by voice or computer and a taxi
will volunteer for the order. Drivers are supposed to monitor the radio and handle an
assignment; they are not in practice made to respond. In theory this portion of the
industry does not need to be heavily regulated. A customer is free to bargain over the
phone and call another service. In New York City lightly regulated "For Hire Vehicles"
which can only respond to customers through dispatch exists along side heavily regulated
taxis with no dispatch capability (Schaller & Gorman, 1995).
Cruising or hailing means that a taxicab drives around looking for fares and a customer
hails them. In New York City they took radios out of cabs in the 1980's to increase
cruising (Schaller & Gilbert, 1995). Cruising taxis are most often in a strong bargaining
position as the customer has no idea how long it will be until another cab shows up
(Cairns, 1996). This leads to the regulation of cruising taxi fares (Amott, 1996).
A taxi stand is a location for cabs to park as they wait for customers. These are typically
hotels, auditoriums, train or bus stations, or anywhere a large number of people might
need taxi service. The general rule is the first one in line gets the first fare. A hotel
doorman may control which cab the customer gets in leaving them little choice. A
c
c
c
customer may not know that they can choose which cab to take. There are significant
constraints on making an informed choice, which leads to regulation.
Airports generally own the land around the airport and so can manage taxi service in
many ways. At SFO only San Francisco taxis can pick up fares though cabs from any
jurisdiction can drop off fares. Airport service can be identical to taxi stands in the lack of
consumer choice. Large airports need to be regulated because traffic flow problems
prohibit the time needed for customers to shop or bargain for fares (Lupro, 1993). When
a visitor arrives at an airport shelhe is in no position to bargain. There may be confusion
with currency, which leads to the newspaper stories about hundred-dollar overcharges on
rides in from airports.
Fare Reeulation
There is ample theory on whether fares should be regulated. In general it boils down to
whether a customer has enough information and opportunity to make a choice between
various competing cabs. Contract services are not regulated per se as taxicab regulation
as they are private contracts. The radio dispatch market is only partially regulated in
some places. In San Francisco taxi fares are regulated while limousine fares are not
regulated. As mentioned above with the FIFO systems at stands and airports and with the
nature of the cruising market consumer choices are restricted and so fares should be
regulated (Arnott, 1996, Cairns, 1996). Frankena and Paulter would only set maximum
fares and let the free market allow fares to go lower (1986). In San Francisco only
maximum fares are set and companies may file to operate at lower fares although no
company has done so.
Medallion Reeulation
The number of taxi permits allowed in a jurisdiction or entry regulation has been highly
debated. There are traditionally two ways the number of medallions has been set; Public
Convenience and Necessity or a formula. The first way is by Public Convenience and
Necessity (PC&N) hearings as in San Francisco. A public hearing is held on the issue of
whether more permits are needed to serve the public. The second way is through a
formula that takes various factors into account: population, airport activity, tourists and
conventions (laGasse, 1986).
Taxi industry consultant Dan Hara presented a formula to determine whether a city had
enough taxis at a taxi convention in 1997. He found that there were six key variables:
population, fare levels, commuters, proportion of low income people, number of frost
free days, and cost of running a private vehicle. The most interesting variable is that he
found that low- income people are more likely to use taxis, as they may not have other
options. Unfortunately hotel rooms are not part of his formula so it is of little use in San
Francisco.
In the late 1970's and early 1980's after the airline industry and trucking industry were
deregulated several cities tried deregulation of the taxi industry. This led to problems.
c
c
c
According to Cairns the number of no- shows to radio dispatch increased along with
complaints that drivers were refusing to convey fares (1996). He also said that
decentralized markets are difficult to monitor especially with tourists who are in a poor
position to bargain.
The taxi industry differs from other industries in that entry barriers are low for
individuals (Teal, 1993). To buy or lease a car does not require a lot of money. The skills
needed to be a driver are barely more than those needed for a driver's license. It does not
require organization or management skills to be an owner-driver. The FIFO system at
airports and stands means there is a guaranteed market (Teal, 1993). This led to the new
entrants providing more low quality service in places such as the airport that didn't need
more service. In order to achieve full public service, certain segments of the market may
have to subsidize other market segments (Toner, 1993). Radio dispatch services require
substantial costs for office staff, equipment, and marketing (Hackner & Nyberg, 1995).
Firms may have to be a certain size to be able to cover the radio dispatch area (Teal &
Berglund, 1987). Teal argues that entry policies should aim at increasing the number of
24-hour, full-service organizations to compete on price and service as opposed to two
independent owner-drivers sitting in line at an airport (J 993).
Driver Oualitv
A study of New York City cab drivers citations found an inverse correlation between the
number of citations and the years of experience Schaller & Gorman, 1995). Hara found a
direct relationship between driver quality and driver income (1995). Low wages lead to
higher turnover lead to bad service as measured by complaints (Schaller & Gorman,
1996b). The barriers to be a taxi driver are very low so there is a ready pool of
replacements (Teal, 1993). The method of employment of drivers from employee to
independent contractor has caused drivers to lose benefits and their overall income to go
down (Schaller & Gorman, 1996a). There is a benefit to the consumer to have
experienced taxi drivers.
Summary of Testimony
In Favor
Representatives from the senior and disabled community spoke eloquently about trying to
get cabs to respond. They are dependent on taxi service, as they may be unable to ride the
MUNI or drive a car due to their physical condition. They said that getting rides from
their homes could be difficult. Getting taxis to take them home could be a nightmare.
Several seniors related stories <if waiting at doctor's offices for hours painting for a ride.
Similarly getting rides back home from the market could be an exhausting experience.
They felt that drivers knew that certain locations like markets would be a short ride for a
small fare. Drivers would avoid these places in favor of the airport or hotels where the
likelihood of a big fare was greater. Locations where seniors were known to live were
sometimes ignored again because of the probability of a short trip.
c
c
c
Hotel managers and doormen said that their guests' main complaint was that they could
not get a taxi. The problem was particularly severe going out to dinner or wanting to
return from dinner. They noticed the problem from the late afternoon until the early
evening. Some hotels had resorted to contracting with limousine services in order to meet
their guests' needs. They said that if taxi service were available they would drop the cost
of the limousine contracts. Convention managers have indicated that the lack of taxi
service will diminish the chance of conventions returning.
Restauranteurs spoke about the lack of service. They talked about the difficulty
customers had getting a taxi to take them from a bar or restaurant. Managers said they
made calls and no cab would show up. Service was worse for restaurants or bars located
away from the downtown area. Employees said they sometimes had trouble getting taxis
home after work. The owners felt that the unavailability of taxi service caused their
business to drop.
Community groups from the neighborhoods said that service was slow and sporadic in
the residential neighborhoods away from the downtown. The low-income neighborhoods
said that they had a hard time getting taxis to take them there much less pick them up
from their homes. There was a general feeling that the airport and the downtown had too
many taxis while the neighborhoods were ignored. They felt that drivers would rather
wait for hours at the airport than serve the neighborhoods. Suggestions were made to
discourage taxis from serving the airport.
The managers of some of the largest taxicab companies said that they thought there was a
need for more taxis. They said that they had drivers waiting to work shifts. They said they
were overwhelmed with the number of telephone calls into their dispatch centers. They
said that half of the taxicabs are providing the vast majority of the radio dispatch service.
Whitehurst Campaigns submitted a study in May of 1997 comparing San Francisco to
eight other major cities. It compared the ratios of taxis to residents where San Francisco
ranked next to last and to overnight visitors where San Francisco ranked last. It also
looked at commuters and lifestyle and concluded that 500 more taxis would be needed. In
December of 1997 the Golden Gate Restaurant Association evaluated the Whitehurst
report and other factors and asked for 600 more taxis. Paul Gillespie compared San
Francisco to 36 other cities and ranked San Francisco 10'" in the ratio of cabs to the
population.
A2ainst more full-time cabs
The United Taxi Workers (UTW), the drivers' union, presented a study. The study looked
at the same ratios as the above studies but compared them to West Coast cities. That
study showed that San Francisco had the highest ratios of taxicabs.
People speaking against more medallions were either taxi drivers or medallion holders or
both. They had several main arguments; inefficient dispatch, peak time need, and low
drivers' wages.
c
c
c
Many drivers criticized the dispatch system. Companies have little incentive to invest in
dispatch system because once the drivers have paid the gate fees and left for their shift
the companies make the same amount of money whether it is a busy or slow night. They
also said that dispatchers had to be tipped or they would not get the good runs. Not
enough dispatchers or call takers are hired. Some customers call several dispatch systems
and then take the first cab that shows up cleaving several drivers with a wasted trip. They
also complained about no-goes,where customers call, but then are not there when the cab
arrives. Many drivers felt that a centralized dispatch system would solve most of the
problems.
Most drivers agreed that there were not enough taxis during the peak times but said that
there were more than enough during other times. The drivers called for peak time permits
to cover the rise in demand in the afternoon rush hour early evening period weekdays and
during Friday and Saturday night. They said that to base the number of permits on the
peak time demand was false. They said that restaurants and hotels fill up sometimes but
staff isn't hired for just for those periods.
Drivers were mainly concerned that their income would fall 30% if the number of
medallions were increased 30%. They said that the gate fees have gone from around $65
in 1990 to around $95 in 1998. Upward costs and stagnant income have squeezed their
standard ofIiving. They are required to pay gate fees for shifts where they may not break
even. They pointed with pride to the good reputation of San Francisco cab drivers. If
more medallions are added then the good drivers will have to leave the industry to be
replaced by lower wage drivers. Those drivers will not have the experience or
knowledge. The service level will fall, as there are more poor drivers.
Drivers also complained about less qualified drivers hanging out at the airport or going
out to the airport without a fare to get the fare back. There were suggestions that this be
banned.
Many complaints were voiced about illegal taxis and limousines. They felt that the
Taxicab Detail should crack down on them. They cited various places where limousines
poached on their customers.
Many drivers and medallion holders were concerned about the effects of a sudden 30%
increase in medallions. Many called for a partial increase followed by more study. There
was a fear that if the most skilled drivers left for other jobs because of plummeting
income they would not return.
Taxi Detail Studies
The Taxi Detail conducted three surveys bearing on taxi availability. The first survey was
on dispatch systems. The second survey looked at the taxi stands at hotels and the third
survey examined the airport. All three surveys covered roughly the same three week
period between March II, 1998 and April 3, 1998.
c
c
c
For the dispatch study the Taxi Detail made 154 calls to dispatch systems requesting a
cab. The dispatch systems were called in rough proportion to the number of cabs in their
system. The overall chance ofa taxi arriving after' telephone call was under 57%.
Betweep 8 P.M. and lOAM. there was above a 70% chance of the taxi arriving. Between
10 A.M. and 4 P.M. a cab would show up on between 52% and 64% of the runs. Between
4 P.M. and 8 P.M. a cab would arrive around 30% of the time. The arrivals per days of
the week varied between 38% on a Thursday and 69% on a Friday. The average arrival
time was 13 minutes.
The hotel taxi stand survey looked at the number of waiting cabs versus the number of
waiting patrons. It showed that cabs were readily available for patrons between 6 AM.
and Noon. Between 4 P.M. and 10 P.M. hotel patrons were waiting for cabs. This
essentially validated what the hotel people had said during testimony.
The study of the airport looked at how many cabs were staged at the airport and how
many cabs departed with fares from the airport and at what hours and days of the week.
The are a total of2l2 spaces for taxicabs to wait at the airport. The Ground
Transportation Unit of the Police Department check the staging area 84 times and at no
time found the lots full and found the lots empty on three occasions all at 4 P.M. on
weekdays. The airport averaged 157 cabs an hour leaving with fares. The busiest times
were weekdays 2 P.M. to 10 P.M. and Sunday from 2 P.M. to Midnight. The idea that
taxicabs would go out to the airport and sit for hours is largely untrue between 8AM. and
Midnight a cab going to the airport would not wait two hours and there were many hours
that average over 300 trips. In reviewing the Monthly Taxicab Pick-ups since April of
1996 there is an increasing number trips from the airport. The average looks to be
increasing from the mid 80,000 level in 1996 to the low 90,000 level in the first half of
1997 to the upper 90,000 level.
Analysis of the Evidence
Almost all groups want more taxicabs including some of the taxi drivers. The general
public will not participate in hearings such as these as they have a vague generalized
interest. The people who have a large economic stake are likely to be over-represented.
At these hearings I saw largely the same group of200 people most of who were taxi
drivers. The hotel, restaurant, taxicab company and medallion holders were well
represented.
The drivers have good reason to be concerned. Driving a taxicab is one of the most
dangerous professions. They have seen their real wages fall over the last few years while
other segments of the economy have progressed. As San Francisco is a port of entry,
immigrants continually arrive from countries with lower wages. The drivers bargaining
power is limited by the availability of unskilled labor to get into their profession. Taxicab
drivers do effect a visitor's view of the City. Studies have shown that full time
experienced drivers have fewer accidents and complaints and generally give better
servIce.
c
c
c
There have been studies of the effects of deregulation on taxicabs. Deregulation put no
limit on the number of taxicabs operating in a jurisdiction which led to sudden increases
in the number of cabs operating. Paul Dempsey wrote about an average increase of 23%
in deregulated cities. The effects of deregulation were falling levels of service, increasing
complaints about taxi drivers, reports of fighting over fares and little increase in service
to those most needing it. The new workers did not have the skills to serve the
neighborhoods or disadvantaged and some of the skilled drivers left the profession to find
work that would pay better.
The driver's fear of a 30% drop in income is overstated. Everyone agrees that during peak
times there is more than enough business. Even with a 30% increase their income during
peak hours would remain the same. During their non-peak hours their income might drop.
The drivers assume that the demand for taxis is fixed. Economists who have studied the
industry share that assumption. I believe that is incorrect for San Francisco.
Everyone agrees that San Francisco is unique. This City has a combination of
characteristics that do not appear other places. The City is one of the most densely
populated in both people and vehicles in the United States. Finding places to park cars is
not only a science but also an art. This would stimulate demand for taxis. It has a mass
transit system that despite its faults carries a large number of people to all areas of the
City. Vast numbers of commuters use mass transit which might again stimulate the use of
taxis from terminals to job sites. Large numbers of people come into the City to shop, eat,
attend cultural events, and nightclubs. These people form a natural market for taxis. San
Francisco is a top destination for tourists from around the world. They are also heavy
users of taxis. That is why studies showing what other cities do and their ratios may not
be applicable here.
I believe that if number of taxis is increased the demand will also increase. In San
Francisco there are tremendous disincentives to drive. The traffic is bad particularly in
the downtown area. Parking can be expensive and time consuming. It is difficult to find
convenient parking in many places in San Francisco outside the downtown. San
Francisco has many residents whom because of difficulty parking by their home are
discouraged from going out. One bad experience in finding a taxicab to take a person
home will outweigh many good experiences. The taxicab industry has not attempted to
market itself. There is very little advertising. This is a sign that the demand has yet to be
reached. Once the public gets the idea that taxi transportation can be relied upon demand
should jump.
Driver's complaints about the unjustified rise in the gates are valid. The rise in gate fees
can be directly tied to the taxi company competition for medallions. Taxi companies
profit by the difference in the marginal cost of running an additional medallion versus the
gate fees they collect. There are economies of scale to the companies of spreading their
fixed costs over more medallions. The medallion holders have expressed some feelings
that their lease rates should not be controlled. The medallions have value only because
the City has restricted the number of medallions and made them a scarce commodity. The
City has yet to restrict the number of restaurant permits and so while the restaurants
c
businesses may be bought or leased the permits themselves are not traded. The Task
Force has recommended lease controls for the Board of Supervisors to implement. This
will help restrict future gate increases.
Driver's complaints about limousines taking fares from taxis are not significant. It is a
sign that if the demand is there entrepreneurs will find a way to fill the need. If taxis were
plentiful then the problem would largely disappear. Taxis are well marked and obviously
available to transport customers. Limousines are generally thought to be already in use. It
is much easier for a consumer to spot and take a taxi.
Alternatives
Centralized Dispatch
c
A continuing subcommittee of the Taxicab Task Force is currently investigating this.
There are several advantages to this. There would be one number for consumers to
remember. The whole fleet could be efficiently used. Customers would not have the
frustrating experience of calling one company for a cab only to see an available taxi from
another service drive past. Waiting time could drop there would be more potential
customers for a cab driver who did want to service a neighborhood. Customers with
special need could draw on the whole fleet. A customer who wanted a driver who spoke
their language would have more drivers to draw upon. All of the above would stimulate
demand. .
There are disadvantages as well. There would be less differentiation between companies.
While a customer could specify a company how many would take the first available taxi.
This trend would lessen the company's incentives to maintain and improve their fleet.
Who would run the dispatch center? Who would staff it? Who would control it? Who
would pay for it? With the current system if a dispatch system went down there are nine
other dispatch systems available. Would all cabs have to use it? What rules would they
have to follow? It will take a long time to work out all the problems.
Aimort
c
Several different groups have complained about the service the airport receives. They feel
that the airport drains the City and that untrained drivers gravitate there. The Taxicl!b
Detail study of the airport indicates that this is not the case for large periods of time. The
demand for taxis at the airport is rising. This is before the new terminal opens. The study
shows that there are times when the airport is underserved. The airport has had problems
with drivers refusing to take passengers to places nearby the airport because the fare will
not be high enough for the driver. Many airports have taxis that are exclusively run to
take passengers from the airport. This would allow the airport to more closely supervise
the operation of the taxicabs and the drivers. As the airport expands in the near future
there are likely to be times when there will be surges of demand as more flights come in
to new gates. Each surge in demand will adversely effect the service in the City. The
current logistics of issuing more medallions is time consuming.
,,-...
\....-
c
r
'-
There are several models that could be followed if it was decided to have a separate
taxicab system for the airport. The first model would offer the current medallion holders
the chance to exchange their current medallion for airport medallions. It could be done by
seniority. The system would otherwise stay the same. A second model could have
companies bid for the opportunity to run an exclusive franchise. Each time the contract
came up for renewal it would go up for bid. It could be a non-exclusive franchise where
companies would have to meet specifications to operate at the airport similar to what now
happens with shuttle vans. They could be required to pay benefits to drivers. These
altematives would offer the airport more flexibility in meeting uncertain conditions in the
foreseeable future.
Peak Time Permits
The Mayors Taxicab Task Force recommended peak time permits. This is advocated
most strongly by drivers and medallion holders but has been endorsed by other groups as
well. The idea is that demand goes up at certain times on certain days. Permits should be
issued which would meet this need. Taxi companies maximize their profits by collecting
as many gate fees as possible. Drivers say that the companies will give them a couple
good shifts along with a couple bad shifts where it is difficult to make any money after
paying gates and gas. If more medallions are issued there will be more competition
during off-hours. Companies usually split the peak period between the day and swing
watch.
The peak demand period covers the afternoon rush hour on weekdays. Tourists and
conventioneers want to get back to their hotel. Workers want to get home and people
want to go out to dinner. This is the time when vehicles are turned over to a new shift. At
the time the demand goes up the actual supply goes down. In addition because of the
traffic congestion the taxis can't serve the same number of customers because each trip
takes longer.
The Taxi Detail studies confirm peak demand. The hotel taxi stand survey showed a peak
time of 4 P.M. to 10 P.M. The Airport survey showed an increase in demand from 2 P.M.
to 10 P.M. on weekdays and 2 P.M. to Midnight on Sunday. The dispatch survey showed
higher demand from demand starting at 10 A.M. and peaking from 4 P.M. to 8 P.M. The
surveys were not targeted to determine peak time issues and so do not have all the issues
covered.
There are many questions that remain to be answered. How would peak time permits be
regulated? What days of the week would they function and during what hours? Who
would decide when a special event warranted the mobilization of those medallions
outside their normal hours? Would they be economically feasible? How would the rules
on the age of the vehicles apply?
Ramo Taxis
The disabled community has not been pleased with the service provided by the ramp
taxis. They still have long waits for a ramp taxi to respond. While the new Chief's Rules
can handle some of these issues the demand is larger than expected. The Ramp Taxis can
seat four passengers beside the wheelchair. So they can provide regular service as well.
c
Recommendations
The most reliable instruments on which to base the recommendations are the Taxi Detail
Studies. They are objective and relevant. I agree with the Mayor's Taxicab Task Force.
Three hundred to four hundred more medallions should be issued. The types of
medallions, and the issuance schedule, will be determined by appropriate decision
makers.
peN EXHffiIT LIST
Exhibits # I thru 3 (1996 Submissions)
. Letter from Paratransit Broker
. Letter from Michael Hutton
. Letter Rom Faribors Golshan
c
Exhibit #4 - Letter &am John A Marks
Exhibit #5 - Report from Strategy Campaigns (Whitehurst Group)
Exhibit #6 - 1997 Letters (in favor for additional taxis]
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
C .
.
John Satre - SF Marriott Fisherman's Wharf
Cecilia Metz - Golden Gate Restaurant Association
James Chappell - SF Planning and Urban Research Association
Mark Mcleod - Enrico's Restaurant
Marsha Garland - North Beach Chamber of Commerce
AlIesandro Baccari - Fishermans Wharf Merchants Association
Thomas W. Creedon - SF Restaurant Industry
Jean H. Gabriel
Lara Karakasevic - San Remo Hotel
Jonathan Gould - Holiday Inn Select Union Square
Wolfgang Hultner - Mandarin Oriental
Eloise Walton - Rosa Parks Apartment
Carolyn Baulsier - North Beach Neighbors
Chris Stevri - Stanford Court Hotel-Renaissance
Kathleen Harrington - Harrington's Bar & Grill
Kathleen Mayeda - SF Senior Center
John Simonich - Holiday Inn
Harris Chan - Sheratons @ Fisherman's Wharf
Obaid Afredi - Ana Hotel San Francisco
Leonard Brant
c . Mikhail Shubov
. Charles Speidel
. Sergio Alvarez - Andale Taqueria
. Mark J. Romeo - North Beach Chamber of Commerce
. J.A. Lew - Bret Harte & S.F. S1. Neighborhood Association
. Ken Cleaveland - Bldg. Owners & Mgras Association of S.F.
. Jonathan Gould - Holiday Inn Select Union Union
. Thomas B. Mysknowski . Holiday Inn Golden Gateway
. Eloise Walton - Rosa Parks Apartment
. Jean H. Gabriel - Cafe de la Presse-Restaurant International
. Jason Mohney - Deja Vu Centerfolds
. August J.P. Longo
. Affordable Housing Alliance
. Burne Roche - Roaring 20's Love Boutique
. Kevin Piediscalzi - Lesbian & Gay Democratic Club
. Alessandro Baccari - Fisherman's Wharf Merchants Association
. Lu Van Chan - S.A.W. Entertainment Limited
. John Rincione - Garden of Eden
. John Liebenguth - Condor
. Danielle Ortega
. Steve Ecks - Palladium Dance Club
. Steve Kass - Casbah Cabaret
. Dean Alaric Von Boerner
C . John M. Hutar - Hotel Nikko S.F.
. John M Hutar - Hotel Nikko
. Robert Migdal
. Wondewossen Mefbib
Exhibit #7-A - 1997 Letters (Opposed to additional taxis)
. Jerome Higgins
. Felix Jerry Droz
. Russell W. Williams
. Robert Henriquez
. Wayne L Swisher
. Brian Hoyt
. Christopher Allen Paul Fulkerson
. Adam
. Lawrence J. Kelley
. Lawrence J. Kelley
. Vladimir Zhubokrug
. Anonymous Report
. James Maddox
. Olivio Dallagiacoma
. Umar Randhawa
C . Anonymous
c . Richard Koehlz
. Mark Gruberg
. Carlene Jensen
. Charles Speidel
. John D. Kiernan
. Rich Powell
. Ed. Burke
. Keith Raskin
Exhibit #8 1998 Letters in favor of additional taxis)
c
. Kathleen Harrington - Golden Gate Restaurant Association
. A, Rahman
. John M. Hutar - Hotel Nikko
. John A Marks - S.F. Convention & Visitors Bureau
. Walter B. Derby
. Anonymous
. Abdul Rahman
. Amao Seknov
. Emad Shehdeh
. RAJ Sanwal
. Jamal Hassoun
. John A. Marks
. Ron Wolter
. Ramona Albright
. Julie Van Dam
. Olivo Dallagiacoma
. Helen Hobbs - Golden Gate Restaurant Association
. Ramona Albright - Twin Peaks Council
. James Nakamura
. William D. Peck
. Robert F. Begley
. Nathan Dwiri
Exhibit #9 1998 Letters (Opposed to additional taxis)
. Thomas Ferris
. Bernard Dethiers
. Mike Iverson
. The Night Cabbie
. David Fine
. Robert Allen
. Yellow Cab #7195
. Thomas Stanghilleni
C . Russell Williams
. Anonymous
c
c
c
. David A Benfell
. Julian M Homwitz
. Alod W. Riggs
. Carl MacMurdo
. Brad Newsham
. Anonymous Cab Driver
. Carl MacMurdo
. Charles Korbel
. Matthew Jeziorski
. Marian L. Zaouk
. Howard A Williams
. Joseph Fleischman
. Barry Taranto
. Lovie Abdelia
. Joe Mirabile
. Al Hall
. Ruagh Graffis
. MID
. Peter H.G. Witt
. ean-Michael Normand
. Matthew Teziorski
. Marian L. Zauve
. Marian L. Zauve
. Rolph Jacobson
. Charles Korbel
. Lawrence I. Kelley
. Joe Mirabile
. Dennis J Korkos
. Charles Wadebaxter
. Keith Raskin
. Brently Pusser
. Ronald L Fishman
Exhibit #10 Golden Gate Restaurant Association Membership Survey of San Francisco's
Taxi Service
Exhibit #11 Petition for More Taxicabs 1997
Exhibit #12 Petition for More Taxicabs...continues 1997
Exhibit #13 Signatures for More Taxicabs 1998
Exhibit # 14 Continuation of More Signatures 1998
Exhibit # 15 Letter from Ron W olter- Veterans Cab 1997
c
c
c
Exhibit #16 Letter from the Golden Gate Association 1998, Helen Hobbs, Chair, Public
Affairs Committee
Exhibit #17 Letter &om United Taxicab Workers 1998
Exhibit #18 Signatures to Hon. Supervisor Gavin Newsom
Exhibit #19 San Francisco Taxi Permitholders and Drivers Association, Inc. (K Owners'
Association) Joseph Fleischman
Exhibit #20 Mayor's Taxi Task Force Final Report April 1998
Exhibit #21 Letter from Brian A. Foster June 1998
Exhibit #22 1996 Hearing transcript
Exhibit #23 1997 Hearing transcript
Exhibit #24 1998 Hearing transcript
Exhibit #25 Letter from Paratransit broker July 1998
Exhibit #26 Letter from MUNI Railway July 1998
Exhibit #27 Taxicab Detail PCN Survey Report
o
1
o
o
I Tnl Online
C Reforming Taxicab Regulations: Focus on the Passenger
Taxicabs are an oft-forgotten part of the Los Angeles transportation
infrastructure. But they do provide important services to many pf the
region's visitors, business travelers and seniors. As L.A. City Councilman
Rudy Svorinich points out here, their importance will only grow when the
Staples Center opens and the DNC arrives. Combine that with the
impending expiration of all taxicab franchises on the same day, and, as
Rudy S1'or;nich
Svorinich argues, the time is ripe jor rethinking taxi regulation in L.A. for
the first time in over two decades.
By Rudy Svorinich, Jr. Los Angeles City Councilman Member, Transportation
Committee
The City of Los Angeles is at a crossroads in its regulation of taxicabs. For the first time
since the present regulatory structure was enacted in the 1970s, all of the City's taxicab
franchises will end on the same day. The City thus has its first opportunity to improve
taxicab service through a complete overhaul of its regulations.
c
Couple this opportunity with the coming series of important events in our city, including
the opening of the Staples Center, the National League of Cities convention and the
Democratic National Convention, and the importance of ensuring the quality of taxicab
service increases further.
Clearly, several ofL.A.'s licensed taxicab companies already run fine operations, providing
good service to the taxi-riding public. On the other hand, we have other licensed companies
whose service needs improvement. We should overhaul taxicab regulations to reward well-
managed companies by encouraging their continued good performance, while implementing
measures which will either bring poor performers up to standard or allow the City to look to
other providers.
To begin its regulatory overhaul, the City hired a consulting firm to survey taxicab regulations
nationwide to see which regulatory schemes were working and which were not. Department of
Transportation staff and the consultants have prepared proposals for public discussion and
presentation to the Taxicab Commission.
Certainly, many groups have a vested interest in the outcome of these discussions, including, of
course, the taxicab companies themselves, their drivers and their regulators. And, although these
constituents are represented in discussions of proposed regulations, the most important
constituent--the riding public--may not be represented at all.
c
The question thus arises, how do we ensure that a discussion among all but one of the important
constituents places the interests of the missing constituent above the interests of those present?
There can be only one obvious answer: by promoting competition among the licensed taxicab
companies. Let Customers Choose Their Taxicab Company
c
c
c
The concept of competition can be used to support more than one side of an argument.
However, competition cannot mean denying customers the right to choose the licensed taxicab
company that best serves their needs. No customer should be forced to take a particular taxicab
simply because that taxicab was the next in line waiting for a passenger.
The vast majority of passengers, from the average L.A. resident who uses taxicabs infrequently
to the traveler from out of town who uses taxicabs for several days then leaves the City, do not
have the means to distinguish between taxicab operators. However, in certain situations, there
are surrogates who stand in the place of such passengers to ensure quality.
Hotels, private bus and train terminals, and other venues with a high number of taxicab trips
know that the quality of taxicab service can reflect positively or negatively on their businesses.
Such businesses must retain the right to select among taxicab companies the operator most
responsive to their needs.
The altemative--forcing businesses to use whatever taxicab is next in line--is simply a welfare
program for abusive, dishonest or incompetent drivers. Because such an idea is anti-
competitive, it will discouragesometimes-costly improvements in quality, rather than encourage
them. With a competitive scheme in place, companies that are left without business will be
forced to improve their service in order to attract customers.
c
c
c
Give Our Vaney Residents A Choice
Competition must be brought to the San Fernando Valley. At the
present time, the Valley's 1.5 million residents are served by 200
taxicabs from two companies. The rest of the City, with approximately
2 million residents is served by more than 1,800 taxicabs from eight
companies.
The City is doing the Valley a disservice by keeping the doors closed
to the rest of the City's licensed taxicabs. More competition will bring
improved service to the Valley, which desperately needs better taxicab
service.
Some have said that opening the door between the Valley and the rest
of the City will result in a flight of taxicabs out of the Valley. I do not
believe this is so. In their efforts to earn a living, taxicab drivers will
go where the passengers are, and the Valley can support more than the
200 taxis licensed there.
Question Assumptions Made Over Twenty Years Ago
Perhaps the single biggest opportunity afforded us during this period is
the opportunity to take a zero-based look at all taxicab regulations. The
City should not squander this opportunity.
For example, under the current regulatory scheme, the City is divided
into five service areas, A through E, with area A covering the Valley,
area B, the Westside, area C, Hollywood and the Central City, area D,
South Central Los Angeles, and area E, Harbor City, Wilmington and
San Pedro. It would appear that the lines drawn some 25 years ago are
arbitrary.
"Competition by
unregulated
taxicabs ...
undercuts the
entire industry
and puts the
public at risk.
Enforcement
against bandits
and poachers
must be
stepped up if we
are to improve
overall service,
safeguard the
public from
uninsured
drivers and
those with
criminal
backgrounds,
and ensure that
licensed
taxicabs enjoy
the benefit of
their
franchises."
A quality analysis should call into question these lines. For instance, the dividing line between
areas B' and C runs for the most part down La Cienega Boulevard. This division, it would
appear, runs counter to taxicab trip patterns and general traffic flows in Los Angeles west of
downtown, which run East-West across La Cienega, not North-South.
We should question whether this dividing line and others result in inefficiency in the form
ofwasted time, fuel and unnecessary enforcement, and whether the benefits of having these lines
drawn as they are outweigh their costs.
C Clean Up The Bandits
Competition by unregulated taxicabs, not forced to maintain City
standards, undercuts the entire industry and puts the public at risk.
Enforcement against bandits and poachers must be stepped up if we
are to improve overall service, safeguard the public from uninsured
drivers and those with criminal backgrounds, and ensure that
licensed taxicabs enjoy the benefit of their franchises.
Other cities similar to Los Angeles, including San Francisco, have
accomplished this task. Bandit taxicabs are not a significant problem
in those cities. L.A. should be no different. The solution to this
problem is more a matter of will and commitment than one of
resources.
Give The Drivers A Raise
c
Finally, although much lip service is paid to the correctly held belief
that taxicab service quality is a very important to the City's image--
and therefore the City's taxicab drivers must be courteous, well-
informed and professional--the City's taxicab drivers have not been
treated by the City as such. In fact, we have treated our taxicab
drivers poorly.
City goverrunent has rejected repeated requests by taxicab drivers
and companies to increase taxicab rates. The last rate increase took
place in 1986. Since that time, according to the Consumer Price
Index, the cost ofliving has increased by 54%.
"City government
has
rejected...requests
to increase
taxicab rates. The
last rate Increase
took place in
1986. Since that
tlme...the cost of
living has
increased by 54%.
For anyone to
expect taxicab
drivers to prOVide
premium ...
service when they
have not had a
raise
In 13 years is
unreasorrable...
Our taxicab
drivers deserve
an
overdue raise."
For anyone to expect taxicab drivers to provide premium level service when they have not had a
raise in 13 years is unreasonable to say the least. Our taxicab drivers deserve an overdue raise.
The City must use the opportunity to revise L.A.'s taxicab regulations to eliminate outdated,
inefficient and anti-competitive rules and enact rules containing incentives to companies to
provide superior service. Should we fail to seize this unique opportunity for real change, we will
be doing the City a terrible disservice.
Current Issue I Subscribe I Free Issue I News bv Emaill Web Archive I Feedback I Submit News I Mastbead
CODVTight 1998 Metro Investment Report
httD:llwww.ablinc.net/tDrl
editor@,ablinc.net
c
David Abel, Publisher
ABL, Inc.
811 West Seventh Street, Suite 900
c
Los Angeles, CA 90017
Telephone (213) 629-9019
Facsimile (213) 623-9207
c
c
o
1
o
o
c
Taxi Regulation in Wisconsin-Law and Policy
Presentation to the Madison Parking and Transit Commission
Peter Carstensen
Professor of Law
University of Wisconsin Law School
3 April 2000
The following outline presents the basic points that I wish to make in discussing the
question of taxi regulation with the subcommittee. I have not, except for key state
statutes and one state Supreme Court decision, cited to specific legal materials. If the
subcommittee would find it helpful, I can provide such citations.
I. Basic Polley: Competition is socially and economically desirable
A. Benefits of competition
c
o 1. In general, competition is both economically and socially desirable. It adjusts
the supply of services to the demand. It allows entry and exit from the market
without cumbersome and costly hearings. It encourages innovation and
experimentation that leads to new services and new ways of providing existing
services. Repeated experience in a wide range of businesses shows that
removing the regulatory barriers to entry and competition has served the public
well.
o 2. A central tenant in this nation is a commitment to the maximum freedom of
opportunity. The right to decide what business or profession to pursue is a
central element of our democracy and a core value in preserving and promoting
our social order. As a nation, we have demanded as much freedom of
opportunity as is possible. Individuals flourish when they have the opportunity to
decide what they want to do without having to overcome unnecessary
government regulation. As much as possible it is important to expand the scope
of economic activity where such freedom is possible.
o 3. The taxi business is particularly unsuited for entry regulation or control over
basic competition. It involves relatively modest costs; there are few, if any
economies of scale or scope beyond a very modest level. Hence, this business
has none of the economic characteristics associated with the monopoly or other
market failures usually used to justify regulation on entry or competition exists.
o 4. There are some specific needs that require government oversight: safety,
security, full disclosure of the service being offered including price, and
accountability for any failure to satisfy the foregoing requirements.
o 5. Experience with open entry in other cities has produced the expected results:
more services, even some price competition. It has also proven to be an
important route for individuals seeking to advance themselves economically.
Moreover, legitimate public interest concerns have been adequately protected.
c
B. Excessive fears of competition
c
· 1. Those who exist under the shelter of entry regulation are likely to claim that
serious problems will result if more competition is allowed. Their economic self-
interest may motivate in part these claims, but there is also an understandable
fear of the unknown.
. 2. In actual experience, most fears of competition prove groundless. Entry does
not occur as quickly or massively as opponents claim. New entrants often face
significant hurdles in establishing their own creditability in the market especially if
the incumbent firms have provided high quality, reliable service.
. 3. Multi-car incumbents have a number of advantages over either single car
operators or even new, multi-car operations. Many customers are repeat users
and will reward high quality service and reliability including service at off-hours.
This is also true of thOse who are in a position to recommend choice of service
such as hotels, restaurants and bars.
. 4. The major competitive risk to established firms comes when those firms have
excessive prices or fail to provide good service. The market is in general a
better means to discipline such failures than is any administrative agency
procedure.
. 5. If specific problems arise for which the market is not a workable source of
discipline, the law can respond with focused changes.
c
C. Not all regulation is impermissible-focus on public safety and other authorized areas
of legitimate concem
It is clear that there are important roles for regulation in the field of taxi service.
Moreover, to some degree any such regulation will increase the costs of entry and
competing in the market. However, all such constraints need to be focused on legitimate
goals: public safety. insurance, as well as the definition of the territory, hours, and price
of service. Moreover, these are the only goals that the state laws allow Madison to seek
through its regulation of taxis.
II. Legal Constraints on Local Regulation
A. Competition is the fundamental policy of the state of Wisconsin in general and with
respect to public transportation.
c
. 1. State law requires that regulatory agencies promote competition both in
general and specifically in the transportation industries.
o a. Wisconsin's antitrust law, section 133.01: "It is the intent of the
legislature to make competition the fundamental economic policy of
this state and, to that end. state regulatory agencies shall regard the
public interest as requiring the preservation and promotion of the
maximum level of competition in any regulated industry consistent with
the other public interest goals established by the legislature." (Emphasis
added.)
o b. Wisconsin's motor vehicle transportation law is to the same effect;
section 194.02: "The legislature intends to let the market promote
competitive and efficient transportation services, while maintaining
the safety regulations necessary to protect the welfare of the traveling
and shipping public. It is the intent of the legislature that this chapter be
interpreted in a manner which gives the most liberal construction to
achieve the aim of a safe, competitive transportation industry."
(Emphasis added.)
. 2. The City of Madison's authority to regulation the taxi business depends on an
explicit grant of legal power from the legislature and so the city acts as a
c
delegated state regulatory authority and is subject to the commands of 133.01
and 194.02. Although 194.01 (1) exempts taxicab service from the definition of
"common motor carrier" which means that most state regulation does not apply,
taxicabs are not excluded from the broad policy governing "motor carrier
operations" expressed in 194.02 (quoted above), and are subject to some
specific state imposed requirements; for example, 194.41(6)(b)(2) sets minimum
insurance requirements.
. 3. The Madison's regulatory authority is conferred and defined in section 349.24
of the Wisconsin statutes: "The council of any city. . . may: (a) Regulate and
license. . .operators of taxicabs used for hire; (b) Regulate an license the taxicab
business by licensing each taxicab used for hire; . . . (d) Revoke any license
mentioned in this section when in its judgment the public safety so requires." In
addition, each taxicab must be insured at level set by local ordinance provided
that the level equals or exceeds the minimum required by state law:
194.41 (6)(b)(2) and 344.15(1).
. 4. Hence, in drafting and enforcing its taxi ordinance, Madison can only
implement legislatively defined goals and must seek the most pro-competitive
means of accomplishing those goals. The legislature has identified expliciUy only
two goals beyond the potential to collect license fees:
o a. public safety: presumably the ordinance can impose reasonable
safety standards on taxis and their drivers. Thus, unsafe cars or drivers
might be reasonably excluded from this business.
o b. insurance: the city may impose a higher level of liability insurance
than the minimum required under state law (25/50).
. 5. The city can make a creditable argument that the grant of authority reasonably
includes an implied right to define essential aspects of the taxi business:
o a. scope of seNice-territory: the city can most easily defend requiring
disclosure of any limits to the area of service; moreover, given its
obligation to enforce other legal requirements against discrimination, the
city may well have a plausible argument for setting minimum service
areas especially if those areas include low income or minority
populations. On the other hand, a requirement that all cab operators must
provide service across the entire city is much harder to defend in the
absence of a clear showing of the need for such a requirement and the
careful assessment of its impact on the potential for new entrants to
compete. After all. the market will discioline those who fail to provide
service in areas where there is demand iust as it will reward those who
provide service in areas of real need.
o b. hours of service: the city should be able to require disclosure of and
adherence to posted hours of service. It is much more questionable
whether there is any justification for requiring all operators to provide 24
hour service, seven days a week. Clearly, demand varies over the day
and through the week. Hence, it inflates the operating costs and entry
costs of firms if they must serve low demand times as well as high
demand periods. A policy of requiring such service implies "cross-
subsidization" of low volume times by excessive charges on users in high
demand times. Public policy generally holds such a random tax to be
undesirable. If more service is needed at low demand times than the
market will supply on its own, the city can explicitly subsidize such
service. This ensures public awareness and acceptance of any tax as
c
c
c
well as a clear recognition of who is paying for the service and benefiting
from it.
o c. disclosure of prices: nothing in state law would seem to authorize the
city to set rates for this service. However, it does seem that the city
should be able to require disclosure of and strict adherence to posted
prices.
o d. alternative forms of service: if an individual proposes an altemative
form of service-for example, a jitney type service or a local van service,
the city should on the one hand be open to considering such a proposal
on its merits, but would also have the authority to impose reasonable
requirements to ensure that such an enterprise provided the service it
promised.
. 6. Any anticompetitive city regulations have very limited immunity from federal
antitrust law because the state law does not seek to pre-empt competition in this
business. Under federal antitrust law, if the state has not explicitly pre-empted
competition, the city is not authorized to do so on its own. This raises concems
for city liability (discussed below) and for existing operators of taxi services who
might seek to use city regulation to frustrate new entry. Two cases decided in
federal circuit courts upholding substantial city regulation of the taxi business that
foreclosed competition rested on statutes in Texas and Illinois that explicitly
authorized the regulations at issue. In the case of Wisconsin, no such statutory
authorization exists.
c
B. This Subcommittee and the Transportation and Parking Commission have an
institutional conflict of interest in recommending or enforcing restrictions on competition
from an alternative, non-city owned mode of transportation.
c
. 1. Institutional obligations of transit commission: state law authorizes the city to
operate a bus system through the establishment of a transit commission that is
explicitly charged with the efficient management of that system. Bus service
competes with other forms of public and private transportation. Hence, the city
through its ownership and operation of the bus system is a competitor in the local
passenger transportation market. In addition, through its operation of a parking
ramp system it has a further stake in the operation of this market. Basically, the
city reduces its costs or eams a profit as the combination of parking and bus
revenue increase. One way to increase revenue is to suppress the competition of
altemative forms of transportation.
. 2. Because of its statutory obligations the Parking and Transit Commission has
an institutional conflict of interest whenever it regulates the taxi business.
. 3. The legal implications of this conflict are not resolved, but could be significant.
The Wisconsin Supreme Court overturned Milwaukee's efforts to regulate
competition in the ambulance market because the control of competition was not
authorized (American Medical Transport v. Curtis-Universal, 154 W.2d 135
(1990). In the case of anticompetitive taxi regulation, the following potential
judicial reactions could occur:
o a. strict scrutiny of any anti competitive aspect of the ordinance as well as
of any adverse decisions with respect to entry: recognizing that regulatory
authority has in fact been delegated, the courts would not void the
ordinance because of the conflict, but would give it very critical review.
The same kind of strict scrutiny would occur if the city denied operating
authority to any taxi operator.
c
o b. voiding the ordinance: a court might simply void the ordinance given
the role of the Parking and Transit Commission. The city's obligation was
promote competition. Involving the agency responsible for competition
with taxi's to play any role would be evidence that the city had failed in its
basic obligation. The merits of the ordinance would not be in issue.
o c. potential antitrust liability under state or federal law because of
competition with taxi business: a recent U. S. Supreme Court decision
arguably reaffirms the view taken in an older case that a city which is
engaged in business activities and then uses its municipal power to
advance its economic interest may be subject to antitrust liability.
Because of the general policy of state law, the city has no claim that it has
any state authorization to restrict competition in the taxi business. This
fact strips the city of its "state action" immunity in federal law. Given its
status as an economic competitor and its continuing contractual
relationship with existing taxi operators, it is possible to imagine a case
charging a conspiracy to restraint new competition for which all might be
liable.
C. Conclusion:
Failure to adhere to the legal constraints may result in loss of all city control over
the taxi business and could result in a damage award against the city for
foreclosing competition
c
The city has no legal authority to impose anticompetitive regulation on the taxi
business. Hence, if it does, it runs the risk of having its entire regulatory scheme
voided and leaving this business unregulated.
III. What should be done?
o A. Identify legitimate public interest concerns-safety, insurance, definition
of scope of business
o B. Draft an ordinance that defines standards
o C. Create an open entry process for new firms, which satisfy the
standards
o D. Identify an administrative agency without a serious conflict to oversee
the enforcement of standards.
Madison Regulation - Application for Initial License
Sec. 11.06(4)(b) PUBLIC UTILITIES
(b) Application for Initial License
c
Any person wishing to obtain a license to engage in the business of
transportation passengers for hire, whose rides originate within the City of
c
Madison, shall present to the City Clerk a written application accompanied by
proof of payment of the fee or fees established in Subdivision (a) above and by
proof of liability Insurance coverage as required In Subsection (8)(a) of this
ordinance.
The application shall state the name and address of the applicant, the number
and type of vehicles proposed to be operated, the method of charging, the
schedule of rates of fare to be adopted, and such other pertinent information as
the City Traffic Engineer may require.
All such applications shall be received by the City Clerk and shall be referred to
the City Traffic Engineer. The Transit and Parking Commission shall hold public
hearings on the applications. The hearings shall begin no later than sixty (60)
days after the applications are referred by the City Clerk. The City Traffic
Engineer shall notify the applicants of the time and place of the hearings. The
Transit and Parking Commission shall hear all persons desiring to be heard, shall
make such investigations as it deems necessary and shall establish standards to
determine whether or not a company should receive a license to engage in the
business of transporting passengers for hire. Such standards shall include, but
are not limited to the following:
c
8. The financial capability and responsibility of the applicant.
9. The applicant's prior experience in operating public passenger services.
10. The level and quality of service provided by the applicant in the past in
areas in which it has operated.
11. The experience and competence of the applicant's drivers.
12. The applicant's prior record of compliance with applicable regulatory laws,
ordinances and rules. This includes records of complaints an -
enforcement actions against drivers and vehicle owners.
13. The applicant's prior record of service complaints.
14. The age and condition of the vehicles proposed to be licensed. by the
applicant.
15. The applicant's safely record, including records of accident experience
and record of employee safely training.
(Am. by Ord. 11,848, Adopted 4-15-97; Effective 5-21-97)
c
o
c
o
c
Toward A 2111 Century Taxicab Regulatory Framework:
The Case of Madison
Samuel R. Staley, Ph.D.
Director of Urban Futures Program
Reason Public Policy Institute
3415 S. Sepulveda Blvd., Suite 400
Los Angeles, CA 90034-6064
Tel. 310.391.2245
Fax. 310.391.4395
e-mail: sstaley@reason.org
web site: http://www.urbanfutures.org
June 5, 2000
Samuel R. Staley directs the Urban Futures Program for the Reason Public Policy
Institute, a nonprofit, nonpartisan education and research organization based in Los
Angeles.
Introduction
c
The taxi industry is one of the most highly regulated industries on the local level. While
many taxicab regulations were instituted as an attempt to improve service quality, the
historical legacy has been lower service quality and industry competitiveness. This
occurs because local regulations create substantial barriers to entry that protect a small
number of established firms (creating an "oligopoly"). Many of these barriers have little
impact on service quality and create inefficiencies in the taxicab industry, reducing
profitability and competitiveness. Furthermore, regulations that prevent new firms from
entering a market severely limit business ownership opportunities in the industry,
particularly for low income and minority populations.
Deregulation Impacts and Directions for Reform
Since taxi entrepreneurs need little formal education to be effective and productive, the
taxicab business is well suited to the skills and income needs of many in the lower tiers
of the economic system. Once Indianapolis deregulated its taxi industry, for example, 32
new companies emerged within the first six months. Three fourths of these companies
were owned by minorities and women. Now, seven years after deregulation, Indianapolis
remains committed to its deregulation strategy. In Denver, the start-up company
Freedom Cab now employs more than 100 drivers that cater to underserved and largely
minority markets ignored by a cartel protected by the state public utilities commission for
more than 45 years.
Thus, in many cases, taxicab regulations have a double negative effect: consumers
suffer because regulations stifle competition to protect existing cab companies, and
potential entrepreneurs are prevented from opening their business to create new wealth
in the community.
c
Historically, the relaxation of taxicab regulations results in the following industry and
service impacts:
c
The number of taxicab companies, cars, and drivers increased by 23
percent on average.
Poorer, mainiy minority areas received more frequent and often higher
quality services.
Minority and women taxicab drivers became empowered by starting their
own businesses.
The negative impact of local regulations on economic opportunity is often an artifact of
the way local (and state) ordinances are designed and implemented. Taxicab ordinances
were written when regulators considered taxicabs (and other transportation services)
utilities. As a result, taxicab regulations followed traditional regulatory schemes, often
limiting competition and access for new companies, tightly regulating fares and rates,
and defining key elements of business operations such as hours of operations and
location.
Shifting the regulatory focus from protecting existing companies to monitoring taxicab
performance could improve services to consumers as well as create economic
opportunities among less educated, poor, and minority populations.
Taxicab regulation in Madison
c
Taxicab regulations in Madison, Wisconsin are detailed in Section 11.06 of the city code,
"Licensing and Regulating Public Passenger Vehicles, for Hire." Several features of this
ordinance stand out as unnecessary regulatory burdens on start-up entrepreneurs. If
stringent enough, regulations effectively impose a "cap" on the number of taxis and
companies by creating significant financial, political, bureaucratic, and administrative
barriers that add costs to starting a new business. Economic opportunities are most
severely limited for poor and minority groups that typically have the few resources to
devote to the maze of red tape, hearings, and approvals. These regulations may be
partially responsible for the decline in the number of legal taxicab companies in Madison
from seven in 1979 to just three in 2000. In addition, and perhaps more importantly,
these regulations limit the ability of the taxi industry to adapt to a dynamic transportation
market.
Among the more important regulatory obstacles to creating a taxicab company in
Madison are:
c
Company licensing fees [Sec. 11.06(4)(a)]. The City of Madison has
dramatically increased the financial barriers to starting up a new taxicab
company in Madison by imposing a $1,500 licensing fee for new
companies. Prior to July 1, 1998, city fees of $125 per company were in
line with many other cities. A survey of eight Ohio cities, for example,
found that the cost of licensing a new company ranged from $25 in
Youngstown to $75 in Columbus to $250 in Akron (with a $10 surcharge
for each additional vehicle). Only the city of Day10n charged fees that
exceeded Madison's current level ($250 per car). Moreover, Madison has
instituted a renewal fee of $500. These fees compound the effects of
other regulatory barriers and obstacles.
c
Public hearings on new cab company applications [Sec. 11.06(4)(b)].
Public hearings should be reserved for deliberating regulatory policy
rather than performing routine, administrative functions and
micromanaging an industry. Madison's ordinance is unduly open on publiC
hearings, allowing virtually anyone to object to a new applicant
irrespective of conflicts of interest and tangible impacts by the proposed
business. Criteria granting licenses should be clear and objective,
enabling taxicab licenses to be processed administratively. Criteria for
approval should be limited to performance issues directly tied to the
quality of service provided. This minimizes the likelihood licenses will be
approved or rejected for political reasons.
Public convenience and necessity [Sec. 11.06(4)(e)]. This provision has
been used in numerous cities to prevent entry into the taxicab industry,
from Cincinnati to Atlanta to Denver. For example, in Denver, Colorado, a
cartel of three taxicab businesses shut out new competition for more than
45 years by convincing the state utility commission existing companies
had the capacity to serve any public need for taxi service.
c
In Madison, the presumption is against new taxicab businesses since the
Transit and Parking Commission must make a positive affirmation that the
new business serves the "public welfare, convenience and necessity."
This makes entrepreneurship - defined as the discovery of new market
opportunities - difficult and in some cases impossible. Small businesses
are conceived and started on innate knowledge of the market and
expectations about what kinds of services consumers want and are not
provided by current providers.
Subjecting new business start-ups to political approval means
entrepreneurs must a) reveal the nature of their market opportunity to
their competitors and b) articulate a compelling case for their business.
These principles operate contrary to the nature of entrepreneurship and
the realities of market-based innovation. In market economies,
consumers determine what services will be provided, not politically
appointed commissions.
c
Twenty-four hour service requirement [Sec. 11.06(7)(a)]. This proviSion is
neither efficient nor appropriate in a modem era driven by technology.
This regulatory obstacle presumes that part-time operations are neither
viable nor desirable. In fact, specialized and part-time operations are
particularly well suited to meet consumer needs in the personal
transportation market. With pagers and mobile cell phones, drivers can be
dispatched anywhere in the city conveniently and cost effectively. Owner
operators can respond to calls and service requests personally at anytime
of the day or night. Some services that specialize in serving bar or
student-centered activities might only be viable on a part-time basis or
during specific times of the year. Part-time operations have the advantage
of filling unmet demand for transportation services while also providing
competition to existing services.
c
Twenty-four hour service requirements also Impose substantial up-front
costs on new companies, requiring investments in additional cers, drivers,
and equipment before a market Is well established. A case study of
similar regulations in Dayton, Ohio found that a start-up cab company
would incur additional costs of at least $15,935 to purchase cars and
insurance, and meet licensing requirements as a direct result of a 24-hour
service provision. These costs did not include operating costs such as
vehicle maintenance and fuel. A full-time service regulation, in effect,
requires new companies to "overcapitalize," making their ventures riskier
and more difficult to start. Entrepreneurs with low income and education
levels but substantial industry experience are particularly hard hit by
these regulations.
Citywide service requirement [Sec. 11.06(7)(a)]. This provision limits the
ability of the taxicab market to meet targeted, specific needs. More
specifically, minority and low-income neighborhoods of traditional cities
tend to be the most underserved areas. Taxicab companies can emerge
to fill specialized niche services: handicapped transportation,
neighborhood transportation, or even business specific transportation
services (e.g., contract transportation with local bars or restaurants).
Freedom Cab in Denver is a case in point. Requiring citywide service
reduces the likelihood these kinds of niche taxi services can evolve.
c
Driver hours of operation [Sec. 11.06(7)(b)). This provision also limits the
flexibility and adaptability of the local taxi industry. For instance, an
owner-operator of a part-time taxi service would technically violate this
provision of the ordinance if she had a 24-hour pager but only received a
few calls a day.
Similarly, other seemingly less intrusive regulations may negatively impact economic
opportunities in the taxicab market. Current regulations, for example, require drivers and
companies (Sec. 11.06(9)) to have a interior and exterior markings that permanently
identify a car as a cab. The intent of this regulation is to ensure consumers are fully
informed about the cab and the fare charged, a laudable and important goal. On the
other hand, this regulation inhibits the ability of cab drivers to use personal vehicles as
part-time cabs. This regulation could be modified to require exterior markings only when
. the cab is in service as a taxi, allowing drivers to take their car out of service and use
them for non-taxi purposes.
Toward performance-based regulations
c
Policymakers should seriously consider the negative impact local regulations have on
innovation and flexibility. Specialized, niche markets (e.g., for students, the elderly, or
the disabled) may benefit from having companies enter the market that focus exclusively
on their needs, whether on a full- or part-time basis. By limiting entry, local regulations
may have the unintended consequence of stifling innovation, encouraging existing firms
to focus on the overall market (the "average" consumer) rather than the needs of specific
individuals that make up a smaller, potentially less lucrative sector of the market (the
"marginal" consumer). Thus, in an attempt to improve the average quality of service,
c
local regulations may in fact discourage the provision of high quality services to specific
segments of the market and weaken market accountability.
The col)1bined effect of Madison's local regulations creates a hostile regulatory climate
for taxicab entrepreneurs. Economic opportunities are reduced while the dynamic
elements of a market economy that ensure consumer needs are met are compromised.
Madison's taxicab ordinance can be reformed to ensure quality services are provided
while also expanding economic opportunities for residents. This requires a paradigmatic
shift in thinking about taxicab regulation toward a performance-based approach.
Rather than focusing on micromanaging the structure of the industry - service
requirements, hours of operations, etc. - the city should focus on whether taxicab
companies provide the type and quality of service they advertise to consumers. In
essence, this requires the city of Madison to focus on the following aspects of taxicab
regulation:
Limiting hearings to complaints from consumers (not competitors) and
broad policy questions;
Ensuring accurate and complete consumer information about rates
and the past performance of drivers and companies;
c
Implementing administrative licensing to streamline permit processing
and minimize the politicization of business development;
Inspecting cabs for health and safety violations to protect consumers
from fraud and unscrupulous fly-by night operations; and
Ensuring cab companies are bonded and insured against liability.
The city of Madison can eliminate unnecessary barriers to entry into the industry by:
Reducing the cab company license fee from $1,500 to a range closer
to the industry standard (e.g., $150);
Repealing 24-hour and citywide service requirements;
Transforming licensing into an administrative process with clear,
objective criteria;
Explicitly eliminating economic impact on current operators as a
justification for denying a license to a new operator;
Eliminating the public convenience and necessity criteria for granting
a new license, allowing consumers and markets to determine the number,
type, and quality of taxi service provided;
c
c
Eliminating mandatory breaks in driver hours to enable part-time,
owner-operator companies; and
Eliminating the requirement for permanent exterior markings and
require markings only during times when the car is in service as a taxicab.
Taken together, these reforms provide a more entrepreneur friendly regulatory climate
for the local taxi industry. They also create a regulatory framework more consistent with
the dynamic, technology driven transportation sector that focuses on consumer needs.
The experience of other cities suggests that consumers - particularly poor and minority
neighborhoods - will benefit from increased access to transportation, and the city will
benefit from greater economic opportunity for all citizens.
References
Staley, Sam. "How Cities Put the Brakes on Taxicabs," The Freeman (March, 1998), pp.
147-50.
Styrlng, Bill. "Taxicab Licensing in Indianapolis: The Situation and Economics," paper
prepared for Regulatory Study Commission, City of Indianapolis, January, 1993.
Taxicab Regulation in Ohio's Largest Cities (Dayton, Ohio: The Buckeye Institute for
Public Policy Solutions, October, 1996)
c
Williams, Walter. The State Against Blacks (New York: McGraw-Hili, 1982), pp. 75-88.
c
o
\
c
1
(
o
c
An Economic Anaiysls of
Taxicab Regulation In Portland, Oregon
John W. Boroski
and
Gerard C.S. Mildner,
Portland State University
Aprll,1998
Executive Summary
c
Recent changes to Portland's taxicab regulations and the City's apparent willingness to
allow two new taxicab companies to enter the market unfortunately do not address more
structural problems within the industry. An analysis of the City Code reveals a host of
other measures which are laden with anti-competitive intent.
This study finds that Portland's taxicab regulations and administration do not actually
support the overall goal of the regulations, which is to promote competition within the
industry and to allow the industry to operate without undo restraint. Restrictions on entry,
minimum service requirements, and prohibition of independent operators do not increase
economic efficiency, and instead are directed to protecting the industry from competition.
In addition, tolerance of "first-in, first-out" queues at taxicab stands effectively prohibits
competition. In creating a highly concentrated industry with little incentive or opportunity
to compete, the City has actually caused the problems that give rise to other regulations.
Because of regulations that restrict entry, increase waiting times, and raise fares, the
number of taxicab trips taken in Portland is inefficiently low. Because of regulations that
inhibit ride sharing, increase trips without return fares (or "deadheading"), and increase
the time that drivers spend waiting in queues, the cost of producing taxicab trips is
unnecessarily high. Finally, a lack of effective competition has created shortages of
certain types of service (e.g. short trips) and stifled innovation. As a result, these
regulations have reduced industry employment and have transferred wealth from
consumers to entrenched taxicab companies, with a disproportionate impact falling on
the poor.
This study recommends that regulations that restrict entry, establish minimum service
requirements, and prohibit independent operators be removed from the Code. In
addition, this study proposes that a system of property rights be established in the
taxicab industry to replace first-in first-out taxicab queues. Taxicab companies should be
required to lease curb space from the City, which is currently given away for free. Each
stand would be reserved for the exclusive use of the controlling company or association.
These zones would be auctioned off, allowing firms with knowledge of local market
opportunities to bid for sites in those areas, with the highest bidders getting access to
the curbspace. In this case, zones might not only include the curb, but might also include
some adjoining space on the sidewalk to create a "taxi-stop" for the taxicab company.
The holder of the taxi-stop rights would have an incentive to advertise its location and its
company service. Independent cab owners would also be allowed to form associations
to lease and manage curb space. As taxicab companies in Portland have historically
resisted attempts to make them compete as distinct fleets, this system of property rights,
combined with an open entry policy, would make industry service more innovative and
dynamic.
c
c
Similarly, this study proposes that taxicabs be required to lease curb and counter space
at Portland Intemational Airport. To ensure competition, the Port of Portland could
establish five or more counter areas and curb areas which would be auctioned off to the
highest bidders. Again, independent taxicabs would be allowed to pool their resources to
lease space. Depending on logistical constraints, some curb area near the retail
counters could be reserved for each company to facilitate quick boarding, or perhaps a
shuttle would carry passengers to a secondary boarding area, as is currently done with
rental cars.
Removing entry barriers and introducing property rights would create a framework
whereby price competition becomes workable, eliminating the need to regulate rates. To
facilitate fare comparisons, however, taxicab companies should be required to use some
uniform measure such as the per-mile rate for distance- based fares. Rates would have
to be posted on vehicles, but they would no longer have to be filed with the Taxicab
Supervisor. Zonal fares, time of day premiums, and other fare mechanisms would also
be permitted.
Under the proposed system, one which fosters true competition and self-regulation, the
only requirements for market entry might be a valid drivers license, vehicle insurance
and registration, and safety certification. Industry competition and self-regulation would
avail the City from having to investigate complaints such as drivers having "grungy attire"
and ensuring that lost and found items are recorded and handled correctly. Similarly, the
City would not have to tell drivers to keep their cars clean, and not to use them to
commit crimes. Instead, taxicab companies would have incentives to voluntarily provide
information regarding fares, amenities, and accident records to groups like the Oregon
Visitors Association, local business groups, senior citizen organizations, and the public
in general.
This study does not call for more or "better" regulations. Instead, this paper argues that
an improved taxicab market can arise by removing regulation and promoting
competition. Elements of this proposal have been tested in places such as Indianapolis,
Washington D.C., Denver, Phoenix, and other cities, where deregulation has revived
local taxicab markets.
================ Boroski is a recent graduate of the Masters in Urban and Regional
Planning Program. Mildner is an Assistant Professor of Urban Studies and Planning, and
a Cascade Policy Institute Academic Advisor.
c
This paper analyzes the current regulatory framework goveming paratransit operations
in Portland, including regulations pertaining to taxicab and jitney operations. Based upon
a review of the economic literature and a survey of taxicab markets and regulations in
over 25 major US cities, the paper identifies changes to local regulations which would
benefit the general consumer of taxicab services, complement other city planning goals,
and enable publicly provided transit to operate more efficiently.
The authors wish to gratefully acknowledge the following individuals for their significant
contributions to this study: .
Tony Rufolo, Professor of Urban Studies and Planning, Portland State University
John Hamilton, Taxicab Supervisor, City of Portland
Mark McGrath, Library Information Specialist, Tri-Met
In addition, a debt of gratitude is owed to the survey respondents listed in the Appendix
to this study.
c
Table of Contents
c
Introduction
Why This StudY is Timely
The Portland Taxicab Industrv
Why Should Planners Care about Taxicabs?
Economic Analysis of Portland's Taxicab Reaulations
. Entrv and Franchise Reaulations
. Service Reauirements
. Quality Standards
. Fare Reaulations
Recommended Chanaes to Portland's Taxicab Reaulations
. Remoyina Barriers to Entrv
. Creatina Prooerty Riehts in Taxicab Stands
. Creatine Comoetition at the Airoort
. Dereaulatine Rates
. Review of Dereeulation in Other Cities
c
Conclusions
Exhibit 1: Market Share of Three Lareest Taxicab Comoanies
Exhibit 2: Comoarison of Taxicab Rates
Sources
Aooendix A: Taxicab Industrv Contacts
Aooendix B: Samole Survev
Aooendix C: Citv of Portland Title 16 Definitions
Endnotes
<>Introduction
c
This paper is a general study of taxicab regulation in Portland which looks at how
traditional taxicab service may be expanded, and how new and improved services can
develop. This paper does not directly evaluate the service that taxicab companies in
Portland currently provide, but rather analyzes the effects of regulation upon service
levels Cllndeed, most passengers probably find local taxicab rides to be moderately
comfortable and not extraordinarily expensive, although not very easy to obtain.
Nevertheless, many patrons can also cite experiences of dispatched taxicabs arriving
very late or not arriving at all, having to tolerate discourteous drivers, and other
problems. This study explores whether or not these are problems that consumers must
learn to endure, and the degree to which these problems may be attributable to factors
such as the taxicab regulations and restrictions on market entry.
This paper is organized into five sections. The opening section summarizes recent
regulatory reform proposals to illustrate current paratransit and taxicab issues in
Portland. The second section of the paper describes the Portland taxicab industry and
the regulations that govern it. The third section identifies the expected economic benefits
from regulatory change in light of current planning goals.
The fourth section of the paper is an economic analysis of Portland's taxicab regulations.
In this section, specific City Code requirements are analyzed to determine whether they
support the stated regulatory goals. Finally, the fifth section presents our recommended
c
changes to the Code, along with a discussion of how taxicab reforms have fared in other
cities.
In advocating deregulation, this paper argues that previous attempts at deregulation
have encouraged destructive competition, and that constructive competition can be
encouraged through market forces based on a system of property rights. Readers
should notice that this system of property rights could also apply to large public
transportation agencies, although total transit deregulation is not addressed specifically.
In the short run, however, competition from private taxicabs could stimulate the kinds of
efficiency gains and service reforms that would improve the overall financial
performance of public transportation (Cervero, 1997).
<>Why This Study Is Timely
c
Several recent events have focused attention on the local paratransit and taxicab
industry in particular, beginning with the partial closure this past fall of the Interstate
Bridge connecting Vancouver, Washington and Portland, Oregon. While local public
transportation agencies spent months devising plans to attract increased ridership, they
were criticized for ignoring policies encouraging the participation of the private sector to
provide much needed transit services (Solberg, 9/10/97). Critics, for instance, asked why
carpools, jitneys, and informal carpools could not utilize the newly installed high
occupancy vehicle lanes. In fact, such a market has formed in San Francisco, where
commuters meet in formal gathering places to form spontaneous carpools to cross the
tolled Golden Gate Bridge at a discount (Webber, 1994). While it may not be reasonable
to expect commuters to change their driving habits under relatively short notice, local
regulations in fact prohibit such ad-hoc ride sharing where a fare is charged. To some,
prohibition of this type of entrepreneurship is troubling enough, assuming that most
commuters already on the road logically choose to transport themselves in a safe
vehicle and retain a valid drivers license because they are a safe driver. Also missing
from the equation, however, were the local taxicab companies who are permitted to
perform these ridesharing functions. Admittedly, the bridge closure was short in duration,
making it difficult to assess the long run market for such services. Taken together,
however, the complete lack of response by the private sector to a transportation
emergency exposes a weakness in current transportation policies.
Not long after the bridge closure, Portland City Council reaffirmed a previOUS decision,
over the objections of Portland's four taxicab companies, allowing shuttle vans and town
cars to provide door-to-door shared-ride service to Portland International Airport. In the
last two years, the number of town car companies has grown from four to 70, and the
number of vehicles has increased from 25 to 167 (Oliver, 12/21/97). Although entry into
the airport market is now relatively unrestricted Cl, service standards and vehicle quality,
. however, are narrowly prescribed (enforceable by fines up to $500 per violation per day)
to make direct competition with the taxicab industry impossible~ Nevert~less, for
reasons explained later in this paper, the taxicab industry continues to lose existing and
potential markets to these relatively unregulated entrepreneurs.
At the behest of the taxicab industry, City Council is now seeking a cooperative effort
between the City, which regulates taxicabs, and the Port of Portland, which regulates
ground transportation at the airport, to address "economic equity and public safety
issues" for non-taxicab operations. In short, the taxicab industry would like to see the
playing field leveled between regulated and non-regulated transportation modes. This
paper argues that in choosing between more stringent regulation of the shuttle industry
and deregulating the taxicab industry, further constraining shuttles and town cars (or
luxury transportation) would be poor public policy. Just as the taxicab industry has failed
c
r'
\.-
to offer new services that customers obviously value, as demonstrated by the success of
these new companies, heavily regulated shuttle and luxury transportation providers will
also fail to discover and deliver innovative services.
Ironically, any further restrictions imposed on the shuttle and luxury transportation
industries will surely be advertised as "self-regulation" (Rose, 1/9/98). Yet as ground
transportation regulators are surely outside and not of these industries, codes which
heavily prescribe service standards and prices cannot be considered the product of self.
regulation. This intentionally obfuscates the fact that self-regulation only occurs in
competitive industries, where the goal is to increase the industry's total market by
elevating service standards. Establishing uniform prices within a highly concentrated
industry, however, will create incentives for companies to increase their profits by cutting
service, and nothing resembling self-regulation will result.
While the dispute between the taxicab industry and the shuttle industry continues, the
local press has announced the triumph of competition in the taxicab industry (Parente,
11/13/97, 12/18/97). City Council has directed the Taxicab Board of Review to amend
the Code which requires that new applicants show a "demonstrated need for additional
taxicab services in the city that is not, or cannot be, accomplished by existing
companies." Thus, after eliminating the italicized three words from the Code, the Taxicab
Board was able to recommend admitting two new firms and 65 new taxicabs into the
industry, the first new taxicab firms in 22 years. This decision is currently before the City
Council. Despite the elimination of this blatantly protectionist language, however, recent
"deregulation" is far from complete, as even a casual perusal of the Code reveals a host
of other measures which may be subjectively administered, and which are laden with
anti-competitive intent.
c
<>The Portland Taxicab Industry
c
In a prior attempt at comprehensive taxicab reform, the City designated Mr. James Allen
to be the local "taxicab czar" for approximately one year (1978). Allen collected industry
operational data (revenues, employment, trip information, etc.), reviewed the economic
literature, interviewed industry experts from other cities, and solicited viewpoints from
taxicab companies, city officials, taxicab drivers, and airport administrators among others
(Allen, 1978). In his report, Allen provides an excellent account of problems in the
industry, including: deficient service during peak periods and during inclement weather,
limited incentives for competition among firms, poor compensation for drivers, an
oversupply of airport service at the expense of inner city service, and a noticeable lack of
innovative service generally. Unfortunately, Allen's final recommendation was to adopt a
"wait and see" approach, advising that time be allowed to pass to see if conditions would
somehow correct themselves. Twenty years later, the same problems continue to plague
the industry.
The only important result of the Allen report was to simplify the administration of the
taxicab regulations. Oversight of the local taxicab industry was previously conducted by
the Bureau of Traffic Engineering, the City Attorney, the Chief of Police, and the Bureau
of Business Licenses, whereas now the regulations are administered by a single Taxicab
Supervisor. The functions of the Supervisor include:
1. Liaison between the industry and City Council;
2. Investigation of industry problems;
3. Investigation of public complaints;
4. Administration of issuing licenses;
5. Investigation of the feasibility of new or revised cab services;
6. Review of company financial and operational data;
c
7. Representation of the City regarding transportation policy changes which could affect
the industry.
Any major revisions to the taxicab regulations must be approved by City Council in the
form of an ordinance. In addition, the Taxicab Supervisor and the Taxicab Board of
Review may each adopt administrative rules which interpret and apply the general
purposes of these ordinances. The Supervisor serves as staff for the Taxicab Board of
Review, whose voting members consist of:
A. Three members of the general public with no affiliation with any taxicab company;
B. The Manager of the Bureau of Licenses or an appropriate designee, the Traffic
Engineer or an appropriate designee or alternate designee; and
C. Two other persons representing government agencies regulating or involving taxicab
services.
c
Although City Council need not approve administrative rules, a public hearing must be
held before any rule changes can be adopted.
Taxicabs in Portland provide approximately 2 million rides per year (Hamilton, 1996). In
comparison, Tri-Met, the local public transportation agency, provides almost 67 million
rides. The Port estimates that taxicabs transport 700 to 900 passengers daily to and
from the airport during non-holiday periods and up to 1,200 rides during service peaks,
constituting approximately 3.7 percent of ground trips (Cambridge Systematics, 1996;
Nelson, 1997). Business travelers represent 63 percent of these taxicab users, whereas
non-business, non-residents (e.g. tourists, visitors) constitute just under 15 percent of
taxicab users. While non-resident business travelers utilize taxicabs and town cars
almost equally, resident business travelers tend to prefer taxicabs (Cambridge
Systematics, 1996). This suggests that town cars have captured a large segment of the
airport market.
Taxicab service in Portland is currently provided by four companies with a combined
fleet of 317 vehicles. The two largest fleets, Broadway Cab and Radio Cab, each
operate 136 vehicles, while Portland Cab and New Rose City Cab operate 26 and 19
vehicles respectively. Currently, there is a minimum fleet size of 15 vehicles and no
provision for independent taxicabs. The total fleet size has not changed since 1994
when 16 additional permits were granted, and City Council has consistently denied
applications for new company permits (six denials out of six applications since 1985
(Hamilton, 1997d)). No new company has started operations in Portland since 1976
when Portland Cab was allowed to enter the market. While in the past prospective new
companies could apply at any time, recent Code changes will identify a one-month
window in which new and existing companies alike must apply for fleet expansions. This
window will follow the publication of the Taxicab Supervisor's Biennial Demand Study.
Under limited circumstances, a more informal demand study may be undertaken if it is
deemed that a "crisis" has occurred which warrants immediate attention. Twenty percent
of each fleet must be ADA accessible by July 1998, and fleets are required to provide
dispatch service 24 hours a day.
Taxicabs in Portland charge $2.50 for the first 1/15th mile (the flag drop), $1.50 for each
additional mile, and $20.00 per hour of waiting timen> Only one taxicab company does
not charge these rates, the maximum allowable under the Code. Radio Cab charges a
$2.00 flag drop, although this fact is not generally advertised. Approximately 70 percent
of all taxicab trips originate by telephone dispatch, compared to 30 percent which
originate from the airport or downtown taxicab stands (Entler, 1997). Probably less than
one percent of all taxicab trips are street hails, the percentage estimated in 1978 by
Allen. Finally, taxicabs are prohibited from soliciting passengers on the transit mall
during day times, and those caught doing so are fined $165 by the policeEl.
c
c
<>Why Should Planners Care about Taxicabs?
c
Planners frequently overlook the industry as a legitimate form of transit as taxicabs do
not provide many shared rides, utilize vehicles similar to private automobiles (confusing
"nonautomobility" with "nonautomobile"; Klein (1997)), and almost never fall within the
purview of planning departmentst!. On the supply side, the low utilization rate of
taxicabs and their relatively low market share of trips in most cities is largely due to local
regulations which effectively prohibit entry of new firms, prohibit competition within the
industry, give subsidies to public transit competitors, and limit the ability of transit
agencies to contract out services to taxicab companies (Kirby, 1974; Klein, 1997;
Cervero, 1997). Despite these obstacles, taxicabs constitute an $8 billion industry
employing just over 300,000 people. In comparison, urban and suburban transit
agencies collect $18 billionO, and have employment of approximately 840,000 (US
Statistical Abstract, 1996; Tables 966 and 1024). In deregulated markets such as
Washington D.C., and in markets where illegal participants operate with relative impunity
(Philadelphia, Los Angeles, and Miami, for instance), thousands of shared-ride taxis and
jitneys provide convenient, low-priced, door-to-door service on a daily basis (Cervero,
1997).
Taxicabs, and paratransit more generally, effectively bridge the gap between private,
single passenger automobiles - which cause too much congestion, waste travel time,
and consume inordinate quantities of fuel - and public transit - which is overcrowded
during peak periods, provides limited service during the off-peak, and operates on
inflexible routes. The definition of paratransit is "...those forms of intraurban passenger
transportation which are available to the public, are distinct from conventional transit
(scheduled bus and rail), and can operate over the highway and street system" (Kirby,
1974). That "miniature transit" performs so well where it is allowed to is a function of its
most salient features, which include: short trip times, reduced loading and unloading
time, increased maneuverability in traffic, freedom from driving, avoidance of transfers
and waiting time, door-to-door service, freedom from parking, route/time flexibility,
reliability, comfort, seat availability, storage space, and personal security (Kirby, 1974;
Klein, 1997, Cervero 1997). Since most studies continue to find that transit patrons value
service improvements greater than fare reductions and that this preference is correlated
with income (Cervero, 1997), one can assume that a society that continues to grow
richer will over time show a preference for modes that offer amenities typically
associated with the private automobile['}. Therefore, a transit system which offers bona
fide alternatives to scheduled, fixed route service is more likely to attract new transit
riders by virtue of simply providing more choice.
Taxicabs can and do serve an extremely diverse clientele. The elderly, for instance, are
often dependent upon others for their transportation needs and have limited finances,
and they particularly value the comfort, door-to-door service, ease of getting in and out,
and security offered by taxicabs. Low income residents and students may favor taxicabs
and forgo the expense of owning and maintaining a private automobile.
Taxicab usage, however, is not limited to those with reduced financial resources.
Professional and managerial workers use taxicabs to attend downtown meetings due to
their high value of time. Similarly, upper income households may employ taxicabs to
provide on-call, door-to-door, chauffeur-driven service on a part-time basis.
With appropriate deregulation, economists predict that taxicab service would expand,
lower prices would result, differentiated services would be offered, and customer waiting
lime would be reduced. If true, planners may question how the benefits attributed to
paratransit complement other city planning goals. To begin, taxicab service can mitigate
perceived parking shortages in close-in shopping, entertainment, and restaurant
c
c
districts, which are a prime focus for new development in current plans. Surprisingly,
while the City continues to study the feasibility of adding parking meters, issuing resident
parking permits, and other strategies in response to this issue, it has not seriously
considered promoting paratransit and taxicab servica. Secondly, taxicabs are well-suited
to provide transit service in fast-growing low-density suburban jurisdictions that
traditional transit serves poorly.
Retuming to the subject of parking, parking demand in Northwest Portland, Lloyd
District, and the Hawthorne District, for instance, is probably highest during the evening
and weekend hours, exactly when public fixed-route transit begins to shut down. In other
cities, evening and weekend trips to art and entertainment districts are well-served by
taxicabs. In Portland, however, most taxicabs choose to serve the milk run between the
downtown and airport. At the same time, thousands of new residents are expected in the
River District and the North Macadam area under current plans for high density and
mixed use development. While these new urbanites will reinforce the 18-hour activity
pattern the City wishes to encourage, they will also exacerbate its parking headaches.
Given a choice today between walking a half mile, waiting 25 minutes for a phone-
dispatched taxicab, or driving, residents of the River District seeking to attend a
downtown concert are most likely to drive. The high cost of parking a vehicle, however,
and the lack of ready taxicab service will limit the development potential of these
districts. Finally, the problem of evening alcohol consumption and auto driving can be
mitigated by good taxicab service, as traditional transit is not cost effective during
evenings. In fact, one study found that after deregulation, local taxicab utilization did
increase due in part to stricter enforcement of drunk-driving laws (Taylor, 1989).
Due primarily to its relatively high cost of labor, Tri-Met is currently exploring alternatives
to its new product line of agency owned and operated minibuses which serve low-
density suburban jurisdictions. Nationally, labor costs as a percent of total transit
operating costs have risen from 66% to 75% from 1960-1992, leading to a rise in
operating costs per passenger trip of 175% (Klein, 1997). At the local level, Tri-Met has
budgeted $35,946 for each regular full-time bus operator for its current fiscal year, a
figure which grows to $50,180 after accounting for the value of benefits guaranteed
under the union contract~. In comparison, the Oregon Employment Department
estimates that taxicab drivers on average net between $6 and $11.50 per hour not
including tipseJ. This data is consistent with figures provided by a long-time Radio Cab
owner-driver, who estimates that the average owner-driver earns about $14 per hour
after expenses including tips (Bussell, 1997). This higher estimate is equivalent to
$29,344 per year, assuming that 2,096 hours are worked (the assumption made for Tri-
Met full-time operators). Taxicab drivers, however, receive no fringe benefits of any kind,
resulting in a total compensation package which is 42% less than that received by Tri-
Met operators.
Recognizing these differentials, Tri-Met is seriously exploring ways in which new
suburban transit service may be contracted to more efficient private paratransit
providers. As stipulated in the union contract, Tri-Met is effectively prohibited from taking
any actions that will have adverse effects on its pubic transit union employees. Thus the
agency is prohibited from contracting out existing service, employing part-time workers
for peak-periods, or reducing service in weak markets. One way to avoid these
constraints, however, is to shelter revenue for new services in accounts separate from
the general operating fund (Arrington, 1997).
Can this strategy produce substantial benefits? Various experiments around the country
show that long term financial savings depend upon whether the contracted transit
providers also become unionized, thereby driving up operating costs, and the nature of
the contract and contracting process. Beginning in 1981, Tidewater Regional Transit
c
c
c
(Norfolk, VA) began contracting out service along low-density corridors to private
demand-responsive vans, despite protests and legal efforts by the local union (Cervero,
1997). Within two years, the agency was able to reduce its subsidy per passenger for
these routes by 64 percent, and the union subsequently agree to reduce its guaranteed
pay hours and create lower paid minibus driver positions with no work rules and fewer
benefits. Effectively, the new paratransit division won back the contract. In another
instance, Phoenix' transit authority contracted with a taxicab company to provide Sunday
fixed-route bus services in the early 1980's, producing savings of over $700,000 in the
first year. Finally, San Diego Transit's DART program has employed private, demand-
responsive vans since 1982 to provide nearly 800 rides per day to the general public in
five isolated communities, at substantial cost savings.
Tri-Met explored this strategy in the 1970's when it solicited bids to contract out its
nighttime "Owl" service in Portland (Allen, 1978). When the taxicab companies submitted
a joint proposal to provide service at the maximum allowable meter rate, however, the
agency elected not to push forward in the face of union opposition, as no cost savings
could be realized. Changes to the Code to promote competition, then, could
simultaneously expand the taxicab market and help Tri-Met to reduce the cost of low-
density suburban service. While this study does not focus on taxicab regulations in force
outside of the City of Portland, this section also points to a more proactive role that Tri-
Met could play in the evolution of transit, namely, encouraging reciprocal regulation (or
deregulation) across jurisdictions so that a greater selection of potential providers exists,
and passengers and drivers can take inter-jurisdictional trips without penalty.
<>Economic Analysis of Portland's Taxicab Regulations
c
In this section, the regulations which apply to Portland's taxicab industry are revisited in
more detail to determine whether they actually support of the stated goals of the
regulations. The Code statesl'.}
A. The purpose of this Chapter is to provide for the safe. fair and efficient operation of
taxicabs. The taxicab industry should be allowed to operate without unnecessary
restraint. However, because taxicabs constitute an essential part of the City's
transportation system and because transportation so fundamentally affects the City's
well-being and that of its citizens, some regulation is necessary to insure that the public
safety is protected, the public need provided, and the public convenience promoted.
B. The provisions contained herein should be applied and enforced in such a manner as
to require the taxicab industry to:
1. Regulate itself, under City supervision;
2. Promote innovation and adaptation to changing needs; and to allow competition and
response to the economic forces of the market place, so long as the public interest is
served thereby.
This section is organized around the four broad types of regulation in the Code: market
entry and franchise restrictions, service requirements, quality standards, and fare levels.
For each type of regulation, market conditions and/or information problems which are
thought to make regulation necessary are identified and analyzed. Incorporated into
each analysis is a description of the actual outcomes of the regulations, including
examples from a national survey of taxicab regulators and companies conducted by the
authors. This survey was directed to taxicab regulators in the 20 largest US cities ranked
by 1994 population in the 1996 Statistical Abstract of the United States. In addition, ten
cities with 1994 population closest to that of Portland (ranked 30th) were included for
comparison purposesCj. For all deregulated cities, and for many regulated cities too,
the largest taxicab companies were also contacted.
c
c
To conclude, transportation and tourism planners need to carefully examine the
regulations which apply to their own local taxicab industry. If regulation is often industry-
dominated and directed primarily to the industry's benefit as some observers contend
(few producers being easily combined into special interest groups), planners can
effectively represent the interests of customers who are too diverse and disorganized to
speak for themselves.
<>Entry and Franchise Regulations
c
Taxicabs are typically regulated as "common carriers", meaning that they provide
transportation services to the general RUbliC in retum for compensation, and are required
to serve everyone who is able to payeJ (Cervero, 1997). As such, common carriers are
often held to service standards, and in return are accorded some protection from
competition through restrictive licensing criteria. Therefore, local taxicab industries are
not "natural" monopolies, but may operate as a monopoly or cartel because of
regulation. In Portland, prospective and existing taxicab companies have one month
following the completion of the Taxicab Supervisor's Biennial Demand Study in which to
apply for fleet expansions (permits). Some time later, usually one month, the Supervisor
publishes his recommendations regarding these applications based on the following
criteria (section 16.40.215.C):
1. The current status of the public transportation system in the City, including but not
limited to:
a. The current and future ability of the public transportation system to provide the timely
and effective movement of persons; and,
b. The ratio of population within the City of Portland to the number of taxicabs currently
in operation.
2. The demonstrated need for additional taxicab service in the City that is not
accomplished by existing companies, as shown by the applicant;
3. The present utilization patterns of taxicabs currently in operation;
4. The interests of the applicant in establishing a local business to legitimately serve the
citizens of this City; and,
5. The extent to which granting the application will serve the purposes of this Chapter, as
set out in Section 16.40.001.
c
These criteria collectively represent the "public convenience and necessity" standard by
which most cities regulate entry into the taxicab market. The next step in the process
requires that the Taxicab Board of Review, informed by the Supervisor's analysis,
develop its own recommendation (through a voting process) to forward to City Council.
Finally, regardless of the decision rendered by the Board, City Council ultimately decides
the outcome based on findings that (Subsection D):
1. The applicant has established both fitness and ability to comply with the requirements
of this Chapter;
2. After consideration of the factors listed in Subsection 16.40.215.C, that the interests of
the City will be served thereby; and,
3. That the applicant has sufficient financial resources to be able to meet the minimum
standards established by Section 16.40.510.
4. The permit may contain such terms or conditions as the Council deems appropriate.
In addition, Subsection E allows the Supervisor to "assist the Board and City Council in
establishing such further standards as the Board or the Council deems appropriate, in
addition to those listed in Subsection C." Of course, any decision to admit a new
company can be and is appealed bylhe existing companies, as is the case in most
11
c
cities. Finally, Section 16.40.210.B1 prohibits the transfer of licenses to independent
operators; all operators must work under the management of one of the existing
(approved) dispatch companies.
The latest demand study undertaken by the Supervisor analyzed population changes
and projections for the city and region, statistics on elderly persons and persons with
disabilities, Tri-met ridership figures, airport passenger counts, convention activity data,
and current taxicab utilization patterns. Apparent in this study are many methodological
problems, only a few of which are discussed here for purpose of illustration. To begin,
the population figures considered do not account for changes in age, income, household
type or occupation, all of which would affect demand for taxicab services. Ultimately, this
analysis only calibrates the current ratio of taxicabs to population to the historical ratio,
which is presumed to be "correct", thereby perpetuating the historic low level of taxicab
service. Similarly, the transit data considered do not distinguish between where or when
service is provided, nor its relationship to total trip-making behavior. Other factors that
surely affect the demand for taxicab service, but which are not considered, include: land
use patterns generally (i.e. the spatial distribution of economic activity), rates of
automobile ownership, prices of alternative forms of transport (e.g. fuel, insurance, fares,
etc.), parking availability and charges, and climate and topographyC). Finally, in his
analysis of convention activity, the Supervisor concedes that "The percentage of overall
taxicab business derived from the Convention Center is unknown. Therefore it is difficult
to discern the precise number of taxicabs required for new demand.", in reference to a
projected 20% increase in convention activity for 1998. One can only wonder, then, how
the initial relationships between taxicab use and population, transit use, and other data
were established, upon which adjustments to the total fleet size are currently based.
The purpose of describing these methodological problems is to demonstrate the inherent
difficulties in estimating the demand for taxicab service. In fact, left to their own devices,
private taxicab companies would not try to definitively measure demand due to analytical
complexities and inaccurate or incomplete data. Hall (1996; p.45) provides a good
summary of this discussion:
One problem with trying to hit this target is that it is invisible. This alone would account
for some errors in marksmanship, but the target is also moving. It moves across the time
of day with changes in the demands to use roads. It moves across the years as the
average level of demand changes with changing incomes, fuel prices, and technology.
The difficulty of hitting this target means that government will miss it.
Has the target been missed in Portland? Anecdotal conversations with many taxicab
users and personal experience only confirm the conclusion of the Supervisor that
taxicabs frequently cannot keep pre-arranged appointments or arrive late, that waiting
time for all customers has increased, that an absolute shortage of taxicabs exists during
periods of peak demand, and that downtown close-in neighborhoods and other markets
are inadequately served (Hamilton, 1996, 1997d). To a certain extent, these problems
may not be due solely to an absolute shortage of taxicabs, but rather may reflect a lack
of incentives for taxicab companies to offer new services. Finally, the fact that eight new
applicants and two existing companies currently seek to increase the total number of
taxicabs, despite the Supervisor's contention that essentially no new demand exists
(Hamilton, 1997d), should lead one to look askance at the entire process.
Before dismissing the biennial demand study as a fruitless endeavor (instead of insisting
that public officials merely sharpen their pencils), it is worthwhile to step back and look at
the supposed goals of entry restrictions to see whether they can be promoted through
entry regulation. Entry regulations are generally thought to guarantee that all geographic
areas and potential customers are served (i.e. unprofitable service is cross-subsidized
c
c
12
c
by profitable operations), reduce traffic congestion, ensure that only "serious. or
"responsible" companies provide service, encourage taxicab firms to finance higher
quality service with returns that are increased through market protection to levels above
which could be earned in other aCtivities, and raise the standard of living for drivers in
the industry. Each of these rationales is discussed in turn.
As already noted, taxicabs in Portland are often unable to keep pre-arranged
appointments and must turn down additional service. In addition, the fact that taxicabs
generally avoid serving areas which are perceived to be unsafe is well documented. The
fact remains that for areas where the risk to life or limb is very real, no price, in fact,
could effectively entice taxicabs to provide service. It is also reasonable to expect that
some percentage of requests which are likely to result in an empty return trip are
similarly refused, as Allen (1978) confirmed in his study. Finally, from a practical
standpoint, universal service requirements are virtually unenforceable. In conclusion, no
evidence exists to show that universal service requirements provide levels of service
superior to what the market would provide, or that market skimming (or "creaming'1 does
not occur. As Frankena and Pautler (1984) note, instead of creating monopolies which
are able to selectively withhold service to maximize profits (taxicabs companies in
Portland are only required to operate at 66% of capacityCj), probably the most efficient
way to ensure universal access to transportation is through explicit subsidies to riders
which do not distort the market for taxicab services.
Regulators and taxicab companies sometimes argue that without entry restrictions, an
endless supply of new taxicabs will bring traffic in city streets to a virtual halt.
Unfortunately, because of taxicabs' physical similarity to private automobiles and their
relatively small passenger loads, the general public, and many planners, too, are prone
to believe this. According to this view, because taxicabs and their users do not pay the
full price of the congestion costs they impose, entry restrictions will reduce the number of
taxicab trips taken and reduce the amount of cruising to an efficient level. This argument
overlooks the fact that unless other road users are made to pay the full costs of the
congestion they impose, any restrictions on the number of taxicabs or on cruising are
likely to lead to an increase in road use by other road users (i.e. private automobiles)
who would find their travel costs reduced~. This argument also does not account for
geography or times of day when congestion is not a problem.
As Downs (1992) explains, in the absence of rapidly increasing population, congestion
levels tend to reach an equilibrium level. At this equilibrium level, some auto users who
would like to use congested roads have been diverted to other options, either traveling in
off-peak time periods, taking alternate routes, or switching to transit or other modes.
Each of these diversions represents a latent demand for the road space. If congested
road capacity is then reduced for some reason (e.g. new drivers begin to use the road),
some commuters will turn to one of the aforementioned options, thereby mitigating some
of the increased congestion. Similarly, if capacity on congested roads is suddenly
increased (e.g. a new lane is constructed), some commuters currently traveling in the
off-peak, taking transit, or traveling via alternate routes will switch to the once congested
facility, tending to bring congestion back towards its equilibrium level. Therefore, any
long term increase in the supply of taxicabs who place a high value on road usage
relative to other users will displace some existing users (including people who substitute
taxicabs for private autos) so that in the long run congestion effects are likely to be
negligible.
Finally, some service expansion and reduction of waiting times would result, which
would also have to be weighed against any increased costs of congestion. In any event,
in Portland these impacts would probably be insignificant due to the taxicab market's
small absolute size relative to general traffic levels.
c
c
IS
c
Regulations that increase the profitability of the taxicab Industry are sometimes
defended on the grounds that taxicab firms will finance higher quality servicas with
excess profits. Assuming for argument's sake that this is true, this still does not provide
evidence that the derived service benefits are always worth the cost of the excess
profits~. The high price of medallions or licenses in some cities, however, shows that
taxicab firms do not invest all their extra profits into enhanced service. Licenses in New
York City, Philadelphia, and San Di~o, for instance, currently trade for $285,000,
$44,000, and $60,000 respectivelyE]. The market value of a taxicab license represents
the present value of the future monopoly rents that accrue to the license holder as a
result of restricted entry and inflated prices.
In PorUand, we estimate the scarcity value of licenses at roughly $17,000. Currently, a
license for a "full" taxicab operable during both day and night shifts can be purchased for
a one-time average fee of $20,000 from individual Radio Cab owner-driversE) (Entler,
1997; Bussell, 1998). Subtracting an estimated $3,000 for the price of the car leaves
$17,000 for the license itself. Radio Cab owner-drivers also pay $185 per week for
dispatch and administrative costs, and about $2,000 per year in vehicle storage fees
(gas. and repairs are paid for out of pocket; Bussell, 1998). As these fees only permit an
owner-driver to drive seven 12-hour shifts, the vehicle is leased out again so that
another driver can drive the remaining 12 hours in any 24-hour period.
For hired drivers that do not own their licenses, the license value would be capitalized
into the periodic lease or "kitty" fees that are paid to the license holder. At Broadway
Cab, the company charges drivers about $400 per week for seven 10-hour shifts, which
covers all costs. The difference between $185 and $400 per week represents the value
of licenses held by Broadway Cab. Finally, differences in license values between
Broadway and Radio could also be attributed to: different discount rates for relatively
high and lower income drivers, service quality differentials between companies which
are difficult to measure, dissipation of monopoly profits through operating inefficiencies,
and the fact that Radio Cab charges slightly lower fares. Table 1 estimates a lower
bound on the costs to consumers that result from protection of the local industry.
Table 1
Estimated Annual Cost of Regulation to Consumers
Annualized Market Value of a License $2,720 (a)
Number of Licenses 317
Annual Transfer from Consumers to Producers $862,240
(a) 2 shifts x [($20,000 less vehicle value (estimated at $3,000)] multiplied by an 8%
annual interest rate.
c
c
This estimate assumes that all dispatch, administrative, and storage fees are charged at
cost. That is, all profits are reflected in the license price, and the dispatcher earns no
excess profit. As these assumptions are conservative, this may understate the total
income transfer due to a shortage of licenses. Importantly, an estimate of the total cost
of regulation should also add the value of the additional time consumers are made to
wait for taxicabs, the value of trips and/or services that simply are not provided, and the
increased costs that consumers pay as they utilize more expensive substitutes, all of
which are difficult to measure, but which are probably substantial.
Finally, as taxicab drivers have few specialized skills, the monopoly profits of the taxicab
industry are unlikely to affect their earnings (Hall, 1996). Rather, the value of unskilled
labor generally determines their earnings. When demand for taxicab service decreases,
for example, the biggest change for drivers is the decline in driver employment as
opposed to earnings, and some drivers move to other jobs which pay about the same
wages.
16
r-
'-'
To examine the characteristics of taxicab drivers, Schaller and Gorman (1995, 1996b,c)
provide a good discussion of factors that influenca taxicab drivers' incentive to provide
higher quality service, whether they work in a regulated or deregulated market. Driving
their study was a survey of New York City residents that showed, out of four perceived
aspects of taxicab service (the fare, availability, vehicle condition, and the driver), most
complaints pertained to the level of service provided by drivers. In this case, common
complaints included drivers' inability to converse in English, inability to locate
destinations, driver discourtesy, and poor driving ability.
Among the authors' key findings are that full-time owner-drivers with four or more years
of experience received much fewer summonses for serious violations such as reckless
driving, overcharging, and service refusals than less experienced drivers (typically
lessees). Not surprisingly, the authors conclude that the key to improving driver quality is
to increase the number of career owner-drivers who, like homeowners, will protect their
investment, and that strict enforcement of traffic regulations (e.g. more fining, or
elimination of some bad drivers), while necessary to protect the public safety, will not
increase the compensation of other drivers left unto itself. Schaller and Gorman then
propose that in New York City all corporately owned licenses (known as medallions)
revert to individual ownership when they are sold in the future, acknowledging that this
might not be for a very long time.
In Portland, however, independent taxicab ownership is stifled through prohibitions on
transferring licenses so that lessees can start their own company, even when the new
company could do better. Predictably, turnover at Radio Cab, where a large number of
drivers are also owners, is approximately 10% to 20% per year, compared to 80% at
Broadway Cab where all licenses are owned by the company (Hamilton, 1998c).
Particularly telling is the fact that many new self-employed Town Car operators are ex-
Broadway drivers. Again, instructing the taxicab companies to treat their employees
better will not resolve problems of driver quality and instability within the industry. The
solution is to facilitate the process of new company formation.
c
<>Service Requirements
Section 16.40.510 of the Code describes the minimum service standards under which
permitted companies must operate:
A. An office open and staffed for a minimum of 8 hours a day, 5 days a week.
B. A dispatch system in operation 24 hours each day capable of providing reasonably
prompt service in response to requests received by telephone.
C. Facilities and personnel sufficient to insure that every taxicab operated by the
company complies with the requirements of this Chapter.
D. Not less than 15 taxicabs, with two thirds of the fleet to be operational at all times, to
provide service on a City-wide basis in accordance with the Supervisor's regulations.
E. Insurance policies in force sufficient to meet the requirements of Section 16.40.730
and to protect the company to the same limits of liability.
F. A taxicab company shall not refuse to respond to any request for taxicab service
received from a location within the City.
G. Each driver shall maintain a log in which a record of every trip shall be kept, in a form
approved by the Supervisor. The taxicab company shall maintain the log for at least 1
year after the last entry therein.
c
Requirements that companies operate a minimum number of days per week, hours per
day, and/or total vehicles can be discussed together. Service standards of this nature
17
c
essentially force companies to demonstrated their "seriousness" through substantial
capital expenditures. These standards also presume that companies must provide
dispatch service to be economically viable, and that 15 vehicles are required to provide
adequate coverage. Several problems result from these type of policies. Assuming that
firms need to provide dispatch service to survive, firms will have an incentive to form a
sufficiently large fleet size to reduce customer wait time and maintain a good reputation.
Moreover, not all service needs to be dispatch-based, as demonstrated by the success
of New Rose City Cab which had no dispatch system for years. Customer wait time at a
taxicab stand is actually determined by the size of the total industry and not by the size
of anyone individual company. The fact remains that in a competitive market, incentives
exist for independent taxicabs to form fleets to capture scale economies, and to create
brand loyalty. This is already beginning to happen in the town car market, which has
minimal entry restrictions, as individual operators begin to direct service to each other
via cellular telephones (Bussell, 1998). To conclude, however, no conclusive evidence
exists to show what might constitute the "optimal" fleet size, and therefore firms should
be left to discover this for themselves. Current service standards do not appear to be
driven by any economic rationale, but rather serve to protect the larger companies from
smaller, potentially lower cost firms.
For cities that base fares upon taxicab firms' cost of doing business, regulations that
raise costs (e.g. minimum office hours) would lead to higher fares. Service requirements
in Portland also prevent the adoption of low cost shared-ride services. For example, all
of the cities and taxicab companies surveyed do not allow taxicabs to pick up additional
passengers en route, or if not, they require that the first passenger or group give
permission to take on additional riders, thereby decreasing taxicab utilization and
increasing the cost of rides. In this case, allowing taxicabs to post destination signs and
accept all riders, to effectively operate as jitneys, could increase utilization by attracting
riders who would seek reduced fares. Jitney service might capture peak rush-hour
demand for transit just as licensed part-time coffee and food vendors supply service not
handled by restaurants. In this light, there is no economic reason why independent
would-be participants should be prohibited from providing peak or niche services that the
larger providers selectively withhold or are incapable of serving. Independent taxicabs,
for instance, might set their sites on providing shuttle service to sporting events, music
events, and festivals.
.C
<>Quality Standards
Safety and quality standards, to be met by each individual taxicab, are described in
section 16.40.720. Thus vehicles must be:
A. Kept clean;
B. Kept in good appearance and good repair;
C. Properly maintained;
D. Kept in safe condition; and
E. Equipped with all pollution control equipment and safety devices originally installed by
the manufacturer, and such equipment and devices shall be kept in good working order.
c
Few studies have criticized regulations concerning vehicle condition and age, safe
operation, driver qualifications, or insurance coverage (Frankena and Pautler, 1984).
Because it may be difficult or impossible for passengers to judge some aspects of the
quality of taxicab service before they ride, it may be efficient for government to regulate
these matters to reduce information costs. This is why restaurants are required to submit
to periodic visits from the local Health Inspector. Although these various aspects of
18
c
safety also affect third parties (e.g. pedestrians and other drivers), these externalities do
not warrant that safety standards be different for taxicabs than for all drivers and
vehicles. In this regard, the amount of insurance that Portland taxicab companies are
required to carry appears to be adequate but not burdensome, and its driver licensing
requirements are not unduly stringent. At the same time, however, it might be efficient to
have stricter enforcement of standards, as the benefits of enforcement would be
increased for vehicles that travel more miles per year (Kirby, 1974). In Portland, permit
holders are not actually required to provide proof of inspections for mechanical safety;
instead all taxicab companies are to file annual policy statements that describe how they
ensure both vehicle and driver safety, and service quality (Hamilton, 1998d). While the
Supervisor does personally inspect all wheelchair accessible vehicles and spot checks
the remainder of the fleet on an ad-hoc basis, a more regular system of inspections, as
occurs in the restaurant industry, might be justified.
<>Fare Regulations
c
The primary reason that regulators establish fixed or maximum fare levels in the taxicab
industry is to ensure that prices are "reasonable" in the eyes of consumers, and that
producers are ensured a "reasonable" profit (Hackner and Nyberg, 1995). Economists
do not define a "reasonable" price but rather have a concept of a market clearing price
which under competitive .conditions simultaneously maximizes wealth for both
consumers and producers.
Cities that regulate fares usually target some revenue-cost ratio or rate of return, and
Portland presumably follows suit. While the Code does permit the Supervisor to collect
financial data from the taxicab companies, company revenue is not actually divulged due
to proprietary confidentiality (Hamilton, 1998d). Instead, the Supervisor estimates the
average costs of doing business for these companies and meets with them to get
concurrence, and without ever seeing their books, sets the rates accordingly. Finally,
these rates are compared to other cities (e.g. Minneapolis, Kansas City, San Jose, and
Seattle) for reasonableness.
Exhibit 2 shows prevailing rates for 28 large US cities, and estimated costs for a
representative city trip and a longer distance trip (the same distance as from downtown
Portland to the airport). Of the 28 cities surveyed, only three cities would charge a higher
fare for the city trip that is modeled, while for the longer trip, ten cities would charge
higher rates. This data reveals that while Portland's meter rate is close to the industry
average, its flag drop charge, weighted to reflect the lower fare charged by Radio Cab, is
the highest among the cities and companies surveyed. The excessiveness of Portland's
taxicab rates is demonstrated, however, not by comparison with other citiesE}, but
rather by high (positive) license values.
c
Hall's earlier observation regarding government's (in)ability to discover the optimum level
of industry supply is also true regarding the process of setting efficient fares. Due to
informational and analytical problems, government is sure to miss the target. However,
to rely upon the market to establish efficient fares, again, we must consider the market
imperfections that would justify rate regulation. Factors typically cited as justification for
setting fixed or maximum fares include inelastic demand for taxicab services,
informational problems in the market for cruising taxicabs, and economies of scale in the
telephone dispatch market. Each of these issues is discussed in turn.
Most studies of the taxicab industry estimate the fare elasticity of demand to be in the
range of -0.5 to -1.0, meaning that the quantity of trips taken is relatively unresponsive to
price changes (Frankena and Pautler, 1984). While most of these studies have
19
c
methodological problems, as many taxicab users are poor and have no car, or are
travelers not wanting to pay high parking charges at airports, it is still plausible to
assume that demand is relatively inelastic. Inelastic demand for a product or service by
itself, however, does not distort the market if competition exists among multiple suppliers
to provide the product or service. A good example of this situation is the market for
cigarettes, where demand is inelastic due to the addictive nature of the product
consumed, and few substitutes exist. In this case, however, competition among brands
drives prices down to an efficient level. Thus inelastic demand only becomes a problem
when producers perceive inelastic demand for their brand. That few taxicab companies
operate in Portland with little incentive to compete, however, is a problem that local
govemment officials have in fact created through regulation, and can rectify.
The peculiar nature of the cruising taxicab market, where consumers and producers
operate from random locations, creates informational problems which are thought to
necessitate rate ceilings. In this case, taxicab users in the cruising market are unlikely to
tum away the first taxicab that comes to them, as they do not know when the next
taxicab will arrive or what price it will ask (Williams, 1980). Since relatively inexpensive
cruising taxicabs cannot signal their whereabouts to consumers, an upward pressure on
prices results, as taxicabs that raise their fares above the going rate are unlikely to lose
many passengers.
Two potential solutions exist to solve informational problems in the cruising taxicab
market. One solution is for hailers to call a dispatch company, which does have a fixed
location, to have a taxicab sent to them. This, of course, would require multiple dispatch
companies serving the market so that price competition is workable.
c
As a second solution, hailing customers also have the option of heading to the nearest
taxicab stand where price competition can occur among the waiting taxicabs. A familiar
example illustrates this pOint. Just as food cart vendors typically appear in areas where
there is a large customer base, and where other food providers (i.e. restaurants) are
located, cruising taxicabs similarly tend to operate where some density of demand
already exists. What prevents roaming food vendors from charging exorbitant prices,
however, is the fact that customers can readily go to a competing vendor or restaurant.
Thus. while a food cart vendor may be able to charge some premium for the .
convenience of bringing his or her product to the customer, a competitive marketplace
keeps this premium at a reasonable (efficient) level.
The problem in Portland, and in most cities, is that price and quality competition at
taxicab stands is effectively prohibited, either through regulations or enforced customs
which require that passengers employ the first taxicab in the queue. At the Portland
airport, passengers are required to accept the first taxicab in the queue. And elsewhere,
while customers have the legal right to choose among taxicabs at stands, the drivers
themselves will direct passengers to the front of the queue. Moreover, the City does not
actively advertise the fact that choice exists, nor does it punish drivers who enforce first-
in, first-out customs. In the taxicab stand market, then, taxicabs effectively operate as
one company, or fleet, and price and quality competition does not occur.
Frankena and Pautler (1984) describe how multiple, distinctively marked fleets can
reduce problems of price searching in the cruising taxicab. Fleets would have greater
incentive to charge lower fares and provide better service than identically-marked
taxicabs for three reasons. Because its vehicles could be identified easily, a fleet would
reduce search costs for riders seeking a lower fare or better service. Secondly, the
larger the number of taxicabs charging a lower fare, the lower will be the expected cost
to riders who tum down higher priced taxicabs. Finally, fleets might attract to the cruising
market a group of riders who are unwilling to pay the higher fare charged by other
c
20
c
taxicabs and who will wait until a fleet vehicle appears. As taxicab companies in Portland
have historically resisted attempts to make them compete as distinct fleets or brands eI.
however, some mechanism is necessary to force them to do so.
Economies of scale exist when the average cost of production declines as a company's
output increases. While there do not appear to be economies of scale in the taxicab
stand or cruising taxicab markets, scale economies exist in the market for advertising,
vehicle management, and vehicle dispatching. Economies of scale can pose problems
when the output range over which cost declines is large relative to the absolute size of
the market. as the number of firms in the industry is likely to be small, and firms may
able to charge prices above marginal cost without causing other firms to enter the
market. Thus, for cities that have relatively small fleet sizes (e.g. Virginia Beach with 39
vehicles, Albuquerque with 133, and Long Beach with 105), price ceilings may be
warranted to restrain firms from exercising market power.
Small market size by itself, however, may not always be the best indicator of scale
economies, as some cities that restrict entry (e.g. Albuquerque, Long Beach) may
actually restrict supply to levels far below what the market would provide, thereby
creating a self-fulfilling prophecy. In fact, cities that have open entry policies, and/or
allow independent taxicabs, regardless of market size, also show reduced monopoly
power. The largest three companies in Fresno, for instance, which only has 50 total
vehicles, only constitute 66% of the market, compared to 94% for Portland. Similarly,
Indianapolis and Kansas City, which have 398 and 360 licensed taxicabs respectively,
and which also have open entry policies, only have monopoly concentrations of 50% and
66%. These findings are consistent with other studies (Frankena and Pautler. 1984) that
show that where open entry is allowed, small firms and independents can coexist with
large companies and can potentially reduce market power (i.e. excessive prices). To
conclude, arguments that claim that economies of scale in the taxicab industry are so
substantial as to make competition impossible are not defensible~.
One result of inefficiently high fares is the long queues that taxicab drivers and town car
drivers wait in at the airport to take rides. Drivers are willing to wait in long queues
because the benefits of a long-haul trip outweigh the cost of waiting. On a per hour
basis, these trips generate the most income and highest profit. At the same time, the fact
that consumers are increasingly choosing town cars, which offer better service at only a
slightly increased cost. to taxicabs, despite the fact that they may not really want a
complimentary newspaper or bottled mineral water, shows how the quality of taxicab
service is overpriced.
The solution to the prOblem of inefficient (excessive) supply, however, is not to restrict
entry of town cars and taxicabs into the market, but to reduce fares to the market
clearing level. Many cities do this by establishing flat airport rates which are lower than
the regulated meter rate on a per mile basis. Retuming to Exhibit 2 then, Portland's rate
for a long distance trip (representing an airport trip) is relatively high on a per mile
basis~. Another solution might be to require taxicabs at the airport to compete with
each other for airport rides rather than using the first-in first-out system. To conclude,
there is no economic reason why the most lucrative service should be reserved
exclusively for the existing taxicab companies, while new entrants are forced to provide
innovative, but marginally profitable service. In this light, policies stating that new airport
providers "need not apply" (Hamilton, 1997d), or that "we don't want to create new
employment opportunities at the expense of our existing businesses" (Francesconi,
1997) are inequitable. Similarly, policies forcing town cars to raise their own rates
effectively puniShes these operators for providing affordable service that consumers
value, and only exacerbates the problem of wasteful overspending. The problem at the
airport calls for more competition and more service, not less.
c
c
21
c
In order to compete for airport service, new entrants would want to offer long-haul
discounts. However, while the Code does not prohibit alternative rate schedules, rates
must be filed with the Supervisor. This system tends to preclude other pricing options
that might benefit both taxicab providers and consumers. Zonal fare systems, for
instance, which charge a set fare in advance for trips entirely within a zone or between
each pair of zones, are particularly helpful to tourists who are vulnerable to circuitous
route taking, and are used extensively in Washington D.C. Zonal systems reduce
customer uncertainty, and would be particularly valued by regular and low income users.
They also facilitate shared-ride service, as fares are more easily divided. Taxicab
companies, therefore, might implement a zonal fare system to gain a competitive
advantage, by creating predictability for customers, and perhaps by eliminating the need
to purchase and maintain taximeters.
Although the City would like to see more innovation from its taxicab companies, the fact
remains that product differentiation does not occur with single regulated prices, and that
unregulated prices to offset increased risk would provide more incentive for exploration
of new markets and services. Similarly, rigid rate structures work against some
"traditional" taxicab services too. The fact that taxicabs are scarce during the rush hour,
for instance, is partly attributable to prohibitions against part-time providers, and is also
due to a rate structure that does not account for circumstances, in this case congestion,
that raise operational costs (which is why telephone companies and airline carriers
institute peak period pricing). Thus, as some trips to distant suburbs and late night trips
are probably turned down do to the increased risk of returning empty, flexible rate
structures could ensure more reliable service by accurately reflecting density of demand.
Whereas Schaller and Gorman showed how lessees can be expected to provide worse
service than driver-owners, Hall (1996, p.60-62) shows for both groups how driving
standards are lowered when a few firms charge similar fares due to a lack of
competition:
Ironically, by standardizing taxi service government has exacerbated the prOblem of
enforcing quality standards for drivers. Avoiding those drivers or companies who provide
bad service is more difficult when service is homogenous. Bad drivers take advantage of
this heightened opportunity to escape penalties which markets impose...lf fare regulation
drives brand name companies out of the trade, their self-policing mechanisms go with
them. This exodus, in turn, encourages those drivers with less scruple and/or greater
skill at avoiding regulation to join the business. In effect, bad drivers drive out the good.
Personal experience, anecdotal conversations with other taxicab users, and Radio Cab
drivers' insistence that the company raise its rates to the maximum allowable (Bussell,
1998) suggest that local taxicab users do not perceive much difference between the
existing companies. And when one company fails to show, or arrives late, the consumer
has few alternatives. Similarly, when taxicabs are deployed on a first-in first-out basis at
taxicab stands, drivers have no incentive to increase quality, as customers cannot
efficiently seek out those who do.
c
c
Finally. returning to the subject of inelastic demand, one effect of the rate structure that
Portland has settled on is its disproportionate impact on the poor. In defense of
Portland's relatively high flag drop charge, the highest among the cities surveyed,
regulatory staff has offered that high up-front costs should be paid for up-front, and that
the high charge is necessary to entice providers to service less lucrative short trips
(Hamilton, 1998d). In fact, only two costs are probably attributable to taxicab trips as
opposed to trip durations, these being the costs of dispatching and time spent boarding
and unloading (Wohl, 1984). Nevertheless, there is no inherent reason why these costs
must be allocated on a per trip basis as opposed to on a per mile basis {although the
22
c
survey results show that most cities take the latter approach). However, most long-
distance trips are by passengers with higher incomes (business travelers and tourists),
and most short-haul trips are by lower income riders on shopping trips or health care
visits (Frankena and Pautler, 1984; Wohl, 1984). Therefore, Portland's rate structure
leads the poor to pay a higher proportion of the industry's fixed costsE].
<>Recommended Changes to Portland's Taxicab Regulations
Portland's taxicab regulations do not actually support the overall goal of the regulations,
which is to promote competition within the industry, and to allow the industry to operate
without undo restraint. As the previous sections have shown, restrictions on entry,
minimum service requirements, and prohibition of independent operators do not increase
economic efficiency, and instead are directed to protecting the industry from competition.
In addition, tolerance of first-in first-out queues at taxicab stands effectively prohibits
competition. In creating a highly concentrated industry with little incentive or opportunity
to compete, then, the City has actually caused the problems that give rise to other
regulations.
<>Removing Barriers to Entry
c
This study recommends that regulations that restrict entry, establish minimum service
requirements, and prohibit independent operators be removed from the Code. These
regulations reduce service for the consumer, stifle innovation, increase the cost of
taxicab trips, reduce industry employment, and constitutes de facto discrimination, as
many would-be participants are minorities and/or immigrants. In addition, experience
from other cities shows that costly enforcement of entry restrictions achieves little, and
that illegal activity will only increase with market size (illegal activity is a persistent
problem in New York, Los Angeles, Chicago and Philadelphia).
Deregulating entry into the industry does present some difficulties. Many taxicab owners
have invested thousands of dollars purchasing licenses or shares in taxicab companies.
However, since the high value of the taxicab license is an artificial creation of the
regulations, the government has every right to take it back. A more politically palatable
solution, however, might warrant a more gradual transition. For instance, the City could
increase the supply of permits at monthly auctions for a transitional period, after which
time no restrictions would apply. Of course, the cost of a long transition period is a
slower pace of innovation.
<>Creating Property Rights in Taxicab Stands
c
A second barrier to competition is the presence of first-in first-out taxicab stands.
Downtown curb spaces have several alternative uses, including but not limited to:
metered parking, lanes of traffic, loading zones, and bike lanes. Construction companies
that use curb space must pay for the privilege. Despite past policies of charging for curb
space, however, the City now gives away the space for free, reasoning that taxicabs
already pay to use this space (less than $50 per year per vehicle) through permit and
business license fees (Allen, 1978; Hamilton, 1997c). Following this reasoning, we would
also base the price Starbucks might pay to operate at a prized location such as NW 21 st
and Lovejoy upon the value of services provided by the Public Health Inspector who
inspects for cleanliness. How many taxicab stands should there be? Of the
23
~'"
L
apProximately 80 taxicab stands in the city, many are underutilized, while others face a
steady demand. City policy over the years has allowed the number of stands to
proliferate without any rational plan for establishing or removing them.
This study proposes that taxicab companies be required to lease curb space from the
City, and that each stand be reserved for the exclusive use of the controlling company or
association. Thus, regulatory staff would identify curb zones, perhaps drawing upon the
input of neighborhoods who might desire additional service, and put them up for lease.
These zones would be auctioned off in such a way to prevent monopoly power which
could result from an initial maldistribution. Firms with knowledge of local market
opportunities would bid for sites in those areas, and the one with the highest valuation
would get the curbspace. In this case, zones might not only include the curb, but might
also include the adjoining space on the sidewalk and road, creating a "complete" stop to
effectively be managed by the taxicab company as a private resource. The holder of the
curb rights would have an incentive to monitor its "property" and report violations, which
would be treated as a private tort and/or a municipal violation. Independent cab owners
would also be allowed to form associations to lease and manage curb space. This
solution simultaneously addresses the problem of stand proliferation, and provides
customers with a method of selecting among taxicab companies that cannot be undone
by the companies.
<>Creating Competition at the Airport
c
This study proposes that taxicabs lease curb and counter space at the airport. The rapid
rise in commercial door-to-door services among airport users represents a major change
in US airport ground access travel during the last two decades, as airport travelers
particularly value high quality transportation service. Even in cities where airports are
well served by rail and bus transit such as Washington D.C. and Chicago, taxicabs are
estimated to account for 36% and 15% of all ground transport trips respectively (Cogan
and Cambridge Systematics, 1997). In this light, demand for taxicab, town car, and
shuttle van service at Portland International Airport should be expected to grow
substantially in the future, reinforcing the need to find a more efficient system of
providing these services.
In this case, the taxicab companies would be required to lease counter space which
could be located within the airport lobby, Eerhaps adjacent to the rental car counters to
further encourage comparison shoppingLl. To ensure competition, the Port of Portland
as manager of the airport could establish five or more counter areas which would be
auctioned off to the highest bidders. Again, independents would be allowed to pool their
resources to lease space. Depending on logistical constraints, some curb area near the
retail counters could be reserved for each company to facilitate quick boarding, or
perhaps a shuttle would carry passengers to a secondary boarding area, as is currently
done with rental cars. To encourage more shared rides, which might be facilitated by
firms offering flat and/or zonal fares, Port staff could also provide shared ride
coordinators to quickly help passengers group together.
In fact, a similar solution was recently proposed for San Francisco International Airport,
which cited problems similar to those experienced in Portland (Cogan and Cambridge
Systematics, 1997). Three separate departure zones, in this case for shuttle services,
were established. Two large companies were to be selected by a bidding process, while
a third area would have a neutral coordinator to dispatch all the other companies. After
the bidding process was conducted, however, the operation was put on hold as the
those in charge of administering the program were flooded with complaints from the
losing companies. Interestingly, many of these same losers indicated that they would still
c
24
c
prefer some system whereby which they could compete on the basis of their reputation
rather than returning to the prior system.
What might Portlanders see as a result of these changes? Some airports already
allocate exclusive curb rights to shuttle companies, and according to that industry's
largest firm, Supershuttle, the total market has expanded at these airports (Klein, 1997).
Competition would be expected to bring the fare level down to an efficient level and
solve the problem of oversupply. Initially, this same solution of leasing counter space
would also be made to apply to town cars. If market entry were deregulated in the near
future, as this study proposes, and a property rights framework to create competition
was implemented, one should eventually expect to see individual companies offering
multiple, differentiated products, so that taxicab service, town car service, and perhaps
even rental car service could all be purchased from the same counter.
<>Deregulating Rates
Removing entry barriers and introducing property rights would create a framework
whereby price competition becomes workable, eliminating the need to regulate rates. To
facilitate fare comparisons, however, taxicab companies should be required to use some
uniform measure (e.g. one-fifth of a mile) for distance-based fares. Rates would have to
be posted on vehicles, but they would no longer have to be filed with the Supervisor.
Zonal fares, time of day premiums, and other fare mechanisms would also be permitted.
<>Review of Deregulation in Other Cities
c
Perhaps the most comprehensive studies of prior attempts at market entry and fare
deregulation were performed by Frankena and Pautler (1984), Teal and Berglund (1987)
and Price Waterhouse (1993). These studies analyzed the effects of taxicab
deregulation in 21 cities to determine the extent that benefits predicted by economists in
fact materialized. These benefits were thought to include more taxicab service and faster
response times, reduced monopoly concentration, lower fares, and improved service.
Following are some key findings of these studies:
1. Number of taxicabs
All studies note that taxicab supply increased dramatically, and that much of this new
supply was directed to already over-served airports where wait times for customers were
already short (as is currently happening in Portland). All authors note that potential price
and service competition was effectively eliminated by continued enforcement of first-in
first-out queues. Frankena and Pautler (1984) report that supply increases caused
taxicab insurance rates to decline due to increased group rate discounts.
2. Market concentration
Frankena and Pautler (1984) report that market share held by the three largest firms in
each city declined substantially. Although Price Waterhouse (1993) does not specifically
mention market concentration, its finding that most new entrants were primarily
independents (few new companies formed) would logically imply decreased monopoly
power.
c
3. Response times
Whereas Price Waterhouse (1993) reports that response times "were similar to pre-
deregulation performance", Frankena and Pautler (1984) and Cervero (1997), report that
25
c
response times declined dramatically in the cities they studied (e.g. Seattle, San Diego,
and Indianapolis).
c
4. Fare levels
Price Waterhouse (1993) reports that fares increased in every case, and cite the
persistence of mechanisms that work against price shopping (i.e. first-in first-out queues)
as the culprit. Frankena and Paulter (1984) note that fare increases were lower than
what would have been predicted based on trends over the prior 10-year period. Price
Waterhouse (1993) also notes substantial variance in fares among cabs. Frankena and
Pautler (1984) suggest that because in most cities taxicabs were required to charge a
uniform set of fares, some taxicabs that served markets with more elastic (price-
sensitive) demand and airport markets probably established some average rate, which
would be lower than that for airport-only providers.
5. Service
All studies report of short-haul trip refusals, though this rate is not compared to pre-
deregulation. Cervero (1997) reports that redlining or refusing to serve minority
neighborhoods was not a noticeable problem.
The fact that all the benefits anticipated from competition did not materialize should
actually come as no surprise, as in fact, competition was not allowed to happen by
design, showing how competition and deregulation are not one and the same, and
pointing to the critical importance of establishing property rights at taxicab stands. By
continuing to enforce first-in first-out queues at taxicab stands, cities only allowed more
taxicabs to jump on a gravy train that had its brakes removed. What is peculiar,
however, is that while all the authors identify the taxicab stands as being at the root of
problems encountered, none seriously question the value of lumping all the providers
together in the first place.
<>Conclusions
c
Because of regulations that restrict entry, increase waiting times, and raise fares, the
number of taxicab trips taken in Portland is inefficiently low. Because of regulations that
inhibit ride sharing, increase trips without return fares (or "deadheading"), and increase
the time that drivers spend waiting in queues, the cost of producing taxicab trips is
unnecessarily high. Finally, a lack of effective competition has created shortages of
certain types of service (e.g. short trips) and stifled innovation. As a result, these
regulations have reduced industry employment and have transferred wealth from
consumers to entrenched taxicab companies, with a disproportionate impact falling on
the poor.
This study does not call for more or "better" regulations. Instead, this paper argues that
an improved taxicab market can arise by removing regulation and promoting
competition. Elements of this proposal have been tested in places such as Indianapolis,
Washington D.C., Denver, Phoenix, and other cities, where deregulation has revived
local taxicab markets.
Under the proposed system, one which fosters true competition and self-regulation, the
only requirements for market entry might be a valid drivers license, vehicle insurance
and registration, and safety certification. Industry competition and self-regulation would
avail the City from having to investigate complaints such as drivers having "grungy attire"
and ensuring that lost and found items are recorded and handled correctly. Similarly, the
City would not have to tell drivers to keep their cars clean, and not to use them to
commit crimes. Instead, taxicab companies would have incentives to voluntarily provide
information regarding fares, amenities, and accident records to groups like the Oregon
26
c
Visitors Association, local business groups, senior citizen organizations, and the pUblic
in general.
..........................................................................................................................-.......-............................................................................--..........
Exhibit 1 : Market Share of Three Largest Taxicab Companies
c
c
27
CiliJ
. htry Relula....
Exilibit 1
Mullet SlJliJe tl/7Jvee Luge...t Taxicab QI01j1ll1Jie.r #
I"" p.._.. ~ :
p.,uIatIoa p.,ulalleaper Lecal perTuIaII .lIUpe__ ,nree Celllplly
(..........) s...,re MiIll TuIe_ (tlulus....) J\IIawM! Market sUre
.....................................................................................................
c
. .
. . ......................
412 . ....-..........-...-..............
Albu'lu.r'lu.b 3,116 133. 3.10 N 100,(10%
BollUnor. 703 8,700 1,151 0.61 N 78.63%
............. ..-.-....--................... . . .................... ...-............ .........-................................................ ..............................
Chorlott. 438 2,.513 4j() 097 N 48.89%
............2,i3:2 .-.......... ~.........-...................,........ ..................... ........................................
Chicago 12,025 5,700 0.48 Y 75.23%
Columbu. 636 3,332 500 1.27 Y 54.60%
...........................................................................................................................................
DolIu 1,023 2,988 1,848 0055 N 37 .34%
Denver 494 3,222 842 0059 N 88.12%
D.l:oit 992 7,152 1,310 0.76 Y 69.08%
E1 Pa.o 579 2,359 2j() 2.32 N 60.00%
F on Worth 452 1,608 170 2.66 N 100.00%
Hou.ton 1,702 3,152 2,067 0.82 Y 78.86%
Long B.ach 434 8,680 105 4.13 N 100.00%
Lo. Ang.I.. 3,449 7,349 2,084 1.65 N <UJ.74%
Milwauk.. 617 6,420 321 1.92 Y 79.44%
C N.wYork' 7,333 23,739 12,187 0.60 Y 4.10%
Philad.lphia 1,524 11,281 1,444 1.06 N 3296%
Portland 451 3,617 317 1.42 N 94.01%
San Antonio 999 3,000 590 1.69 N 45.59%
San Di.go 1,152 3,556 870 1.32 Y 42.76%
SeatU. 521 6,210 643 0.81 N 65.47%
Opea Extry
Fresno 387 3,905 j() 7.74 N 66.00%
Indianapoli.d 752 2,079 398 1.89 Y 49.75%
Kansas City 444 1,425 360 1.23 y 67.78%
Pho.nix' 1,049 2,498 Unknown Unknown Y Unknown
San Francisco 735 15,739 995 0.74 y 48.84%
San J os. 817 4,769 m 1.56 N 78.10%
ruc.oJ 435 2,783 Unknown Unknown Y Unkno
Virginia Beach 430 1,732 39 11.03 Y 10000%
c
50UlC..: 1996 Statistical Ab.t...,t of the U nit.d Stat..; S1llVOY re.wt.
. The.. fJglllOS do hOt account for i1lega1 taxicab., or companies with monopoly power tllatleaw taxicabs idle.
· Only two large fums in the IMlkel.
< Dispatching prolubited for taxicab..
· One large flrm (111) and one rnedium..iz.dfll1\l (21);lot. ofi1ldepeJldents.
. Compo. flIo for a busiJ1es. Iic....; hO recolds kept for total lIumber ofwhicles. 537 whicles for 3lupst fleets.
f Compo. file fora buiness Iic....; no recolds kept for total lIumber ofwhicles. 143 whicles fbr21uptt fleets.
. .................................
28
,-"
L
<>Exhiblt 2: Comparison of Taxicab Rates
c
c
29
........................................................ ................... ........................................................................................................................................................
Exhibit 2
Comparison oJTaxicab &us
. FJacDrop : FJacDnp :Me1erRa1e: WoitCllarce e..t.r: e..t.r....JIC
Cllarce . Dfstuc:e : ,er Mile : ,er M1m11e : Ci l' .' Dls....e l' . .
c
ell;)'
'Rate. Recula'"
.~1.b.':''l.U!~'l.U.d
Baltimore
Charlotte
Chicago
Columbus
Dollas
Denver
c
D.l:oit
ElPaso
Fort Worth
Fr.sno
Houston
Long Beach
Lo s Angele s
Milw.ut<ee
New York
Philadelphia
PorUand'
San Antonio
Ra1e
T ·
i~::.n~
.... .Fn.e~
'Maximum
Maximum
'Maximum
.......................
Filed
Maximum
Maximum
Maximum
'Maximum
Maximum
Filed
Maximum
Maximum
Maximum
Maximum
Filed
Maximum
Filed
San Diego'
San Francisco Maximum
San Jose Maximum
S.atUe Maximum
Virginia Beach Maximum
Rales Not ReCula..
..-.....'w;w....
.... ......$i:4O
iJ:iooj
........$6.30.:
SO:25 'S4:30T
$4.81 :
...... .........$00i7.....i~:43..
$0,30 $5.83
$0.20 $4.90
$552
$5.17
$555
$4,90
$6.30
$5.70
$6.95
$6.18
$5.75
$5.85
$6.40
$6.60
$5.25
$5.99
$650
$6.84
$7.10
$4.10
Hsi:ooT
$1.40
$1.35
$1.20
$1.40
...... '$\50
siOiOH
....... ..$I6.fl
$1.50
$180
$1.60
$150
$150
$1.80
$1.50
$1.30
$180
$190
$1.80
$100
$0.23
$0.30
$0.20
$0.30
$0.30
$0.38
$0.30
$0.25
$0.20
$0.20
$0.33
$020
$0.30
$0.19
$0.50
$0.15
...-........................
$20.15
siiOf
$16.21
....................................
$17.60
$17.60
$15.30
..... ...................
$18.39
$i7.30
.........................
$18.60
........ $1:530
$20.20
$18.75
$22.63
$20.08
$18.75
$18.80
$2190
$19.68
$16.50
$20.49
$22.10
$23.18
$22.90
$1225
Indianapolis' Open $6.16 $21.83
Kansas City Open $536 $16.42
Pho .nix Open $5.00 $16.44
T son' Open $559 $18.50
....$i.6O
$2.00 .
$1.50 .
.............0:143..
0.111.
0.000
Source: survey results
. Filed m:I Open rates are weighted avo,. of 3 ~Sl fums' eJCCept whereilldicated
· City trip equal 10 25 miles with 2 minutes of wait time.
< Lollg distOllCe trip equal to II miles with 3 minutes of wait time.
. Weighted avo,. of only two companies in the morbI.
'Weightedavo,. ofoll fInns on file.
f Weighted avo,. ofolle large fum (1 n) aM Olle medillll\-.ized fum(21).
· Weighted avo,. oflwo largest fInns
c
$1.40 .
$1.20 .
$1.50 .
$1.90 .
$1.50 .
$1.90
$1.90
$1.75
$2.00
$1.80
$2001$250
$1.60
0.143.
0.000
0.000
0.125.
0.100
0.111
0.200
0.167
0.200
0.167
0.067
0.000
$1.70
$1.90
$1.80
$100
0167
0.100
0.111
0.200
30
,..-
L
<>Sources
c
Allen, James J. Regulation of Taxicabs in the City of Portland: Review and
Recommendations (Volumes I, II, III). Prepared for the City of Portland, Oregon Bureau
of Planning. 1978
Arrington, G.B. Director of Strategic Planning, Tri-Met. Address to Central City Transit
Plan Citizens Task Force. February 3, 1998
Bogue, Philip R. "Tri-Met welcomes competition to enhance mobility in the region." The
Oregonian. October 14, 1997
Bussell, David. Owner-Driver, Radio Cab Co. Interview with author. February 1, 1998
Cambridge Systematics. 1996 Enplanement Study.
Cervero, Robert. Paratransit in America. Praeger Publishers; Westport, CT. 1997
Cogan, Matthew A. and Cambridge Systematics. The Peer Analysis Report Prepared for
the Port of Portland. April 1997
Dempsey, Paul Stephen. "Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation: the
Paradox of Market Failure." Transportation Law JoumaI24(1) Summer 1996: 73-120.
Downs, Anthony. Stuck in Traffic: Coping with Peak-Hour Traffic Congestion. Brookings
Institute Press; Washington D.C. 1992
Entler, Steve. General Manager, Radio Cab Co. Interview with author. December 19,
1997
Francesconi, Jim. "Francesconi Says Editorial Unfair". The Portland Skanner. December
3, 1997
Frankena, M. and PA Pautler. An Economic Analysis of Taxicab Regulation. Staff
Report of the Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade Commission. Washington D.C.
1984
Gaunt, Clive and Terry Black. "The Unanticipated Effects of the Industry Commission's
Recommendations on the Regulation of the Taxicab Industry." Economic Analysis &
Policy 24(2) September 1994: 151-170.
Hackner, Jonas and Sten Nyberg. "Deregulating Taxi Services: A Word of Caution."
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 29(2) May 1995: 195-207.
Hall, Christopher D. The Uncertain Hand: Hong Kong Taxis and Tenders. The Chinese
University Press; Hong Kong. 1996
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. "Taxicabs and Livability." Portland
State University. 1996
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Personal communication with
author. October 23, 1997(a)
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Smart Cab Application
Supplement. November 4, 1997(b)
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Personal Communication with
author. December 29, 1997(c)
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Biennial Taxicab Demand Study.
December 31, 1997(d)
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Personal Communication with
author. January 7, 1998(a)
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Personal Communication with
author. January 16, 1998(b)
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Personal communication with
author. February 7, 1998(c)
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Personal communication with
author. February 18, 1998(d)
c
31
c
Hamilton, John. City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor. Personal communication with
author. March 11, 1998( e)
Kirby, Ronald F. and others. Para-Transit: Neglected Options for Urban Mobility. The
Urban Institute; Washington D.C. 1974
Klein, Daniel B., Adrian T. Moore and Binyam Reja. Curb Rights. Brookings Institution
Press; Washington D.C. 1997
Nelson, Pauline. Port of Portland Ground Transportation Unit. Personal communication
with author. February 9, 1998
Oliv,er, Gordon. "Town cars muddy the waters of Portland taxi r~gulation." The Sunday
Oregonian. December 21, 1997
Oregon Employment Department. Oregon Wage Information - 1995
Oregonian editorial. "Loosen transit reins." The Sunday Oregonian. September 18, 1997
Parente, Michele. "Portland moves to open taxi market." The Oregonian. November 13,
1997
Parente, Michele. "Portland council edits taxicab rules." The Oregonian. December 18,
1997
Parente, Michele. "More taxis in Portland's future?" The Oregonian. January 8, 1998
Parente, Michele. "Taxicab applications flood city in-box." The Oregonian. February 4,
1998.
Parente, Michele. "Board: City will fare better with more cabs." The Oregonian. April 2,
1998.
Price Waterhouse Office of Government Services. Analysis of Taxicab Deregulation and
Re-Regulation Prepared for the International Taxicab Foundation. Washington D.C.
1993
Rose, Michael. "Hacks ready to attack new cab rival." The Business Journal of Portland.
July 25, 1997
Rose, Michael. "Squeeze time for town cars." The Business Journal of Portland. January
9, 1998
Rose, Michael. "Ex-cabbies collide with New Rose City." The Business Journal of
Portland. January 30, 1998
Schaller, Bruce and Gorman Gilbert. "Factors of Production in a Regulated Industry:
Improving the Proficiency of New York City Taxicab Drivers." Transportation Quarterly
49(4) Fall 1995: 81-91.
Schaller, Bruce and Gorman Gilbert. "Villain or Bogeyman? New York's Taxi Medallion
System." Transportation Quarterly 50(1) Winter 1996: 91-103.
Schaller, Bruce and Gorman Gilbert. "Fixing New York Taxi Service." Transportation
Quarterly 50(2) Spring 1996: 85-95.
Smart Cab Co., LLC. Application for Taxicab Company Operating Permit. July 1997
Solberg, Bruce. "Bridging the transportation gap." Daily Journal of Commerce.
September 10, 1997
Taylor, D. Wayne. "The Economic Effects of the Direct Regulation of the Taxicab
Industry in Metropolitan Toronto." Logistics and Transportation 25(2) June 1989: 169-
181.
Teal, Roger F. and Mary Berglund. "The Impacts of Taxicab Deregulation in the USA."
Journal ofTransport Economics and Policy eJ (1) January 1987: 37-55.
Tri-Met Operating Budget for Fiscal Year 1997-1998
Tri-Met Working and Wage Agreement. December 1,1994 - November 30,1998
U.S. Bureau of the Census. Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1996 (116th
edition). Washington D.C. 1996
Webber, Melvin M. "The Marriage of Autos and Transit: How to Make Transit Popular
Again." Access 5 Fall 1994: 27-31.
"......
L
c
32
c
Williams, David J. "Information and Price Determination in Taxi Markets." Quarterly
Review of Economics and Business 20(4) Winter 1980: 36-43.
WOhl, Martin and Chris Hendrickson. Transportation Investment and Pricing Principles.
John Wiley and Sons; New York, NY. 1984
<>Appendix A - Taxicab Industry Contacts
c
Vivian Allison, City of Detroit Consumer Affairs
Paulette Braithwaite, City of Virginia Beach Special Events/Film Office
Terry Brown, City of San Jose Police Department
Dolores Butcher, City of Tucson Business Licenses
Jim Copeland, City of Milwaukee License Division
Julia Craig, City of Charlotte Taxicab Inspectors Office
Blanton Daniels, City of Houston Transportation Division
Anna Deosdade, City of San Antonio Police Department
Ceci Flores, City of EI Paso Police Department, Vehicles For Hire
Jaunice Floyd, City of Long Beach Business Licenses Department
Alan Fromberg, City of New York Taxi and Livery Commission
Sharon Gadd, City of Columbus Public Safety Department, License Section
Gary Gramlick, Colorado Public Utilities Commission
Mary Beth Haley, City of Dallas Transportation Regulation
John Hamilton, City of Portland Taxicab Supervisor, Bureau of Licenses
Sant R. Harrison, Pennsylvania Public Utilities Commission, Bureau of Transportation
and Safety
Robin Hunt, Yellow Cab Inc., Indianapolis, Indiana
Jeannie Lee, City of Los Angeles Department of Transportation
Craig Leisy, City of Seattle Consumer Affairs Unit
Barbara Lupro, City of San Diego Metropolitan Transit Development Board
Vince Martinez, New Mexico State Corporation Commission
Leon Molina, City of Fresno
Richard Page, Maryland Public Service Commission
Steve Patterson, City of Chicago Department of Consumer Affairs
Sandra Ramirez, Strategic Planning, Arizona Department of Motor Vehicles
Danny Reed, City of Fort Worth
Sg!. Vincent Simpson, City of San Francisco Police Department
Floyd Underwood, City of Kansas City Taxicab Permits
<>Appendix B - Sample Survey
c
Hello. My name is John Boroski and I am an Urban and Regional Planning student at
Portland State University. As part of my thesis research, I am conducting a national
survey of taxicab companies and regulators so that I may gain a better understanding of
taxicab regulation, and the general degree of innovation within the paratransit industry .
Please take a few minutes to complete the following survey. Questions and completed
surveys can be directed to me at:
Phone:
Fax:
E-Mail:
Mail:
34
c
B. Large, expensive, classic or vintage vehicle commonly recognized by the limousine
industry as a limousine or executive vehicle.
C. Vehicles impeccably clean and rigorously maintained.
D. Passenger amenities, including but not limited to, luxury upholstery, halo lighting, sun
roof, telephone, television, or other amenities.
E. Except as provided in subparagraph f., below, service by reservation only (for
example, not to be hailed on the street) means restricted to requests by prior
arrangement.
F. Service may be made available on demand for transportation originating at the
Portland Intemational Airport, but only if such service is provided pursuant to a written
contract between the Port of Portland and the Luxury Transportation provider and such
service is in accordance with all of the other criteria contained in paragraphs a., b., c., d.,
e., and g.
G. Premium rates (i.e., rates which are consistently and substantially higher than the
prevailing rates charged by licensed taxicab companies within the City of Portland).
c
Shuttle Transportation: Transportation provided in a motor vehicle:
A. Over a fixed route and time schedule; or,
B. Other than a fixed route and time schedule for:
1. Transportation originating at Portland International Airport; or,
2. Transportation originating in the City of Portland where the destination is Portland
International Airport; and,
3. Only if the transportation provider has a valid Port of Portland
Ordinance 351 Permit; and,
4. The shuttle operator provides regular, ongoing transportation service
with a vehicle used exclusively for shuttle service where service at a
minimum includes:
a. Van(s) or bus(es), commonly recognized by the industry as "shuttle" transportation
vehicles, capable of carrying multiple passengers and their luggage; and,
b. Vehicles maintained in a clean and safe condition; and,
c. The full name and telephone number of the service company permanently displayed
on the outside of the vehicle, on both sides, and the phrase, "airport shuttle," included
either as part of the company name, or as a description of the type of service provided;
and,
d. A vehicle that is not equipped with a fare meter or top light normally utilized by
permitted taxicabs; and,
e. Service by prior day reservation only, meaning restricted to requests by prior day
arrangement, except that service may be made available on demand when originating at
the Portland International Airport; and,
f. Established rates, when compared on a single-passenger basis, that are consistently
and substantially lower than the maximum meter rate allowed by Taxicab Regulations;
and,
g. Service is multi-stop, shared-ride service, and does not promise direct non-stop
service.
<>Endnotes
c
1 For the purposes of this paper, taxicab service is defined as service which the
"average" consumer might enjoy, and hence does not directly address issues particular
to agency requested transportation (ART) or specially attended transportation (SAT).
35
c
2 Vehicles must be less than five years old, and companies must provide proof of
insurance and a $1,000 deposit.
3 Legal definitions distinguishing "shuttle service" and "luxury transportation" from
taxicab service are included in Appendix C.
4 At low speeds, generally less than 10 mph (the "crossover point"), the meter switches
from calculating mileage to calculating time.
5 Taxicabs are permitted to use the bus lanes for through travel from 7:00 p.m. to 6:00
a.m. Monday through Friday, and all day on Saturdays, Sundays, and on holidays. Town
cars, however, are currently prohibited from using the bus lanes at any time.
6 See the list of survey respondents in Appendix A.
7 This includes federal, state, and local govemment operating subsidies and capital
grants.
8 As evidence, the mode share of work trips in the Portland MSA for mass transit fell in
1980-1990 from 8.4% to 5.4%, while the share for carpool was relatively stable. Metro-
wide, the 1990 carpool share was 12.3%. Unfortunately, a separate figure for taxicabs is
not available.
9 Most full-time drivers already have three or more years of experience, at which point
they are at the top of the pay scale.
10 Tellingly, literature provided by the Department lists bus and taxi drivers together
under the same job profile, #6142, as they require the same aptitudes (eye-hand-foot
coordination, quick reflexes, ability to judge distances, etc.).
11 Section 16.40.001 (Purpose) of the Code, amended in December 1997.
121n addition to the cities listed in Exhibits 1 and 2, Jacksonville, New Orleans,
Memphis, and Washington D.C were also contacted but declined to respond. A sample
survey is included in Appendix B.
13 City of Portland regulatory staff sometimes use the term "public utility" to denote
"common carrier".
14 Many regulators rely on data from other cities to establish fleet sizes and fare levels.
15 The Taxicab Board of Review has never defined what this means exactly (Hamilton,
1998e). While this requirement could be operationalized, it does point out a complication
of the regulatory approach. The fact that this requirement exists at all, however, seems
to acknowledge that a monopoly market structure exists.
16 For an excellent review of the causes of congestion and potential solutions, readers
are encouraged to read Anthony Downs' Stuck in Traffic.
17 Similarly, the direct and more equitable approach to reducing problems of aggressive
driving is strict enforcement of traffic regulations.
18 To a certain extent, then, the goal of creating a market where consumer and producer
benefits are maximized is pursued only insofar as it is convenient to do so (which also
explains the establishment of uniform rates, which are easier to administer).
19 Pedestrians attempting to signal the attention of a passing taxicab are likely to be
greeted with a polite nod of the head, a blank stare, or complete disregard as the empty
vehicle passes them by. Local industry representatives reply that residents of west coast
cities "are simply not used to hailing cabs", and therefore taxicab drivers "are not used to
looking for hailers" (Allen, 1978; Entler, 1997; Hamilton, 1997a). Yet in San Diego, for
instance, which has a population density similar to that of Portland but has a much less
concentrated industry, actual survey data reports over 8% of total trips are street hails.
20 This is demonstrated by the success of low-cost, no-frills airline service after
deregulation in that industry.
21 In comparison, licenses in Indianapolis, which has an open entry policy, cost only
$102.
c
c
36
-^'
L
22 This cost will fluctuate to reflect the condition of the vehicle, which is transferred with
the license. Other equipment such as taximeters and topl/ghts are supplied by the
company for quality control. While Radio Cab does not buy back its licenses, its
members must approve any new owner-drivers, who must have driven at least 6 months
for the company.
23 As most cities restrict entry and service, most of these fares will be inefficiently high,
and market conditions vary too much from city to city to make direct comparison
possible.
24 A high concentration of market power, which has not changed significantly in the last
20 years, encouraged Portland's two largest taxicab companies to trade days at high-
yield taxicab stands in the past, which had been segregated for exclusive company use
presumably to foster competition (Allen, 1978).
25 One only need look to the airline industry, where huge up-front fixed costs were also
presumed to be insurmountable, to see how deregulation can entice new entrants to
provide traditional and niche services efficiently and profitably.
26 The hypothetical airport trip modeled for Portland also does not include the airport
gate fee which customers are required to pay.
27 The current maximum flag drop of $2.50 actually represents a reduction from a
suggested drop charge of $5.00 (a Board recommendation; Hamilton, 1998d).
28 One can only imagine the public outcry that would result, for instance, if new policies
required rental car customers, upon deplaning, to wait in a line and to accept the first
vehicle that approached them (perhaps all vehicles would be Geo Metro's) at some fixed
price; yet this is exactly the manner in which taxicabs are deployed.
._.._~-_..-----.._-~--~._-~.-....~_...---.._.~.-._.~_.-
c
Founded in 1991, Cascade Policy Institute is Oregon's premier policy research center.
Cascade's mission is to explore private, voluntary ideas that strengthen Oregon's
economy, support personal responsibility, and secure individual freedom.
To that end Cascade publishes studies, organizes public forums, and provides speakers.
Focusing on local and state issues, Cascade provides practical solutions for concerned
citizens, policy-makers and the media.
A 501 (c)(3) nonprofit organization, Cascade neither solicits nor accepts government
funding, but instead relies entirely on private contributions.
Nothing written here should be construed as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of
any legislation or as and endorsement of any candidate or initiative.
.------~~-_....._._'......_____....."_._.h........._......h......~__..--...-.------~~-"'"""""'..--.-._._................~.~_._.~......_w~~,,____....
Cascade Policy Institute 813 S. W. Alder, Suite 450 Portland, OR 97205
Phone: (503) 242-0900
send mail to info@CascadePolicv.ofQ
Go to Cascade home Daoe
Return to Index of TAXI-L Sianificant Documents
c
o
o
1
o
c
yF~
(
1312 W Brooks St., Ontario, CA 91762. (909) 391-1434i\ (909) 391-2178 (fax)
City of San Dimas
City Hall
245 East Bonita Ave.
San Dimas, CA 92418
RECEIVED
FEB 12 1998
CITy UI"
w..u .....,,~ '_
The Honorable Mayor Curtis W. Morris and
Members of the San Dimas City Council
This application is a formal request to provide quality taxicab service to the City of San
Dimas.
Bell Cab Company will provide safe reliable and quality taxicab service Three Hundred
Sixty-Five Days Q Year and Twenty-Four Hours Q Day. The Senior Management at Bell
Cab Company has in excess of 1 00 Years experience in the taxicab business and in
managing local community Dial-A-Ride and Senior Transportation programs. Bell Cab
Company provides superior taxicab service in three Southern California Counties (Los
Angeles, San Dimas, and Riverside) encompassing over fifty cities.
c
APPLICANT
San Gabriel Transit
1312 W. Brooks St.
Ontario, Ca. 91762
Corporate Location
San Gabriel Transit
2623 River Avenue
Rosemead, Ca 91770
818-307-1510 / 818-307-1529 (fax)
Federal Tax I.D.:
95-1771822
Place and date of Incorporation:
ArcadiaCA. Sept 19,1953
Color Scheme Name and Monogram
Bell Cab Company vehicles have a white body with a distinctive cranberry red
roof. Our corporate logo is a Cranberry Red decal of the Liberty Bell located on
the rear passenger doors.
c
\
r-'
'-
YF~
1312 W Brooks St., Ontario, CA 91762. (909)391-1434.& (909) 391-2178 (fax)
Principal OffIcers
President
Senior Vice-President
Timmy Mardirossian
11061 Leolang Ave
Sunland, Ca. 91040
DLN: N7591648
D.0.B.3-21-52
S,S. 529 98 0483
Richard "Duke" Perrin
6322 Princeville Circle
Huntington Beach, Ca. 92648
DLN. H0545422 .
D.0.B.9-1O-42
S.S. 573 54 1702
Metro Access
San Gabriel Transit (Bell Cab) is the current Metro Access provider of
transportation for the San Gabriel Valley area including San Dimas, San Gabriel
Transit provides over 1000 trips a month to disabled residents in San Dimas and
received local taxicab licensing will facilitate better response time and higher
service levels.
c
Vehicles
Bell Cab Company would request a license for twenty vehicles for local service to
the City of San Dimas and Metro Access, This would allow our company to
provide outstanding service to the City of San Dimas twenty-four hours a day,
three hundred sixty-ftve days a year. There would be no congestion of service or
vehicles due to the fact that these vehicles would provide service for the whole
Pomona Valley Region.
San Dimas Dla/.A-c.b
Bell Cab Company would welcome the opportunity to also provide community
Dial.A-Cab services through the Pomona Valley Transit Authority. Our drivers
receive special training to work with the frail. elderly and handicapped and we
believe our company could enhance the quality of service that the seniors
critically need.
San Dimas Community Hospital
The staff of San Dimas Community Hospital has contacted Bell Cab Company in
order to provide a variety of critically important transportation services.
c
. Social Services
. Emergency Room
. Volunteer Services
. Day Surgery
. Outpatient Services
c y..~
1312 W Brooks St., Ontario. CA 91762. (909) 391-1434~ (909) 391-2178 (fax)
Dispatching
All Bell Cab Company vehicles will be computer-dispatched in San Dimas to
ensure safe, prompt, and reliable service.
Rates
Bell Cab Company operates at a meter rate as follows:
. $1.90 Flag Drop
. $1. 60 per mile
Bell Cab Company also provides Senior C/dzen Discounts and low flat rates to
common destinations.
c
Operating Trade Name
Bell Cab Company
1312 W. Brooks St.
Ontario, Ca. 91762
Office:
Dispatch:
Fax:
909391 1434
909 808 1111
9093912178
Current Ucens/ng In San Bernadino County
. Chino
. Chino Hills
. Ontario
. Upland
. Orand Terrace
. Highland
. Loma Linda
. Red1ands
. Rialto
. Yuciapa
. San Bernadino County
c
c
Ya~
2e23 RIvw A...... R_, ~.81no. Telephone (818) 307-1810. Fox (818) 307.1828
Restaurants
A Critical transportation issue is the ability to provide responsible safe and efficient
service to all restaurants and establishments that serve alcoholic beverages. Our
company has an extensive history of proactive involvement in community based
programs which discourage drunk driving.
Our management has contacted the agencies listed below and will work proactively with
them towards this goal.
. San Dimas Sheriff's Department
Community Relations Department
Deputy Ella Cook
. Local Chapters of Students Against Drunk Driving
. Local Chapter of Mothers Against Drunk Driving
C Our management has visited and spoken to all of the local managers of the following
restaurants and without exception an of these businesses support additional taxicab
service.
. Applebee's Grin and Bar
. Bl's Family Restaurant
. Casa Del Rey
. Cask N Cleaver
. Pinnacle Peak Restaurant
. Red Robin Restaurant
· Mayan Mexican Grin
. The Pizza Place
. Zendeja's Restaurant
. San Dimas Canyon Clubhouse
. San Dimas Canyon Golf Course
. Via Verde Country Club
c
Wheelchair Accesslbl.Taxlcabs
BELL Cab Company is the largest provider of wheelchair accessible taxicab services in
Los Angeles County. BELL Cab Company will provide wheelchair acceSSIble taxicabs
for residents and visitors the City of San Dimas for the physically handicapped.
c
~
Y1l.~
2823 RI\w A...... R__, c_ 91770. r..- (818) 307-1810. Fox (818) 307-1829
Non Smoking Taxicabs
BELL CAB COMPIlR\' has designated over half of its fleet as smoke free vehicles. This
program has been developed in partnership with the American Cancer Society.
Infant Seats
BELL CAB COMPIlR\' supplies infant car seats upon request Not only is this policy in
compliance with the laws of California, it is in keeping with our corporate philosophy of
our commitment to safety.
Taxicabs have become increasingly utilized as a transportation resource for parents to
assist in their transportation requests with the young children.
c
BELL CAB COMPItIn' has transported Downs Syndrome Infants for the
California Regional Centers for the Developmentally Disabled for years.
Unifonns: Driver's Appearance
BELL CAB COMPIlR\' requires its drivers to maintain a proper appearance at all times.
Drivers must be clean shaven and well groomed at all times. Uniform standards are:
. Clean White Dress Shirt
. Black Necktie
. Black Shoes
. Black Belt
. Dark Trousers
Dispatchers and field supervisors monitor compliance with the established dress code on
an ongoing basis and have the authority to send a driver home who is not in proper
uniform.
BELL Cab Company Management is currently reviewing these policies to further
upgrade the image of its taxicab drivers to the public at large.
c
".-"",
v-.;-~
=~.
:le23 RhIor A..... R_ c_lI1m. TIlopMw (818) 307-1510. FlIX (818) 307-15211
\-
Population/Demographics
There are currently only two legally licensed IilXlcabs allowed to provide taxlcab -
service In the Qty 01 San DlmDS.
Po ulation
September 1969
Two Taxicabs
12,100
c
Asof Population
March 1998 35,100
Two Taxicabs
Research from the City of San Dimas Planing Department and the City of San Dimas
Public Library and San Dimas Chamber of Commerce confirms a 300% increase in
population in the thirty years that Yellow Cab has provided service to the City of San
Dimas. Keep in mind these facts:
· 300% increase in population
· A current stable and growing labor force of 14,470
· One of the lowest unemployment rates in Los Angeles and San Bernadino
County areas. (3.1 %)
· In the last thirty years, Yellow Cab IuJs not provided OM additional
taxicab to seIW the resldenls and businesses 01 San DlINIS 011 a twenty-
lOll, IHIsis.
· Since 1986 there have been over 30,000 subsidized DIal A Cab trips a
. year.
· Over 2500 subsidized trips a year are provided in taxicabs for the
popular Get About program.
c
,...-
\.-
Ya~
21123 R'- A_ R--. ~ 81770. T~ (818) 307-1810. Fill (818) 307-1e:z11
Metro Access
I have already submitted average monthly ridership statistics which support ~ strong and
stable ridership for residents in the City of San Dimas. It is critical to quality service that
our company be allowed to locate our taxicab drivers physically in the City of San Dimas
to ensure timely and better levels of service for the frail and disabled.
Metrollnk
Metrolink Rail Service commenced operations in October 1992. The City of San Dimas
through this service is provided local commuter rail services from both the Covina
Metrolink and the Pomona Metrolink Station that provides connections to practically
every major point of commerce in Southern California.
It would therefore be essential for both local taxicab companies to develop low cost
feeder service lor potential rail rlthrs olthe City 01 StuI D/1tUU.
c
Bell Cab Company has historically marketed low cost Metrolink shuttle services with
taxicabs and vans and will in conjunction with the South Coast Air Quality Management
District offer these services to both large and small employers in the City of San Dimas.
San Dimas Dial A Cab
The City of San Dimas Dial A Cab Program started service in December of 1986.
. System ridership in the first few years averaged between 400 to 700 rides per
month.
. Ridership has increased to 2500 to 3000 rides per month with only two licensed
taxicabs.
· Ridership has fluctuated because of fee based changes instituted by the Pomona
Valley Transit Authority.
· Bell Cab Company would also like to provide contract Dial A Cab Services to the
City of San Dimas for this important and essential community program.
· Our staff research indicated numerous service delays in the program from staff at
the San Dimas Senior Citizen Community Center - (909) 394-6290.
· Muldple provl4enlor tills DUll A Cab Program would stllltllltW betUr levels 01
service lor the rlthrs and ensure lower 10"1 term costs/or tills program
c
,,-.
'-
c
c
ya-~
2Il23 R'- A_ _. ~ 91770. Toiophono (818) 307.1510. Fox (818) 307.1B2ll
Bonita Unified School district
Our Staffhas been contacted by the Special Education Department of the Bonita Unified
School District.
Mr. Dave Kempf
Ms. Susan Liston
Taxicabs are used individually on specific cases to provide specialized transportation to
schools in and outside the district.
There are 1200 special edllCadon students In Stilt DllIUIS tJult require some lorm 01
nontradJdoltal trtIlISpOrtadon, The transportation department for the Bonita Unified
School District has identified the fact that some trips, due to a child's specific disability,
are uniquely suited to the individual attention that a taxicab driver can provide. Our
drivers receive special training to cope with a variety of disabilities.
,
Managed Levels of Competition
Bell Cab Company is not a supporter of market deregulation but strongly opposes
monopolies tIuU result In lower levels 01 sel'l'ice, minimal marketing and lead to hostage
pricing by service companies and taxicab operators. Reasonable levels of competition
lead to higher levels of service, stable consumer prices better accessibility to taxicabs and
availability at all times of the day,
/--
yfrrp
2ll2l Ri>w A_ R__. ~ 81770. T%phano (818) 307-1510. Fill (818) 307-1521l
\.-
Get About
The city of San Dimas is also provided local contract transportation services through
Pomona Valley Transit Authority using the popular Get Abollt.
This service is provided by contract through Mayflower. Due to the constraints and the
regional popularity of the Get About system, there are an additionally several hundred
trips a month that Mayflower contracts out for overflow service to Yellow Cab
Bell Cab Company could provltk critical support se1Vices in tuIdltionlor tM Gel About
Program.
Hospitals I Medical Clinics
Our management has met with the following locations with respect to additional taxicab
services for their patients.
c
. California Prostate Center
. San Dimas Community Hospital
. Family Medical Clinic
. Casa Bonita Convalescent Hospital
Hospitals and Clinics utilize taxicabs extensively for a variety of transportation needs
. Day Surgety
. Therapy Appointments
. Emergency Room Services
. Volunteer Transportation
. Lab Specimen Deliveries
Wlthout exception, all olthese lacmties have expressed II desire lor tuIdltional se1Vices.
Alzheimer's Care and Assisted Living Center
This project initiated by the Community Development Department is a 2.9-acre site near
North San Dimas Avenue. I have spoken to city planner Craig Hensley and he believes
transportation is a critical cornerstone to this proposed project
c
c
~~tQ
ra~.
2e23 Rtwr A_ _..ood. C_ 81770. r..- (818) 307-1510. Fox (818) 307-162ll
Summary
Our management, drivers and dispatch personnel look forward to the opportunity to
provide quality community taxicab services to the residents, visitors and businesses of the
City of San Dimas.
I appreciate all of the support that the city staff has afforded me in the research on this
issue. On behalf ofBeU Cab Company, I look forward to doing business in the City of
San Dimas.
Yellow Cab wiD "",Ice statemmts that there Is not addJdo1UJl busilfDl to :support an
adJlitio1UJl taxicab operator. .
Those statemenlS are clearly not tnu.
Sincerely,
c
~
Scott Schaffer
Executive Vice President
Bell Cab Company
c
;J'.'-'
~
c
c
. ..CI.~ ~
ta~
21123 _ A....... R__, ~ 81no. TIIIphono (818) 307-1810. Fa (818) 307-1828
San Dimas Chamber of Commerce
And Community Organizations .
Bell Cab Company is the only taxicab operator thst is a member of the LoI181 San Dimas Chamber of
Commerce, lilt DUllllpI. of OAr collllllJtmau to 'M CIty of SlUt Di_
This proposal alone demonstrates the importance of outreach and marketing. Education
and information will allow the end user to familiarize themselves with the benefits of
local taxicab services and competition.
Our Firm will also aggressively market our taxicab end ridesharing services to local community
organizations including but not limited to the following:
. San Dimas Lions Club
. San Dimas Merchants Association
. San Dimas Rotary
. Automobile Club of Southem California
. Soroptomist of San Dimas
. San Dimas Chamber of Commerce and Community Organizations
. American Red Cross
. The San Dimas Optimist Club
. McKinley Children's Center
.
These agencies and community groups are essential to informing local residents and
businesses oftbe importance and availability of the quality and the diversity of taxicab
service.
o
c
1
""","
o
FEB~II-2002 MON 05:29 PM LUPE FAX NO, 17603915945 P. 05
2/11/2002 - 17: 17 reporter
07.11.1997 Sun Staff Writer 1- djes ps Cab company will try again for city's OK R ANello
Source=Sun_SlafCWriter; Da
C djcs ps
Cab company will try
again for city's OK RANCHO CUCAMONGA
SHARON CHING
RANCHO CUCAMONOA A taxi gill company plans to return to the City Council soon to try again to offer its
services to residents.
Bell QIll. Co. wants another shot at convincing the council to let it handle fares in Rancho Cucamonga. The City
Council voted 2-1 Wednesday to direct staff to prepare a resolution denying an earlier request.
Mayor Bill Alexander and Councilman Paul Biane said there isu't euough demand 10 support both Bell and the
Yellow rm Co., wbich already operates in the city.
"1 don't think having another cab company in town will generate more taxi trips," Biane said. "1 think in time, a
second company will be needed."
But Councihnan Jim Curata!o wanted to allow Bell Cab Co. into town for a one-year trial period. "I don't have
anything against Y cHow Cab. but we're a growing eity and in a growing region."
Qlh companies must receivc permits from the city before picking up fares. Yellow Cab Co. ofticials said an
oversupply of taxis would mean a loss of business.
c
"A cab can do and must do IS to 20 trips per day for the drivcr and us to make a living," said Brian Hunt of Yellow
Cab Co. "Another gill company... will only cause more vehicles and drivers to share the same number of trips. "
Carol McLean, a Yellow Cab Co. driver, said, "I've seen these guys hijack fares from us. They're trying 10 infiltrate
. our territory."
Bell Cat> Co. officials said many customers are dissatisfied with Yellow Cab Co. and they want to offer riders a
choice.
"rfpeople can't depend on taxi l;lll2:! as a sc..'fvice, they're not going to re-use taxi cabs," said Scott Schaffer, BeWs
~:i:ti;:d::~:eneral ~~~:;~;:: Ontario office, said ~::i~e iSCriti~1 for consumers. "To have a ~ ~
monopoly is not right. When there's no competition, the level of service goes down."
At Wednesday's council meeting, Councilman Rex Gutierrez excused bimsel om
of a conflict of interest. Councilwoman Diane Williams was absent.
ssian bet
The resolution denying Bell Cab Co. permission to pick up Rancho fares is set for the Nov. 19 council meeting
Copyright 1997 The San Bernardino County Sun
Year-1997; Month=11; Month..Nov; Day=7: Day=Fr; Book=B; ZonesWest; Byllne=Chln9_Sharon; Company=Bell..Q.@...
Clty=Rancho_Cucamonga: Slala-Callfornla: Malnkey=GovernmentlCounly ....9overnment/Transportatlon; PhOIO=No;
Graphic-No;
CperOSSk (e) Oigital Collections
Page 1
c
c
c
02/11/02 !ION 17:02 FAX 909 890 3565 P-E SB BUREAU 141004
I, " ..JB~ City Council hears testimony concerning the application from Bell Cab to provide> addipage 10f2
Story S of 10
11~~~~t~~:.tUm to Se1lTc~creen~SnRe Uocumen.~ DUIP~
Aceess #: 220194
Headline: Tul company set to pick up slack The Fontana City Council hears testimony concerninf'
the application from Bell Cab to provide additional service to the city, but no action is taken.
Date: 08/06/98
Credit: The Pres, -Enterprise
SeeUon: LOCAL
Zone; SAN BERNARDINO COUNTY
Pa,e: B02
ByUne; Anne M. Peterson
Subject: FONTA."IA; CITY COUNCIL; TRANSPORTATION
Ke~:TAJaS;PROPOSAL
Leneth: 20
l'OllTANA
Bartender Pam Schmidt says when she calla a cab for one of her
customers at Cherp's Cocktails. she will wait ~rom One to three
hours before a cab driver COmes walkir.g through the d~~r.
Schmidt has come to expect that from the city's curcent
franchie. taxi provider. Yellow Cab Taxi Co. It's a claim company
officials say is inexcusable.
III ha.ve no excuse for th03tl it's not acceptable, II Yl!llow C.a.b
Ol'ller Brian Hunt .lIai~. 'If they are having tbree-hour '~aits. they
need ~not.h.r cab company." H. said average wait8, howel'rer, are leas
than 30 minutes in rontaAa .
Now, with the prospect chat a new taxi company, Sell Cab Co.,
ill vying to provide i!Ldditional service for ront:ana .r.elJident.s and
busines. ~eople, Schmiat gets excited.
"lfe dehnitely need anotber cab .ervice here," saia Schmidt,
who ha.Il worked at Cherp'8 for three ye:.rl8~ "It'e &nywhere from 4n
hour to tbree-ho~r wait. It doesn't It.ake any ditrer"nc!l if it's day
or night.'
OntClrio-based Bell cab Co. riled a francbi.. appU"ation with
Pent an.. in February. But it aidn't go before the rout""" City
Council until Tuesday when council members listened tn more than
three hours of testimony from Sell, Yellow Cab and res;.dents.
Council members, however. delayed any action on the franchi.e
&goreement, pogtponingthe decision from two to four weeks until they
hClve more information.
Bell vice president Scott Schaffer said his taxi C(lmpany
operat... in .ever.l other l.nh.nd Empire citiell. includi.n>r Ontario.
Grand Terrace, Redland., Yucaipa, Corona, Moreno Vallel' and
Highland, ..nd ther.. ill .nough w.j,n.... to 1<;eep more than one t....1
company busy . ,
"il~ c",11 ~a a_.~ol: mor..,\t~ll")l. ~hiM":!S,"h"1'{~~}l.d,
Riight !il1o "~t~../;" be .IIaic1( ~theFe /~'-<l 1oac} !;l:li iI~vl.t'e w..r
t\tl!lir' . a \16t 'QJ. ))Il'l1neQ/ cloet-e." ;/
V y tome council members axen't convinced. th.~X'~ is flnough need
to warrant grant~ng another taxi cab franchi.. . City Manager Frank
Schuma .aid his office will study other citias where two taxi
companies operata and eee if there ara any..roble..... Ir. addition,
he said he wants to take an inrol:Ttlal surveyor those r,'sidents moSt
likely to u.. taxi gervice and eee if there have been many problems
with the exiating service before he makes a recommendation to
accept Bell Cab's francbi.. applicCltion,
In the fraAebi.. agreement with ~ellow Cab, the con~any pays
the city $10 a year per cab to operate in the City. In exchan~e,
Yellow Cab is allowed to pick up and drop off fares within thi city
http://library.pe.coml
2/1 1/02
c
c
c
02111/02 !liON 17: 03 FAX 909 890 3~6~ P-B SB BUREAU ~ OO~
...IB> City COUIlcil hears testimony concerning the application from Bell Cab to provide adcli Page 2 of2
1,>1' .... - -~
limits. Other cab companies are simply allowed to drop off
customers in POlltana but can't pick up 1'0111:.... farell unless they
a~so haye a fr.nc~L.a agreement with the city_
"What I want is what 10 going to b. best for the citizens of
PODtana ," Mayor David Eshleman said.
The mayor suggested creacing a joint powers authorjty with some
surrounding cities in which one company WOuld be granted a
f~.Dohi.e Co operate in five to 10 neighboring citie..
Yellow Cab operates four taxi. in PODtaue 24 hou%s a day. But
SOme customers say four cabs i. not enough.
Schmidt said ahe tells her customers ahead of time they will
have to wait quite awhile for . cab because there are only a few
serving :ronlolUl. .
The citY'a taxi fr.nchise ordinance specifies one taxi for
every 2,000 reaidents 00 that.. maximum of about 54 cab. could
operate in POD!:.... _
Bell Cab has applied to operate 36 cabs in the city, bringing
the total to 40 cabs in rontan. .
"From the testimony I heard, the residents of rontaDa need more
service," Councilman Marl<: Nuaimi ~Qid. 'Whether we do it by adding
another franchi.. or eliminating the franchi.. altogether, it's
clear. If
All council members agree that the city'. taxi fr.~ehi..
o~dinance is outdated and flawed and needa to be overhauled.
Nuaimi said the cab companies could work with the city to mend
th. ordinance so that it's profitable to have mo~e tha~ one company
serving PODt~a .
But Yellow Cab general manager Steven Carrigan said service
decreaaes in any city where more than One taxi companr ie allowed.
"If you hsve one service provider, they'll (custome.s) call
us," h. said. "If you have cwo, they'll call two. Whoe',er gets
there tirst, gets tbe trip. When the service is shared by both
companies it makes both companies weaker."
Hunt ...id the aver.ge .....it for a Yellow Cab i. abOll': ~4 minutes
in J'ont.ana . "If we have an hour wait, that I s: the exceJ~tion, It he
said.
The council will consider the Bell Cab franeh1.. ~'plication
again at the Aug. 16 or Se~t. 1 meeting.
Il!rev~~~ijIK~nim to,Hl~~~CtJ.!m to ~e~I1.~~I~gm!C1.!m~lPtijifa.yl1
http~/mbrary.pe.coml
2/11102
FEB-II-2002 MON 05:28 PM LUPE FAX NO. 17603915945 P. 03
,. \ 2/11/2002 - 17:16 reporter
28:07.1998 San Bernardino County Sun 01 - -b1 w wd Jcs aw Cab company challenges Yellow
SoureeooSan_Bernardlno_Counly_Sun; Oat 28.07.1sl8i Sectlon=Local: Page=01;
c
-bl w wdjes aw
Cab company
challenges
Yellow Qlb
Bell9lll Co. plans to ask three West End cities to allow competition.
KIlRRI GlNIS
~~""'-"'4~_",..~"."..^,--,,,----
~o{.:4'H>AJ1'!
.,-.-'"
2/3A local' company will bid to bccome"[ second taxi service in three West End cities during August, arguing
that the area's growth has raised enough demand to merit competition.
2/3Bell ~ Co. will go before Montclair City Council on Monday, Fontana City Council on Aug. 4 and Rancho
Cucamonga City C.ouncll on Aug. 19. Yellow Qll! Co. holds the sole franchise for each of those communities.
2/3 "We believe the lnlalld Empire is fenile for an additional taXi cab company," said SCOtt Schaffer, exccudve vice
president for Bell Q!h Co. .
213The company previously bid for service in Rancho Cucamonga and failed Fontana city staff has recommended
against approval of a permit.
C 2I3The Fontana City Council discussed the issue July 21, but cOllncil members delayed action while directing a
I subcommiltfJe on economic development to gather more information.
2/3"Based on the information we had at the time, it didn't appear there was enough of a necessity to have anothe:
llllh
company," Councilman John Roberts said.
213"We're at the point now where we're just taking testimony and trYing to determine what the facts are."
2/3Schaffer said Fontana's recent growth has produced more business for cab companies. He pointed to the oper
of California Speedway and additional traffic at Kaiser Permanente Medical Center.
213Bell O!h serves 10 cities in San Bernardino County including Rialto, Redlands, Upland, Colton and Highland.
Yellow ~ provides service from West Covina to Rlalto. The two companies compctc in Upland, Chino, Chino
H~sandO~o. 5~tlP4,( dJ< .p~ Ifv.,)) ';4 11nI,.;;, hT~ -
213Ontario spokesman John Freiman said the expansion of Ontario International Airport and the traffic at Ontario
Mills pushed the need for a second cah company.
213Yellow Cah officials said IfFonrana and Rancho Cucamonga take on an additional cab company, the quality of
service will decline.
2/3"Unwarranted competition in the taxi industry drives up rates the passengers pay," said Steve Carrigan,
operations manager for Yellow Cah. "Tfthis happens we will have to reduce our size and thus reduce our ability to
provide services."
CrDeSk (e) Digital Collections
Page 1
FEB-II-2002 MON 05:28 PM LUPE
.
'.
FAX NO. 17603915945 P. 04
2/11/2002 -17:16 reporter
-b1 w wd jcs aw Cab company challenges Yellow
>.
28:07.1998 San Bernardino County Sun 01-
2/3Bell C.ab applied to opente in Rancho Cucamonga in November, but city c'lUncil members decided there was no
~ need for a second taxi company, said Duane Baker. assistant to the city manager.
Copyright 1998 The San Bernardino County SUD
Veap:1998; Month=7; Monlh=Jul: Day=28: Day=Tu; Book=B; Zone=West; Byllne=Glnla_Kern; Company=Bell.J;;stLCo;
Malnkey=TransportallonrraxJ~; Subkey-GovernmentlClty..govemmentlCily Council; Photo=No; Graphic=No;
Aspect=San_Bemardlno_County-Sun; Aspect-Local; Aspect=Jul; Aspect"Tu; AsPect=S; Aspect=West; Aspect=Glnls_Kerri;
Aspect=Sell...QaILCo; Aspect=Transportallon; Aspacl-TaxilCil!!l; Aspect=Govemment; Aspect=City ....9overnmen[;
Aspect=CiIy Council; Aspect-No; Aspect=No;
e
trOesk (e) Digital Collectlons
Page 2
...... ..-.... ........or.. rl\u..-lItl.."nu CMr"IKC ~AO 9093693019
< em":' \Q 1WI .::: IN ..,.J ctI ~'c:.c ':::: ~ ~ ;;: ~ i>\'= ~ ~ ~ >t~- 'i bC'- ~
~o~ ~c ~ ~~] ~~O~~~~ ~-Og. e ~ ~ ~
!~U_~U~tl'.~"" ~~~M- I ~"~g. .;~ .
3Cl:1Q.~:lI... 1lr.,;:;l:t, w:Jc:~:I ;I"o"",:..~..a > a O.J
.- " i!l i " l'..U'. ; a... ~] u .. e l!..c . . ~ -S " II 8 .....'ll..
. s B~:J g [~h,~ li~.i~i.!~'a ~.l1~~'ji~ii :'i; .~
~~~~" .."~~" ~'~t~~"~"je ~s .~ ~D~~ ..
..!l<ll S a.~s~~":<Il~!s.s l! ,n '=~1.'l ~::~Ji!::5..!! l,u'P- fi.;~
=-~l ~...~~ at'! ~llll"~'E.!! ~~ Ii] ~'~-!:':sJ.H il~I!"
:ga.~];~i~8~"iI!;~!5~~~~~S~!=r~~~~;9~~
c:; ~';;.5I..lll e .~<.ti Q.i:I? ..goo -:ilia. .!llI < <<I vJ!< 0" e 41
c
T-846
P,03
lIt__ Q.l'1;l IG 9! ~ '~ .. co cu .."""......,....
:3 ;l ~ ~'.'= I'~ .~ .; ~ c ~ l ~ t'~ CG =
~..8..c " =1 J 3 l! >.. ..!!,,:l 0 Ii: .;= ;!l e .
Q. ca.!, c: ...... "0 ..::l 0 "':I v !:to ~ III CIlI,<lI
Q,l 6~ 21'" >-<1 .s ~ ~ ~~ ~"'rlJJ..c:r.. b
"O"lI,l Q,l>.Q.CIIR ..... n:I E co::;; ..Q >.!.
1!6-=-:i ~ m ~ go ~ i ; ~ ~o"~ 'i c"j~.!c; I
o c:... ~"E -..:::::: 0;.; g lI4g:-a.o.! f Q. =::&::=
5.201E!=~~~o '~-~~~~3~.i~~
'-d~C;1-<t'lItlIl~E'i :-=Se>..:.a.tIllr!! ~._
o~.5~o_~~u~~ ~~~a~~5',,"=~~
~~ ~u._ . ~-c~ _ ~w
g s~~ :5 ~,,= t'.2-;;~ ~.2::Jl.!u t'E C ~
~o~~.~~~>30~~~~t~~~~~~
=~~a~~~J~~~;.~l-~ M ~~u
." t,J-C c:: .... ".", "0_11;'""'" '"
~. ~ GS ~ <<I ~, en '" C ~ ra 8.~ :rJ J:: . Cell' ;.=
~Q,I-....-,,3:=...i r:a.:=G 1Ill_~."'=~aI!::Eo
'-:I: - - ~ ~ .- 0" .... ~ > -':5
f'J~~=~S.~.!~t~=l~e~~'a~J=.
~ __casC~~~ 3_ =~. ~~~~~Q
......-..... -t.l-- .C~ c:....ol:,;~>O...~ 100
';fa:t -5.c"::.c"41--0 '-~~-N"::-5.Jt~~ :.c
~~~> 'ilo.~uEal: e ~ ~ -.~
....c=..~c: ",,-"C',;slf,a;": Q<<I-l;....
--o=gf2 ~~.,..!~3;~ =~~"t:.s.!~~.. 0
a ct~ III ~:I C~.. 4.1 ~ 0 3: ~ at
.-= St"t:_ t.-....oc ....c:.g "" !Lg c:I] 5 ~ Q;
;II "1;'.."' g ~ c 0 - 2 e:'" .a: .... {,J'- c ~ a E ~
~;..i3: 'o~"Q5' ~1:: =....f:l.~~~~.9_
.. ~~ i~.~1~ ~~~E~~.~~1 ~
,3] 0": ; t; a._ Co - ~o III C 9r:~_ ._
.....!:!u: e"T:...~=~g a;Q~.g-.(IO--'==~..;.~ .:::
<: i~: ,,~a.! ~.~ Co ~'s. :: ~ ~ ~ ~:e ~.si]
..c::.... ~ 1I",=,->-"'l;I ~......t.lC; ""'U .___
~-~.. :...~~._..c ~-~"-o~~~.I-
= ~::: > Po.... _ ~ ~ ~ Q, ~ g Ul 3: = Ii Q, tlO
- C it: '0.= ~ ~ :J i en "A - "'::e c: .... ~ .s ~ _ ~ C
C of i - '" 1: ~ -= C '" e ; 'l:' ~ '" "- < ~ .. ~ ~ ~.~ ~
~;= .~-~~=~ =~<~ ~ ~ ~~><
..c::::tg~;::' c!:..aoc:;o~ O')ii.:.!:a15~~...
....~~~~ ~~~~~~- -~~-~~-~=
I ~ ~ == II ~ . 0':::-;: '" . ~ ~e:"Q -J ~ t
-= ~ e ~ = 9. s.. - ... c:: =:e.. _ ; ~ 0 >t
~ '- Q t: =::c::a :H..; ......c 0
~ c~~ -~~ ~~~ ~c-~
=s "= If 8 c s ~ :. ..: tI.::S = _ c::._
t S"O .3 '=;--="'..c: 8.1oI.z ~ a:: ..c"o o;.-..c
." .. e:; .5';j o~ l: ~Hi ~ ~ ~; ~ ..'" l'! ~
~:. ~ ~.8 -g~]aI~.f"i~~~:S5~~e
Q, 10 ..-:.:: ~ =_:sz ~ ....._.... C b,o~ liP..&:;
-a1~'38~ ~= -~~~~I-~~~ ~-
3 ~.::.co.s..c ..c=> ~ 3-5 i e-; >OM 0 ;'i: ~ ~ S
~ ':I L::! .- lIlI E U _ 51.... ~ 0 ~ q,'" .::J -.x:.i
~~~>=.- .~~a.~o~~u..~be~>~
Co ;="t:In~~=-5.;'e..r:~>.t '.a:i~...J~Qj
:Jc.._ :s.~!:._ l:;..a"aIG:J>C,I"Oc;u:::lll;>~
-UGOo ",~Q,- .~'a-~>'-~ (1')>"
t1C~ e- III CoI ~ ~ = OJ :t.aa C1.c ~ -2 .0.:5......:, .. ~ .s:.: .s
.C ~S~=_S~ ._Q.~&",w ~~:S~~.
.2101~~~e~~i~E~~G~~~~'~~o.5~~
:~-=e &~8= e::~ t:.8:2~ ~g.E&'o ~
. QI DQ >-a ..:. >.~ :zlI ~ C!J .., 11 u C,I ~ "'! ~ ~ =tcli
:.cc.~ "i~c~.cm..c --C:e.:4~ =>:-: t::l(:
.C;'t" u:5"o'i"-!'.l 3;;-~"" --e '..:1",
~C:'~ ~ ~"i ~~ e ~iiii ;s~'::~:C ~~ ~~
: ic= g '5; ~i]]j! 1::"ii E >.~ 1;.:
.,c . U ~:=:".. '" 11 - <i ._ j .. ,lII., .." -= Iii: 8
,. "...~".....", - ..........:..Jo> ..c:
~ c >. ~ ..:;: - eo ~ :I C l: =..,;; .- Lo r>S
.1:.:1..= ~ aa:.... >.l: a E 1IQe-~::S aI II; il Q,I
'""m_ =o..a.o">.C..." >." e" c::..c:
: Q.l 1,1 ~ t; ~ aoI CI is ~ ca c ~ t~ _ ca ~ 1M .!:oD
i~~J =;5~t .e~ ~~Il~ !~~~=
i'.3~cs 'faA C .~~. i~Oi&lClJ ..!!~=.:
I$. E... tIC.! cd':g ajSJi ....c.ie; Ei ...-Q., 1:.0
. - 0 " .- " 0 e _ .. ~ "s 0 .s .... s
: ~ &. CD ~::: 3.5 IQ ~ ~ e ~ g ..:J le ..:: ... 0
'tt'! .~!I...c:~",.c ~u~.= q,la=~
: u ". - . :;:.... _> i;'. Ill. _..." ...c > II 0
;='is..J~' !i'~,Hl! Ei~ !'is..'' 1l.,;E- 2..cGo. ~
: 0 Cf.I -.- c.:::;;a: t=v.J ~ > ..., ~ ._ UJ ~ ~..., I: J; """
~. __ ______H
"
c
as
-
Q.
:J
CI)
(,)
.-
>
..
CI)
(/)
o
...
~
s::
as
Q.
E
o
CJ
.a
as
CJ
~
CI)
:;2
_.__._--_._~--
'-a! .........o.s "0' O'.5..c",
~ If! :a =ir~ In .oS" Ii -5.a..... -~.:tCll.
~ .- ~a.w~~.... 8 a.~ ~~~
Q,I E 01';'5 ='1-5;cE i ~ G.Q ..c a~
~$e ~j~~'~a~~ ~ ~t~ ~ca~
,,-;"'S ~,-~CI ..."C"" C>> ~c:o i::t::8,
t~5::: .10 _8s..Q ~1l~ -5 = as;t ~.,,;~
bO"C..... . - rn c twI - . ~ . o.at l;) 0 ell
tlS_...i .56+01 CiI =' ~=c >.~ ="ga~11 li!.': >.
;"il"" ~"C"ll g.[-=:; .."'.... ~>- .;<;'0..
:::i!l"o I:"QI '"Qi ~D. "'c-.M.. .., ......,
~J!~ :E Q~ ~-:: .! EJLa :l1.!Hfi: ~ >
~~~ ~8~1'~~~8.~~~ca~.~>~~
Uoa<<SbgUlQ, .:FfJs ~..c:..Qoc~_~~~
'-..0 .:s - . 0 ~ as - CI!.., 1IJ "C..c::
tl_CQ ~.,gj.~~!!ij.. ~c_i-;~ e~'~ ~.=~
~...u"..Q.._ f"-'ICI f4._lZJ-,,_~..c~.
~.;~~~~i~.if~ii~'~~!~~tJ~
.CI ~ S '1: = aa"Q..:d c:a-. Q. C):~ ~ 0 ~
.w i ~ lQ.... ; 2:L5.: ~ ~ ~ IS~:-' ~"t:J rd
~u.c :: ~ J ; "0 ~ ~ c: t:: ~:.c E g :s; sbG
]=;:Ei ~ ~'li~'~ SI ::~ ~g;:g.=~ ::.g.5
o",:lJiolii""~-:l =,,-..cS.., ~:.ll
::& lU-==.gV!"! :.eie";*....t:] ~=
1!ao_(IO(,I>_... c-c->,cC:::"'C -,Si
""S.~."-" ~cee~=c ~_~
,!: ell c-cc:......l;t c; . 1'C._t:_ 0 __ l.O
-~<<f-..-SJJ~'" c..c..cO."Q. ::::::1:=
=alG:>~91bCc:DS! COIlO""O.,,~:s~ .:!~::1
.".....ll'''~3-= ~;a.,."ee~ -!l8
~:c cU 0 -'>a'" 0 .... c .... ..:5 ~ I: >.... "'.... ~
~ -.: c ~ ell il u CI .,.j of := "'C..:: !! - t -=. ~ ir..:::
~~d!~~=.p'...~~=....~~~o...~
:e;~ 3 ~:'cl=~.;l~J':;~ ill!:~~ e~C! ".
SI ... 1;1 C . >. r: s II .. .. J.~. I:Q Ii.- c~...
I::a = ~.~ e J; -2 ~ i ~ it ~ ;: !. - S"tl = =
eS;i~~~~.S~~~=oo~~Q~~~~llo.~
--as~.gs ~- -f' : U"'O _
8...c:::IiI"s ..83a13 ..,,;-;. .3'5 ~):l:
-. Q"
:Ias~
e (1).1:
(I)';
.. rn CI)~
; I%: ~.
-1;;;'2,
~ CI) >.i!
~.c'iiS
t'" -
i CI) e.;
"".- B
~.......
.. 0":7
~ 0 c ~
: .c CI) ~
! J e'i
:;f!:I~
~ ,,, fIJ ~
<I: W'- ~
>..cs
ca"~
Q."O~
)(as4
as CLI '"
F..."
I
.!:]:: e S ~=G ~ ~ ~ i: "8 E C m.f ti ~ ~ rn 111 -; .
;:t:~ CI~~C~ ~'i':J=o ]tlO .9l:g:t:~ !
O~C e ~gc ~~~~~ ~~~~=~~~Q ~
-':'G./ ~c- ."'..... III .x'" .b ._e:-;J9,,~='._ 'C
Q.I ,,"1: '>I >. '>I ...:.. I:G_ .... c: v ~ c;: ILl =-._ C too _
e~l g~~~i ~~.5~~ 5~~~3S~i~~ .5
" ~ ",,~- =... - ~co- ~..~c
<<tI .. u "a Q, ..!Z =:I..c: ~ m ... "'C _._.w ~ >0.
-~I.I - ~ .....-..:~ ~.-.="C::c:Ja". c
>..,! ..c: ~ llII >. .- . ~ ~ ~ g,,"c j:I .. ..... .: <<tI".:)
-= 51 'S1!"a"Q~ S.S.-';....... CS >.12 >>~-:~-i>::E :S
il~ I~i~~ ~~ti~~]i~j~i~~~]~~
~ e~ .::s ~ ~ t::J lIi~J e ~ ~ 8:i:'" 5:~.!-; ~.s~: e:
. fa Q,... ~ ~ ~ ... ~ >:'~ ~ c a 0 co ~ i ;.....; "=i '" ... ::1-0 it
~~ ~j:I"" .o~~oi~~Ql-~e~=~~~<Q~_
5~"210!!" ..S,,"'c,= ~C"I "tl"=ati;altl' m-= "'-5~
~:I::~~~;J~f~~is~I~.~~g~P~iii~~i~
~ 'Caco ~~~se ~.~O~! ~~~~ ~2~~~
all'J"T:I.,S-a ...:,= ILl <<I c: .3 >> 3~ I;i ;.J.....; rQ"f;I'R
.c Il=I ..! lZ as oS..c .... ._..c: <<II = _ fG._ IllS ;l ;l
IS lIlI~ 3 <<l....c: - 11.1 "'" QI U f_
QQ.:o" -.s JQ~ ::; .... -0 Ba;o..........
~g"a -; f._Cl: u oS:! ;;..!! c..cot-8"
.SI.I= ~~ ._-~ =~~~ ._~u4~1
.......e I: ~ t:: ~ i: "'Si! 17.l:ll - _Q ~ -=
~ PJ~ t: .2'- ~=~ ~ 0 a;.....- ~ J -S :3.91
"'-l; :J e ~~ ...!;: ~ taD'O if.,-5 ..=~." ~ e"
>0 "..0 ~ . C Ii l! ~ ~ >0 z.8....ij ",=.,.._ l!! "
1IllA ~a.gOAc 1:1 ..= c g~~lD<<tIii
J';c Ii; ~':i'g~ ~t .n =-ll..H~ ii aiE1L~ e
j S-!Se ",,- g. go'c.o=S"Q;JC: S(::I.-og
""i Q"l:~ '-2:'0 ....;!~",,~cl,,:.:!l..sis
"~ ~ CI"Q i --= e.a c oS >; -; ~u.... 0 !. 5 :J..Q CD
t;il ;:r~'U.;.~;"S!c:~..'i S' f;!,U ~~'e e8~iliH
c5 Q., 5'J-S'c_~"; 11;1 o. -~ ..!.Q; .. e,g
111>>- ~ ~ I! :; .....a oS.5 ! 8.~ ~"'a.~ i SJ 1 >- ~ ~ 5 ~ ; "5:: =-...
l! D..&::ICd:J Eilii C);.:~ ~ 'Zl ~-ts.....~ ~
.
,
lea
1TJ) If)) , ,,; ,) 0
l[~Jec fi~Jt21hon
iJ1 ,)1 &.--
It'" J;? /
~~ L I L ^
\.t-/'''" C:Jk-, /".~
)" lv w' J.~
f.)' (;JF
-:-,~...
Prepared far the
Int;~rnational "raxicab Foundation
38.&9 Farragut Avenue
Kensington, Maryland 20895
Prepared by
Price Waterhouse
Office of Government Services
Washington, DC
'1ovember 8, 1993
i25 for ITF & ITI.A Members
S50 for Non-Members
~ International Taxicab Foundation
('tler/O?
fl dJC,
waShington: "Dc 20QOL
Price PVaterhouse
8
8 November, 1993
Mr. Alfred LaGasse
Executive Vice President
International Taxicab Foundation
3849 Farragut A venue
Kensington, MD 20895
Dear Mr. LaGasse:
We are pleased to submit this final report documenting our findings from an
analysis of taxicab regulation and re-regulation that we performed on behalf
of the International Taxicab Foundation.
Our findings rest on research methods described in Section 1 of the report,
which rely on three data sources: (i) past case studies of taxi deregulation,
sponsored by the U.S. Department of Transportation; (ii) taxi fare and
license data for individual cities, made available by the International
Taxicab and Livery Association; and (iii) telephone surveys of public
officials in cities that implemented taxicab deregulation, conducted by Price
Waterhouse. Price Waterhouse has not independently audited data from the
first two sources, although we have no reason to believe the data have any .
characteristics that would invalidate our findings.
Our report concludes that the effects of taxi deregulation have ranged from
benign to adverse, depending on local markets and conditions. This is a
departure from the experience with deregulation in other industries and is
influenced by taxi market imperfections that reduce or remove incentives
for price and service quality competition. Consequently, we found that
most cities that had fully deregulated taxi service have since reverted to
some form of control over market entry.
We very much appreciate the assistance provided by you and other
members of ITF during this engagement.
Very truly yours,
~ ~ c.:.r2- ~o.....-\-es- ~.='^ ~~
fXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Taxicab regulation and deregulation refer to opposite ends of a specuum of government
control over taxi services. Regulation rypiclly implies government determinacion of service
supply (by limiting taxi licenses), or prices:by serring fIxed or maximum fares), or both.
l>ercgulation, in contrast, typicallr implies on absence of government conuol. Although
regulatory choice is nor limited to these tWO extremes, philosophical support for one or the
o:her tends to be the driving force behind changes in public policy.
Since the late 1970s, local governments and the taxi industry have engaged in periodic
debate regarding the merits of taxi deregulnion. These debates were initially influenced by the
deregulation of ocher prominent industries - airlines. trucking. and telecommunicatior1S to name
a few. Proponents of taxideregulacion cited several kinds of consumer benefIts that were
experienced with these other deregulation efforts. These benefIts were believed to include more
r:uci service: :lnci faster response rimes, lowc:r fares, service innovarions. and service expansion [0
under-served neighborhoods. Proponents "f taxi regulation argued, in counterpoint. that
deregulation would result in poorer service. less safery, less accountability. and less reliability.
Because most taxi services in the US were regulated at the time these debares fIrst occurred.
there was little empirical evidence to supp"rr either argument.
The International Taxicab Foundo':ion engaged Price Waterhouse to analyze and
document the experiences with deregulaticn over the last ten years. Twenry-one cities
deregulated taxi services prior to 1983, though no major cities are known to have deregulated
since. The shorr-term effects of deregulati,)n were previously documented in a series of case
studies I sponsored by the US Departmen. ofT ransporration, published in 1983 and 1984.
The purpose of chis report is to add to che :ecord by describing changes in regulatory practices
that followed deregulation. and to explore ,he comparative effects of deregulation over che long
term.
It is imporrant for readers to note that Price Waterhouse does not advocate either
deregulation or regulation of taxi services. Rather, our purpose is to clarify and compare the
effects of deregulation as experienced in a number of metropolitan areas in the US. We trust
that this objective rendering of the available facts will assist public decision-makers in their
deliberation of the taxi industry regulatory structure.
Short-Term Effects of Deregulation
Deregulation ir.trodnced several ir.~mediate changes in taxi supply. price, and service
quality in the six cities for wilich derailed case scudy information is available (see citation above).
The experience of these cicies generally indicates that the benefIts of deregulation were devalued
by unanticipated and \I nattractive side effe~ts:
.
Although the supply of taxi st!Tflius expanded dramatically, only marginal srrviu
improvl!77unrs w~e experi,nud by consum~s. Within a year of deregulation,
che supply of taxi services i~creased an average of 23%. Because most new
entrants were independen~ operators and small fleet owners with limited
I Berkeley. Oakland. Pho. ,ix. Portland. San Die~~. and Seattle.
Analy,is ofT lDdraf, Regul ion ,m. . D"egul4tion
Final Report page i
capabiliry co serve rhc relephone-based marker, n:"sc new service was
. concenrrared ar already well-served loc"rions - SU.:l, as airpores and major
cabs rands. Cuscomer wair rimes ar rhese locarior." already shore, were reduced
fureher. Response rimes in rhe relephone marker were similar ro pre-
deregularion performance. Trip refusals and no-,hows, however, increased
significandy.
.
Prices TOU in every insrance. Paradoxically, rhe i"flux of new emranrs did nor
invoke rhe price compemion rypically experienccd in orher newly-deregulared
indusrries. Prices rose an average of 29% in che y~ar following deregularion.
There appear co be cwo sources of chis unexpecreJ evem. Firsr, fare increases
prior co deregularion had consisrencly lagged caS[ increases. Vereran operacors
chus correcred prices ar che firsr opporeuniry. Second, new enrrams generally
charged higher fares chan rhe veceran operarors. The cabsrand markecs on which
chese operacors focused rheir services are generally price insensirive and, becausc
of rhe firsr-in tim-our nacure of raxi queues, comparison shopping is
discouraged. For chese reasons, che new emrams had no incemive co imroducc
. ..
pnce comperlClon.
.
Service quality declined. Trip refusals, a decline in vehicle age and condirion,
and aggressive passenger soliciracion associared wich an over-supply of caxis arc
characceristic of a worsening in service qualiry following deregulacion.
The negacivc aspeccs of deregulacion were especially evidenr ac airpores and major courisc
accraccions. As a resulr, deregulacion often acquired rhe enmiry of che business communiry and
adverse media coverage. These effeces were mosc closely associaced wich cities char implemenced
an "open enrry" policy chac enabled an influx of independenr owner-operacors rhar were
unaffiliaced wich companies or raxi cooperacives.
The shorr-rerm effeces of deregularion were less adverse in smaller ciries which have an
insignificam cabsrand marker. The celephone-based marker, which dominares rhe smaller ciries,
is difficulr for independem operarors ro serve effeccively. These cicies chus avoided rhe
scrucrural changes co rhe indus cry char comribuced ro rhe problems in larger ciries no red above.
Post~Deregulation Changes in Regulatory Practices
All posc-deregularion changes in regulacory practices were limiced co cities chac had
implemenred a "fully deregulaced" sysrem, wherein borh markec enrry and fares were left co che
induscry's discrecion2. Ocher cities which had only partially deregulaced - for example, chrough
che use of minimum 'scandards for markec enrry or by relaxing govemmem involvemem in fares
- reporred no changes in regulacory scruccure. .
Nine of rhe chireeen eicies chac had deregulared via "open encry" chose ro reverr CO "
regulaced syscem, eicher in whole or in part, by 1992. Six cities returned co a Fully-regulaced
scruccure, in which che local governmem limies markec encry and sees a fixed or maximum tare.
Two ocher ciries implememed regulacions for airpore-based service. These eighr ciries were [he
2 see Seerion 1 of rhis reporr for a definicion of rhe rui regulatory strucrure.
A1UtIysis ofT axicab Regulation ant! Dmgulation
Final Report page u
largest of those that had initiall}' deregulated, and had the most intensive airporr activiry. One
other ciry reverted to a minimum standords approach.
Only four of the 21 cities continue to employ a fully-deregulated system. These are
among the smallest cities in the group. Related to the size of these cities is the absence of major
srructural changes in the indusrry that precipitated re-regulation in the larger cities.
Long-Term Effects of Deregulation
Long-term pricc performance in deregulated cities is similar to that of regulated cities.
based on price information submirred ar.nually by members of the Ir.:ernational Taxicab and
Livery Association (ITLA). Between 191:5 and 1992, the median fareJ for a five-mil.,. trip rose
by 6.5% ($0.50) in deregulated cities versus 4.S% ($0.33) in a sample of regulated cities (see
appendix B for details). Fares in cities which re-regulated their taxi services rose by only 2%
($0.17) during this period. a reaction to -he high rate of fare growth following deregulation.
These results indicate that deregulation, over the long term. has contributed to neither higher
nor lower fares than experienced by the industry generally.
Other long-term effects of deregulation are difficult to discern. Taxi supply (i.e., taxis
per 1,000 population) in deregulated citi.,s stabilized after the shorr-term increases noted above,
and appears to be lower and more variabi~ than in regulated or re-regulated cities. Very little
data is available to supporr long-term eva:uation of service qualiry. These rypes of data are
rardy collected even in regulated cities, aCId are especially scarce in deregulated cities.
.
In retrospect, the effects of taxi deregulation have ranged from benign to adverse,
depending on local conditions and mark:rs. There appears to be scam evidence that .
detegulation fully achieved the goals on which its implemenration was premised. though some
goals clearly were achieved (e.g.. more taxis, less regulatory involvement by government).
Market imperfections peculiar to the taxi industry, including unusual product supply (e.g., first-
in, first-out queues at cabstands) and poor availabiliry of information on price and qualiry, tend
to negate the consumer benefits rypically associated with deregulation in other industries. It is
perhaps noteworrhy that no major US cities have deregulated taxi services since the early 1980s.
3 In constam 1992 dollars.
Final Repon page Hi
An4/.v<is .fTaxkab Regulati"" aNi E=guI4titm
1. FRAMEWORK
A wa\'" of der"gulation occurred in the taxicab industry during th" lat" 1970s and
early 19805, involving 21 citi"s across the U.s. Sinc" that tim", most d"regulated cities
exp"rienc"d unfavorabl" r"sults and opted to :"e-regulate, while the r"mainder hav" for various
re",ons remain"d der"gulat"d. The puq::ose (.f this report is to docum"nt the "xperience of
each, and to explain th" circumstances which led to these different outcomes.
This section of the repon imroduce~ rhe terminology used to'describe ta.xi regulation,
and provides an overview of the method, used to compile the record on det"gulation.
Regulation, Deregulation, and Re-Regulation
Taxicab regulation and deregulation :efet to opposite e"ds of a spectrum of
government control ov"r taxi services. R'gul"tion rypieally imp!i"s gov<:cnmem determination
of servie" supply (by limiting taxi licenses), Ot prices (by s"tting fixed or ma.ximum fares). or
both. Da'gulation, in contrast, rypically imF li"s an absenc" of gov"rnm"nt control. R,-
rrgulation r"f"rs to a tight"ning of governmer:t control over s"rvice supply and/or prices,
following a period of rdaxation of comrols. .
Th" matrix bdow illustrat'" th~ twO basic dim"nsions of th" r"gulatoty structur":"
mark"t "ntry m"chanisms and far,,-setting m{'chanisms. Market "mry m"chanisms, shown in
the left-most column. rang" from most r"scrictive (predetermined c"iling) to l"ast rescrictive
(open entry). Far,,-setting mechanisms, shown in the top-most row, rang" from most
testrietive (reguLror defines all far",) to least r"scrictive (individual operators define fares).
Full regulation and full d"regulation refer to opposite corners of this matrix, as shown.
Berween th"se twO "xtremes lie hybrid approaches by which government may control some
aspectS of taxi servic" that are of concern to local interests.
i'are-Setting Mechanisms
Market Entry
Mechanisms
Predetermined
Ceiling
-RegtJI.tMl- ryplc.lly me. Jns that
both mark" ..try end'. ,... .r.
.p<<:/fltJd by 'ogufs!rJn
Regulator Detlnes
Minimum or
Maximum
Individual Operators
Define FareJ
Regulator De!lnes
All Fates
Population Rallo
Convenience &
Nee.laity
Franchise System
Minimum
Standards
Open Entry
A1J4lysu .fTIlXier.b kguLsriJJn IS"" DmguLstilJr.
Final R <port PlSi' /
Oefirtirions for rhe rypes of marker emry mechanisrr.s4. in order of decreasing
govcrnmem comrol, arc as follows:
.
Predetermined ceiling. The ciry limits the ;.umber of taxicabs in operdtioll.
rypically by issuing a fixed number of taxicaL permirs. If demand for taxicab
service exceeds rhe ceiling, this is effectively:. closed entry policy.
Popular,on rario. The number of taxicabs in operation is se; as a function of
population (e.g., 0.75 cabs per 1,000). The IJtio allows the number of permits
to vary with demand.
Convenience and necessiry. New permits may be issued under ce((ain
conditions. A wide range of criteria fall imo this caregory, usually relevant [Q
demand and the need for additional service.
.
Franchise system. This system involves graming specific companies the right
to operate ta:'Cicabs. Its effect may range from closed emry to open emry.
depending on the requiremems for emry of new companies and the ability of
existing companies to increase the number of cabs.
.
Minimum standards. Cabs are allowed to operate as long as they satisfy
certain minimum standards. Th"5e standanis differ from convenience and
necessity in that they are unrelated to demaad. The standards may include
one or more of m"5e &octors: a minimum nlimber of vehicb, radio dispatch
capabiliry, 24 hour service, or a vehicle age Emit. Th"5e regulations limit
supply by raising the cost of market emry.
.
Open emry. Under open entry, almost anyone who owns an operable vehicle
can obtain a taxi permit and provide service. There are still requiremems
under open emry, such as insurance or absence of a criminal record, but these
are less restrictive than is the case for minirr. um standards.
The last "vo mechanisms - minimum standards and open entry - are most closely
associated with deregulation. These mechanisms remove the regulatory body from decisions
regarding taxicab supply, rdying on market forces to "5tabEsh an equilibrium. Minimum
srandards, however, can be used to influence the type of new emrants to the market, and ihus
the quality and stabiliry of service.
Fare-setting mechanisms form the second dimensi"n of the regulatory matrix.
Definitions of th"5e mechanisms are as follows:
.
Government-set fares. The local governmcm sets the fare that operarors may
charge. The rationale is that taxicab service is a public utility, and the public
must be protected from unreasonable rates.
4 Definitions were drawn from: Urban Mass Transporcation Administration. T llXicab R~gulation in US eif;';;
Va/um' J (Fintz/ R'pa,,): October 1983.
Final Report pat,2
Analysis afTllXicab RegubttWn anti Dmgubztiqn
2. TAXI REGULATION
Regulations goverr.ing the ta.xieali industry ha\', L.eeL in place sir,:;: the beginning wf
taxicab service. The most active period for new taxica~ ,cgL.:.ition in the US occurred du:ing
the late 1920s and early 1930s, when the Deptession ",used extremely compctiti\'e
conditions. and growing urban centers irwariably expe,ie::cc'; problems \':ith t3xicab service.
A \,(/'z.rhingron POIt areicle from 1933, entitled "T :Lxi"d, Ch.."s." effectivelY conveys the i"itial
desire for ta.xicab regulations:
Taxicabs a..re litcrall)' running wild on \X'.uhingmn streets, ",,-ir.h ;dmosc complw.: IJck of
supervision or comrol. Public safety, reasonable: working i"cgul~Hions, and cqui~;~blc ra:cs :lCC
almost completely disrcgarded...Hundrcds of incxp::rienc.::i dri...::.rs rem cabs 2.1I~t oflc:r their
services {O the public. One dri\'cr who was rc:cendy obscr.'cd prccceding down Pcnnsyi\"ania
Avenue like: a dcrdicc confessed that he: had noe driven a af fo~ s::\'~n or eight )'c.:~s.
A central feature of ta.xicab service is the potentially iow COSt of market entr}'. A
setviceable vehicle and a licensed drivet arc the minimum rCL1uitements to start a ta.xicab
. .
operation. In an untegulated environment. the low cOS[ of ;::itt}' attracts individuals who have
limited employment options. Thus. during periods of high unemployn,ent, independent taxi
operators flood the market. Condicions such as these during the Dcpre;;ion led cities to
regularc taxi services. Once this practice was established. it tended to spread to other cities as
a precedent for protecting the public interest.
Accordingly. restriction of market entry is the central feature of the ta.xi regulatorj
structure. Three arguments arc traditionally cited by the taxi industry in favor of tegulating
market entry5:
.
"natural monopoly" - onc firm can pro,,'ide services at least cost
.
"destructive competition" - too many com?critors yield insufficient protlt;
and cause declines in safety and service.
.
"cross subsidy" - profits in lucrative markets arc needed [0 subsidize service in
unprofitable markets.
fares.
page.
A 1983 study estimated that 80% of cities limited market entry. and 77% regulated
The full disrrib~tion of regulatory practices is shown in the graph on the following
Most ta.xi regulations arc effected by local jurisdictions (i.e.. cicies and counties).
Only three states completely regularc taxis, and scyen others exert partial control. The
remaining states generally specify only minimum standards i'or safery. leaving fare and entry
regulation to local governments.
5 From Teal. e[ al, Urban Transportation R<gulation in Arizona. USDOT/UMTA. 190'\.
Arurlysis o[Taxicab R<gul.ation and D<Tcgul.acum
Final Report p"gc 4
Market Entry Mechanisms
Population
Ratio
10%
Franchise
System
7%
Minimum
Standards
20%
Convenience &
Necessity
29%
FRre-Setting Mechanisms
Industry-Set
Fares
23%
Maximum/Mini
mum Fares
27%
Pre-set Ceiling
34%
Government-
set Fare
50%
Source: Shaw, Gilbert, et ai, Tl!Xicab Regulations in US Cities, USDOT/UMTA, 1983.
.
A""'pis ofTllXirab Regulation anJ Dmgulation
Final Report page 5
3. TAXI DEREGULATION AND RE-REGULATION
Through 1983. rwenty-one US cities opted to deregulate raxi services to various
degrees. In rhe past ten years, six of these cities revcreed ro a Fully-regulated sysrem, and
anorher rwo ciries regulated raxi services at airpores. The cities which maintained a
deregulared structure rended ro have one of the following characteristics: (1) relacively
smaller in population than the other cities; (2) less reliant on airpore aeriviry; or (3) had
implemented orher measures that raised the hurdles for market entry. Only four of rhe 2 i
ciries continue to employ a Fully-deregulared system today.
This section of rhe reporr describes why rhese rwenry-one ciries deresulared, rhe
effeces of deregulation, and changes in rhe regulato'y strucrure following deregularion.
Why Cities Deregulated
Twenry-one US cities, principally in Wesrern and Sunbelt states, deregulated taxi
services by 1983. Two ciries - Arlanta and Indianapolis - deregulared in 1965 and 1973,
respectively. The remaining nineteen cities deregulared between 1979 and 1983. Most of
rhese cities moved from rradirional regulatory srrucrures to one of tWO forms of deregulated
marker entry: (I) open entry (13 cities); and (2) minimum standards (5 cities). Three other
cities deregulated fares, but maintained conrrols over marker entry. Graphics showing the
locations and dates of these deregulations, and the changes in regulatory structure. are
presented on the following page.
In relephone and on-site surveys of these cities, a free-market ideology was cited as
the driving force behind deregulation, which held the following expecrarions:
.
Price. Presuming rhar entry restricrions had enabled incumbent operators to
charge higher fares rhan would prevail in a comperirive market, proponents of
deregulation expecred new entranrs to force a reducrion in the prevailing races.
The positive license values in regulated cities were cired as e\.idence that the
incumbent operarors enjoyed some monopoly power.
.
Level of service. As entry restrictions are lifted. deregulation proponents
expecred the nwnber of cabs in service ro increase. In rheory, these additional
cabs should reduce the wait times for street-hailed service and response rime~
for telephone orders.
.
Quality of service. Proponents of deregulation expected that rhe new
comperitiveness of the industry should cause operators to compete based on
quality as well as price. resulting in improved service qualiry and the
availabiliry of new pricing and service oprions.
.
Administrative costs. Proponents of deregulation expecred that open entry
would reduce government costs by eliminating permir processing effortS, and
rhar cosrs would also be saved by eliminating rare change review.
While some of these benefirs were realized through deregularion, ocher less
arrracrive and unanticipated results occurred as well. In mOSt cities, these outweighed the
benefits and forced a reconsideration of full-scale deregulation.
A1l4iysu ofT a:m:ab Regulation anti Deregulation
Final Rcpor< page 6
:3ummary of Taxi Deregulation in the US
I Location & Timing of De regulations.
Seattle (1979)
Spoknne (1980)
Tacoma (1981)
Portlend (1979)
Sacramento (1f'~2)
Oakland (1979)
Berkeley (1980)
Fresno (1979)
San Diego (197r1
Phoenix (1982) "
Tucson (1982)
+ Open Entry
Madison (1979)
Milwaukee (1979)
Des Plalnes, IL (1981)
Indianapolis (1973)
Springfield, OH (1981)
Kansas City (1983)
Charlotte (1982)
At/anta (1965)
Jacksonville (1983)
Tampa (N/A)
.:. Minimum Standards
o Fares Only (reslricted entry)
Taxi Regulatory Structure:"Pre- and Post-Deregulation
Pre-Deregulation
Post.Oeregulation
9 9
. 8
. 7 . 7
~ 6 ~ 6
U U
-0 5 -0 5
! . j .
E 3 3 open Entry
, , MInimum Standard_
z 2 z 2
Franchi.. System
, ConwnWnce .. nee...lty
Populltlon ratio
PrecSe\ermlned Ceiling
Amz/ysis of Taxkab lI<gulation anti Deregulation
Final Report pag.7
Effects of Deregulation
The effects of deregulation varied by location. Cities which be: a rclatiycly brso
population, a high level of airport activit)" and condirions conduci,'e (0 low-cost market uttrr
tended to haye a negative experience wirh deregulation. As a result, ~hese cities either fcdi:.. or
partially re-regulated taxi services (see "Po;t-Dereguhtion Chang<:s :n Regulatory S[[U([~:"".
following this section). Cities which did not possess the above characteristics, mnyCl"'c1y.
experienced no dramatic effects - eith<:r positive or negative - and have performed I<1uch l:i.e
the rest of the industry over the long-term.
A summary of the effects of deregulation is presented below.
Price
Despite a large incr<:ase in service supply (see "Level of Service" on page I: J.
which in other indumies has fostered price competition, prices rose following taxi
deregulation in every documented case. The short-term changcs in ptice were quite
dramatic. In the long-run, however, ptices in deregalat<:d cities have performed
similar to the industry as a whole. Please refer to the graphs on page 9 for a summary
of shoft-term and long-term changes in price.
In the first year following deregulation, the a,'erag<: 5-mile fare rose by 29%
($1.39) in the six citi<:s documented in the USDOT cas<: studies. This ranged from J.
high of 56% ($2.40) in Seatde to a low of 7% ($0.40) in O;lkland. The price
increases roughly reflect changes in industry structure, particulady an increase in
ind<:pendent and small-fleet operators (see "Level of Service", below). In Seatde and
San Diego, these operators were observed to charge high<:r lires - sometimes
substantially higher fares - than those charged by the larg<:r, more-<:stablished
compani<:s. This can b<: s<:<:n in tr.<: graphs on page 10. A similar effect was noted6 in
Phoenix, but price information by company size was not docum<:nt<:d. In all three
cities, independent and small-fl<:et operators focus<:d th<:ir service on major cabsunds
and th<: airports. These ar<: generally price-insensitive markets with little or no
comparison shopping by prosp<:ctive customers. This condition, along with the tier
that th<:s<: operators sp<:nt long wait tim<:s in the tax: qu<:ucz, discouraged price
eomp<:tition on the part of n<:w entrants.
In the long-term (i.<:., 1985-1992), ptice ttends in deregulated cities are
similar to those in re-regulat<:d cities and tegulated cities (see bottom graph on page
9). The m<:~ian far<:? for a fiv<:-mile trip rose by 6.5% ($0.50) in deregulated cities
v<:rsus 4.8% ($0.33) in r<:gulated cities. Fares in cities which re-r<:gulat<:d th<:ir taxi
s<:rviccs ros<: by only 2% ($0.17) during this p<:riod, a r<:action to th<: high rat<: of far<:
growth during th<:ir d<:regulated p<:riod. Thes<: r<:sults indicate that d<:regulation, o\'<:r
the long term, has had litde impact on fare gtowth rdativ<: to th<: rest of the industry.
6 Teal, C[ al, Urban Transponation Deregulation in Atiron.. USDOT, 1984. page 54.
7 In COOSWl( 1992 dollars.
Aruzlysis of TaxicAb &gu},.,.ion Anti Dmgu/4rion
final Repon pag' 8
Taxi Prices: Short-Term and Long-Term Trends
Chance in 5-Mile Fare. One Year After Derequlaticn I
Net Change
.:.
Average Berkeley
?"c,nl Change I
r
50.0%
..
E
40.0% -~
..
~
c
n
:10.0":". -6
..
~
!3
c
20.0"10 8
"
"-
10.0".
0.0%
Oakland
52.50
52.00
e
.,
."
c S1.50
n'
.0
c.
~ S1.00
50_50
SO.OO
Seattlo
f :'ocnix
Portland
San Diego
Souru: USDOT (~t JrwfitI Dr: I .'t iffu:z of~. rtru!tz:o'] rrviJion. J 983-/984.
Median Fare lor a 5-Mile Trip, 1955 VS, 1992 I
58.50
58.00
57.50
" $7.00
'"
'"
'"
56.50
.;
;
"- 56.00
.!!
:i 55.50
.;,
55.00
54.50
$4.00
Oeragulated
~;itles
o 198,!i
III 1992
R"..regulated
Cities
Regulated
Cilles
Souru: tirauHlfrom ITLA Tari(,: Faa Eotl. s::::u:ia {UtAppmtlir BJ
Analyru of Taxicab R<gul.atin:. and D<r<gUbrtion
Final Report page 9
$10.00
$9.00
$8.00
$7.00
$6.00
$5.00
$4.00
$3.00
$2.00
$1.00
$0.00
Fares for a 5-Mife Trip, by Company Size
I Seattle, one year aft.;r deregulation ~
~i~t~
:!::~fij
~~c.~
#"
;';.-;1
~~
..').-.
!>:J
:~~J.!
.--....~.t!
1~
''::~1}
~>:..
'r~{~_
-~~
2103
41020
More than 20
Company Size (It of cabs)
I
lOU~l; cDmpiltti by hie: U.:::urhowt' from t.:.ri:.::: r~:r a::t4
rrporua by Ihr Ciry D/S(:.::~ Dtp.%mrun: ofLi:u:JlllZnd
Co1UU1IUT Affii1"1. JUtl( /9S0.
I Sa~ Diego, one year after deregulation I
$7.00
$6.00
$5.00
$4.00
$3.00
$2.00
$1.00
$0.00
2103
4 to 32 More than 32
Company aize (I of cabs)
Sourrr: U~DOT. Effi~ tlf&~ry Rr-.Vio" in
SA" Dirt(J, 1983.
o Mini::-.um FnfO
8 Max~-nlJm Fate
Ii Avera;c Faro
Aruzlysis .[Taxicab &rufation arul Dcrerufation
Final Repon pag,10
Level of Service
Doregularion producod in most casos an immediate. largo increaso in the
numbo: of taxis. Because now enuanrs tendod to congregate at alroady wdl-servod
location. this largo increase in supply did not produce ccrrosponding improvemenrs
in cusremor servico. In tho lon:-: torm. the 10vd of sorvico appoars ro havo subilizod in
deroguhtod cities. Dara are in.<ufficionr. howovcr. to commonr on tho long-tam
effocts ,.f taxi supply 011 service improvomonrs.
As notod in rho graph (rop) on tho following pago. tho numbor of taxi
oporarors immodiatdy after dorogulation increased by 23% on avorago. ranging from
a high of 70% (Phoenix) ro a low of 10% (Borkdey). Tho tYpe of now en~rants varied
considorably among the:se citios (soe borcom graph on following pago). In Phoenix.
San Diego. and Soarclo. tho percenrago of cabs opoIated by independonrs and small-
floot owners grow while tho porcenrage of largo fleot operarors declined. These
oporarors focused thoir servko on the airporrs and major cabstands. Conscquontly.
Phoonix. San Diogo. and Soattl.: exporionced large faro incroasos that woro in parr
arcriburablo ro small oporarors serving a price-insensiti\.e market (see "Price", above).
In Oakland. on the other hand. now largo floet owners enrorod tho markot. while in
Borkdey thore was little: chango. In conrrast ro tho othor ciries above. Oakland and
Borkdey exporioncod little chango in faros.
Customor-orientod service improvomonrs expocted ro occur with tho large
incroas: in sup?ly wore obsorvo(:. ro be marginal. Focus of new ontrants on the
cabstand market. as notod earl: ;r. roduced a1roady-short wait timos to almost zoro.
Rosponso timos for tho tdepho:.o-basod market woro not consistontly ovaluatod in the
case studies. though tho availab!o data suggests that little chango occurrod. In tho
only data sot containing beforo-and-aftor data (for San Diogo)8 rosponso timos for all
sorviced calls were about the sarno after dorogulation (13.6 minutos) as beforo (13.4
minutes). The rate of no-shows and tfip cancdlations. howevor. incroasod ,
dramatically - from 2% of all c;;lls to 18.2%. As shown in tho graph on pago 13. trip
refusals and no-shows aro most closdy rdatod to small floots and indopondent
operators. This was found to l->o truo in both San Diogo and Soattlo.
Long-torm data for evaluating taxi supply and service improvomonrs aro
sparso. Alrhough taxi supply dara was mado availablo by the ITLA, geographic
inconsistencios berwoon taxi supply data and population tend to limit the validity of
long-term comparisons to tronds within classos of cities - doregulatod. ro-rogulatod
and rogulated (seo graph on par,e 14). It is apparonl toat growth in taxi supply in
curronrly-dorogulatod cities has stabilizod. Meanwhilo. taxi supply has doclined
rdativo to population in re-regulatod and regulatod cities. In re-rogulatod citios, this
roflocrs a conri:1Uing corroction to tho rapid growth in taxi supply that occurrod with
dorogularion (no to: for a description ",f changos in rogulatory structuro by city, seo
"Posr-Doregulation Rogulatory Changos". bdow).
8 US DOT, Effim of R<r;u!.rrory RcviIion in San Di<go, 1983. Table B-9.
Analysis of T axi.ab &gU/&rion and lJ"egula<,on
Final Report pag< J J
c
.2
C O.S
:;
a.
o
c..
g 0.6
".
~
'" 0.4
.D
.
"
Changes in Taxi Supply & Industry Structure Following Deregulation
1.2
0.2
o
Soattle
Oakland Berkeley Avorage Portland Phoenix San Diego
I Before ,,~ Aftar ~ ".Cha,,>~
Souz::c: USOcr/UM'P.. OJC sn:dics on me cfi'ccu of faxigubtol)" revision. 1983.1984
.lCY.
.20-/.
.30%
-400/.
.500/.
--60%
Net Change in Percentage Distribution of Taxis by Company Size
30%
20"10
10%
0%
"--~
.",'
<
-".:
~~
~~.
.:.~
~~~-'
"':1'
!;~
Berkeley
Oaldand
Phoenix
San Diego
Seattle
.1 cat!
02103cab$
1141030catls
o "..ore than 30 cabs
Sauce: USOO"lUMlr. ~e INdies on the cffe:::.s of~to~' It:'VlJion. 198.3-198.1
s~.o~
70.0~~
60.0~;' ,.
0.
a.
5a.O~. ,
III
E
.
(C.O.,. a
c
.
.c
"
30.00". C
.
~
.
20.0% c..
10.0%
0.0%
AnAlysis a/Taxicab Regulation 1"'4 Dn--ruJation
Final Rcpon page /2
Response 10 Telephone-Based Service Requests
After Deregulation
I Seatti,cl
60%
50%
<10"10
"0
0
.
,
;; 30%
a:
0
c.
~
20%
10%
0./.
Mini Fleets
(1-3)
~ 25%
c:
~
o
~ 200/.
b
.,
;;
~ 15Y.
;;
a:
c.
~ 10./.
Independent
Fleets
Large
Service
Companies
25.0
20.0
..
.
:;
o
15.0 I
10.0
5.0
0.0
c-
E
i=
.
o
c
o
c.
o
~ Sl1urr",," USDOT. E.ffiruDI
Gt'pUfO'7 &visu,n in .ft'.3uk. IN]
Trip Refusal Ra:e
1:.
Response Time
I San Diego I
35%
30"/.
l'
12
10 "
.
:;
c
8 I
.
E
1=
6 ~
c
o
c.
o
4 ~
Tri" Refusal Rate
Response lime
5%
0./..
Independent
Associations
$rr: 'f Fleets
Large Service
Company
.:.
2
Sill,"t': OSDOT. Effias 1I/
/lrpJ4tory/lrvUu,1I in 5411 LJY;p. IN3
o
Analysu .[Taxicab RcguLzli.,. and Dc....~ti.n
Final Report pat' 13
Taxis per 1,000 Population (median values)
1.10
1.00
,
0.90
O.BO
0.70
0.60
(An:.
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
Oereculated
Ciiies
Ae--reguln:od .
Citie,
Regulated
Cities
Note: geographic inconsistencies between taxi supply
and population data skew the cabs pe; 1,000 figure and
thus comparisons across categories rr.ay not be accurate.
The 1985-92 trends, however. should be valid.
S()"1T:t: tTiA Tu~.:b he' B()(1K IIfltI US Cnuw. Su Affa:dix B far tkuils.
01985
51992
AlUllysu of T ",,;cab &gulation an4 Deregulation
Final Repon pag' J4
S,.n,iu Quality
The quality of raxi servicc is affecred by several variables, including: (I)
responsiveness ro customers; (2) vehicle condirion and cleanliness; and {3l driver
behavior. The case srudies of rhe effecrs of deregulation provide limited. b"t
consistent, dara on rhe first two of rhese variables. Informarion on driver benavior is
rcCerenced in the case studies, bur is less rigorously measured.
As nmed above in "Level of Service", the short-term effects of deregulation
included a slight improvement in waiting times ar cabsrands, an insignifica;', change
in response rimes ro relephone-based se:vice requesrs, and a significant inerec,se in
service refusals and no-shows. On bal~nce, ir can be said that deregulation provided
marginal improvements in CUstom,,;r responsiveness, bur only for rhose customers thar
taxi operators deemed ro be high prioriry (as evidenced from rhe rrip refusal rare).
The effect of deregularion on vehicle condirion can be assessed by chlnges in
vehicle age and inspecrion resulrs. In San Diego, vehicles owned by new macker
entrants - generally independents 2,d ,mall fleer owners - were observed to be 7.1
years old on average, versus 2.9 years for rhe large service company rhat held mosr of
the ra."i licenses prior ro deregularion (see graph on following page). Two years
following deregulation. all fleers oferatcd with yet older vehicles. In Seartle. rhe
median vehicle age increased to 6 )'ears old following deregulation from 4 years old
prior to deregulation9, Further, vc;,:c!e inspection failures inereased ro 35% tWO years
following deregulation from 20% r:le )'ear prior to deregulation. Both cases suggest
thar a large influx of new entranrs caus", all operators [0 defer invesrment until
m:lIker condirions allow a greater r.,cu,,, on investment.
Information on changes in driver behavior following deregulation is scant. Ar
major cabs rands and airporrs, however, over-supply of raxis was consistently reported
to result in aggressive solicitarion or passengers and confrontarions among drivers. ,
There is no evidence, hearsay or orherwise, indicaring rhar deregulation acrec to
improve relarions berween drivers and customers,
Administrative Cosu
. Changes in adminisrrative com as a result of deregularion depend on several
variables, including: (1) the volume of new market entrants; (2) license applicarion and
vehicle inspection procedures; (3) rhe frequency of rare changes; and (4) rhe fee
structure and cost recovery policy of rhe local jurisdicrion,
The USDOT case srudies 0:1 the effects of deregularion indicate thar
adminisrrative costs either did not change or increased following deregularion, In San
Diego, open entry was reported to increase the time and dollar COSt of permit
processing and related activitiesIO. This was influeneed primarily by rhe volume of
9 USDOT/UMTA, Effim ofTttxi Rtt;'.da,ory Rtvision in Sta"k, 1983. p. 98.
10 USDOT/UMTA, Effim ofTttxi R'l;"Its,ory Rtvision in San DitKO, 1983. pp, 200-204,
Ana/Viis of1iz:,Mab Rtgultstion an,! Dcrtr.uJation
Final Report pagt J 5
Comparison of Fleet Age by Size of Taxi Company. ;;an Diego
(one year after deregulation)
oyer 30 cabs
4 to 30 cabs
2 to 3 cabs
1 cab
~ en '" '"
'" ~ ~ ~
'" co '"
'" '" '" '"
>- >- >- >-
~ ':' M '<T
V 0- M
~
100.0%
90.0%
80.0%
c:;
'"
70.0%
'0
60.0% "
.,;j Cl
'"
"J 50.0% ~
-, .
ro.;l "
"'i'i 40.0% .~
~ "
. :;
.~ .~ 30.0% E
~... ::J
~j 20.0'% u
) 10.0%
0.0%
en :::!
~ ~ '"
'" co "
" '" >-
>- >- en
co ... ^
.;, '"
how to read this chart:
each bar shows the percentage 01 a ileet
that is equal to or less than /he age
displayed on the horizontat axis.
source:
U5DOT/UMTA. Effects of Taxi Regulatory Revision
in Sa" Diego, 1983, p. 8.11.
[continued from previous page]
new permit requests submirred by market entrants. In Seatrle. ,taff cOStS were
reponed to increase due to the larger number of taxis to be impected. Inspection
effortS were exacerbated by the provision for quanerly fare ch""ges, which
necessitated a corresponding increase in meter validations II. Oakland and Berkeley.
in contrast. experienced immaterial changes in coStSl2. As nOted earlier, open enrr{in
rllese cities did ,not result_ in a large influx of new operators.
In the cities for which objective and con~istcnt data are available regatding the effects
of deregulation. the fuJly-deregulated model (i.e.._open entry and ind:mry-set fares) appears
to have yielded few desired changes in taxi service. An increase in the number of taxis was
the most clearly-arrained objective. Other unanticipated and unarrractive resulrs that were
associated with the large influx of new operators encouraged most open entry cities to
reconsider taxi detegulation. These post-deregulation changes in regulatory structure are
described in the following section.
11 USDOT/UMTA. Effie" o/Tai R<r;.lalory Revision in Sea,,". 1983. p. 146.
12 USDOT/UMTA. Tai R'l"IaIOry Revision in Oakland 0- Berkeley. C,,/ifom!a: 1'"0 Case Seud!cs. 1983. p. 54.
A1l4iysis o/Taxicab &ru"zWIII ~nd Dmru"zrion
Final Report pag.16
nost-Deregulation Changps in Regulatory Structure
In respo'nse (0 lb: problems nOled abl)"c, mOSI of lhe cilics lhal deregulated hav.
since r(,'erred (0 some form of cegulation. AI; shown in the graph on the following page
(top). this wave of re-rerulalion was led by the largcst cilies of the group that had the mOSI
Intonsi"e airpon aClivit)'. Parricularly notablc was a shift from opon entry (0 some form of re-
regulation. pre~=nted in . he lable below.
Date of Initial Tvocof&-Rc...,J"tion Dau or R~-
Ci". Da~vu!n('ion Rrrr'J''''rion
..
1\c1anca 1965 Prc-dcrcrmincd ceiling. 1981
rc(!ul:ltl:d fares
Indi:ln:Ip,~lis 1973 Pre-decermined ceiling. i 974'
rcou),tcd farcs
Milwauk ;c 1979 Pre-determined ceiling. 1992
rcpulJtcd f;arcs
O,kland 1979 Pre-determined ceiling. 1968
rc"ub.!ed f.arcs
53n Diego 1979 Prc-dtccrmincd ceiling. 1982
maximum farcs
SeJttle 1979 Pre-determined ceiling. 1984
maximum farcs
Phoenix 1982 Aitnon f"nchisc 1983
5acramc:r..to 1982 furnorc pcrmirs unknown
.
The current reguialory strucmre for the origin,1 21 deregulated cities shows a clear
split berween tlte fully-rec;ulated and fully deregulated models. The current SlalUS of lhese
,cities is as follows: (I) six cities lhat were previously open encry have re-regulaled alllaxi
';ervices: (2) cwo cities lh"\l were previously open enery have regulaled airporr-based serviees.
'.vhile retaining an open entry approach for non-airporr services; (3) lhree cities had
deregubted farcs only, and have concinued this practice while retaining entry controls (e.g'.,
convenience & necessiry'; (4) six cities retained a minimum standards approach; ;nd (5) four
cities retained the fully-ckregubted approach. combining open entry with indust:v-set fares.
Of the thirteen cities tho had originally opted for open entry. only fout continue this practice
roda\'.
The cities that have fully" re-regulated" taxi services tend to be larger cities in
which deregulation (i.e.. open entr}') had amacted a large number of independent operacors -
:\danca. Indianapolis. San Diego. and Semle. Two other large cities - Milwaukee and
Oakland - re-regulated for other reasons.
Two open ent:y cities - Phoenix arod Sacramento - chose co regulate taxi service
rrom airports. rhe most ,'isible source of prob'ems, but retained the open entry system for all
other taxi services. In th'Ose cities. private-secror "franchise systems" also have evolved wherein
major hotels enter into exclusive concracts wi,h taxi companies to provide service co cheir
I'uests. Thus, the formal and informal regulation of major stand markets was dfected in
some deregulated cities co protect consumers who are unlikely or unable co shop for the best
. .
I:LXI among compellng s~rvlces.
.1na/ysu .fT~a" R<gul4fio f and Dn-<gul4rion
Final &pon pag< 17
:i~(i~Current:Rtr' "tilato'" .StructUi:'''\i ,feltles"'''?
~tlllmDl!retiJat~cr;Tax% BetWe'~9791&119f3'
.
. 0
,
+
+
... .:.
<t +
( ) +
.. .:.
.
~~. .
25,000
20,000
~
<IJ
o
o
o
~
<IJ 15,000
-
c
QJ
E
~ 10,000
ro
c.
c
UJ
5,000
o
o
200
400 600 800 1,000 1,200
Population (OOOs)
+ Re-Regulated
o Airport Regulated
.:. Minimum Standards
~ Deregulated
;:.~'1Reg!,llatciiy;.5thJctureSin:m~regulatedand Re::Regulated Cities'- J,
Current Regulatory Structure in.
the 21 Deregulated Cities
6
5
.
.
= .
<3
'0 3
.
"
E 2
,
z
6
5
.
.
~ 3
<3 2
'0 1
.
" 0
~ .,
z -2
-3
..
J>
~.~ .r$-t-
<t-';::'v~.,\c ~""'~.,\e
Changes in Regulatory StructurL'
Compared to Initial Deregulation
Open l!nlry
Mlnlmunl Standard.
Franchi.. Syslem
Convenience & nee...it'!
population retlo
Predetennlned Coiling
.'
.<+
~ ~.~
Aru:/ysu ofTaxiub &gu/4rum ''','' Dmgukrion
Final Report page 18
Th~ ~ici~s which had limit~d d~r~gulation 10 far~ only r~pore~d no significant issu~s
and (0 our knowl~dge hav~ mad~ no ~nsuing r~gula(Ory chang~s. Ea~h of th~s~ Cili~s has
~nrry r~Slrictions, how~v~r. Th~ citi~s includ~: (1) Tampa (population ratio approach); (2)
D~s Plain~s, Illinois (conv~ni~nc~ & n~c~ssiry approach); and (3) Charlo((~ (franchis~ sysr~m
approach).
Th~ citi~s which cmploy~d a minimum srandards approach (0 markel ~nrry, which is
a mid-poinr b~rw~~n full d~r~gulation and full r~gulation of caxi s~rvic~s, lik~wis~ r~pore~d no
significanr issu~s and accordingly hav~ mainrain~d this srruccur~. Thcs~ citi~ includ~: (1)
Poreland, Or~gon; (2) Fr~sno, California; (3) Madison, Wisconsin; (4) Kansas City. Missouri;
(5) Tucson, Arizona; and (6) Jacksonvill~, Florida. Th~ minimum slandards (~.g... 24-hour
disparch capabiliry) ~x~rcis~d in th~~ ciri~s acr to rais~ th~ COSl of mark~r ~nlry. thus
discouraging ind~p~ndcnc own~r-op~ra(Ors thaI ar~ nor affiliar~d wirh a taxi coop~rariv~ or
company.
Th~ four citi~s which hav~ r~lain~d a fully-d~r~gulat~d SYSl~m ar~ among th~ small~sl
of rh~ Cili~s lhat had initially impl~mcnr~d full d~r~gulalion. Th~s~ citi~s includ~: (I)
B~rkel~y, California; (2) Spokan~, Washington; (3) Tacoma, Washingron; and (4)
Springfield, Illinois.
*
*
*
*
.
In r~rrosp~ct. the ~ff~cts of ta..xi d~r~gulati[)n hav~ rang~d from b~nign (0 adv~rs~,
d~p~nding on local conditions and mark~ts. Th~r~ app~ars (0 b~ scant ~vid~nc~ thar
doregulacion fully achi~ved th~ goals on which its impl~mencation was pr~miscd. though
som~ goals c1~arly w~r~ achi~ved (e.g., mor~ taxis, less r~gulatory involv~m~nr by
gov~rnm~nc). M:lrk~t imperf~ctions p~culiar to th~ taxi industry, including unusual proquct
su!,ply (~.g.. fim-in, first-oue qu~u~s at cabstands) anci consum~rs' lack of knowl~dg~ of taxi
p"c~ and qualiry, t~nd (0 n~gate th~ improv~m~nr in pric~ and p~rformanc~ associar~d with
d~r~gularion in orh~r industri~s.
.
Ale 1(YIis of T iVXab :'.'cgrJation tln4 ncr.grJatiorr
Fin:a.l Report page /9
APPENDICES
A: Current & His~orical Regulatory Changes
in Deregulated Cities
B: Comparative L-ice and Supply Statistics
Bibliography
APPENDIX A:
Current & Historical Regulatory Changes
in Deregulated Cities
z
o
-
....
<:
...:i
o
o
gj
~
U
~
....
~
(JJ
r;l
o
z
<:
::::
u
IX
o
..,
<
~
-'I 'J . 0==- .
>.~ ",,0 NO 0 C 0' N~ on
- ... <"" << < < "":;
c." on;;:: 00 M _0 "'<- ON
Eo 'C ." . z- -- M"': <- . - - C- O . ." .
-"" .<- ZZ N"" Z ., M"" ..,.<- ..,.00
"t. .... - .... .... V) .... .... .... ....
.
O?
c 0- I >
.S '"
." "0
:g C r
et 'u ~
'" .!:! '"
!:l:: " ~
v- v. .e
v- v. v-
i: " " ,
" " " "
u u " '"
t: c c " E
c <<l .;j E
U E ,
" u " " " " " u u " > " " " > " " " "'"'
E ~ E E E E E E E E c E E c c > E E ~~
" " " " " " " '" r. 0 " " ;; 0 0 '" "
v- ~ ~ v- ~ v. v. v. v. v. U v. v. ~ U ell v. v. v. -
c
.S
'"
:;
ell
u
!:l::
:.-
~
u
Z
00-
'"
~
ell
.=
'u
u
-
v. "
v. ~
" "
u~
~ E
o<l ~
> .-
S ~
u E
"
'"
~
N M
"" ""
a- a-
c
o
-=
~
e:.
"
!:l::
~
o
o
."
~
'c
....
~
.9 U
E ':'
c "
.9 E
~ E
c u
c.>
o 0
C. ell
8-
?:
~v.
_ u
C l;l
U ~
~
t.-
~
U
~
<
U
ell
"
~
o
.c
u
c
<
-...
'8
u
~
E
"
c:
...
C-
o
'"
'"
C-
CD
c:
'u
u
"
c:
.~
..
;:;
""
..
c..
~~
- ~.
c: ",'
..~
<
o
"
E
"
<:
o
ell
C
'u
u
"
13 ~
.5 E
E ...
~ ~
"0 >-
~ 0
C. ell
00
a-
-
~
E
u
c
u
C.
o
~~
- ~
c "
u ~
c
.2
~
co
u
~
U
~
^
^
cr:
~~
E ~
u _
C v.
" C
c."O
o .:
o
""
C'>
ell
C
'ij
U
'" U
u '?
.~ ~
u E
u E
'" ~
~ 0
C.ell
~v.
C ~
u~
<
U
:>,
u
u
-t:
u
~
o
v.
v.
u
u
u
C
<<l
>
c
o
~u
... '?
.~ ~
"fie;;
f,i-5
~ c
~ .-
N
""
a-
-
:>,
.;;;
v.
u
u
"
c
'"
a u
u '?
u E
c u
'S E
u E
> u
c >-
o 0
u ell
~v.
- ~
fi.!!
u
z
~
E
0::
"
.c
U
?;>
.;;;
v.
u
u
u
c
olJ
~o
c v.
'S ~
u v.
> C
c:'"
8 .5
~n
E l;l
u ~
...J
v.
U
c
.;;
E:
v.
"
Q
?;>
v.~
v.",
" U
U v.
~ 'e
"'~
? u
~ '?
u E
c: "
'2 ~
u ~
> ..
C >-
o 0
u <>0
""
a-
- <-
"" co
a- C'>
U
'?
E
u
E
E
u
>
o
co
E _
... u
- v.
v. .
:>,-
v. C
" "
v. E
:c E
u u
c >
" 0
..=co
~~
E l;l
u ~
X
f-
o
::l
""
Ui
~~
c ~
" -
5 ~
c.'"
o .5
C'>
<-
C'>
<<
- -
zz
~v.
- ~
c '"
u ~
o
c
v.
U
~
t.:..
o
v.
'0
~
"
'" ~
c ~
~.!:
E E
c c
E .~
:s ~
E E
N
""
C'>
-
~R
c ~
u _
C ~
u C
c.]
0._
~~
- ~
c "
u~
c
.2
~
co
u
';'
"
~
^
^
cr:
,..,
<-
C'>
.S!
;;
~
c
.S!
;;
~
[
.~
'0
c.
r.
C
"
~
..5
C
E
u
c
~
0'
~~
- ~
c "
" ~
z
o
0-
o
:e
ell
.=
"
u
'0
"
.=
E
...
;:;
'0
..
~
C.
~
'"
~
"
'" ~
c u
~~
v.
E E
c c
E E
:s .~
S E
..,.
<-
c-
M
00
C'>
~
E
"
c
OJ
c.
o
?;>
.;;;
v.
"
u
"
c
'"
a u
u '?
u E
c u
'a e
u e
> u
c >
o 0
u ell
~~
E l;l
...~
~~
- ~
5.:!
c
.S!
;;;
:;
ell
~
~
...J
\:.
~
.:;:
c
o
v.
""
U
'"
~
^
^
cr:
~
v.
:!
v. U
s~
E v.
:5.g
E .=
..,. M
"" 00
'" a-
- -
N
M
~
'ij
u
u
"E ':'
c E
.~ ...
u E
u E
'" ~
e 0
C.ell
~~
E l;l
u.....
o
~
?;>
U
::l
v.
f,i
~
~
n
0 ::: 0 ;0 0 ;0 . 0 ::: :>
0.
n_
'" ." ." 0 Y 0 Y Z Y ::: :::
.. 0 :r ~ ~ "
0 ::l 0 ~ y y " y ~ ..
~ 0 0.
3 ~ " ~ [ ~ 0- ~ " ;;;'
;;' 0. "! c: c: c 0
.0 0. r.-
g 0. ~ ~ . ~ r.- ."
" " n n Q
<5 0 :>- ." '" n '" < '" !' ~
" " E. .:;:
'" N r :>- ~ :>-
E. :0 ~ -
n
:>- g 0' 0
" "
~ n ~ n ~g . ~~ 0;" n ~ n ~ n ~" ~g ~" ~g >-l
~ g " g g g .. " ~ "
~ a~ ~ -
!:l~ n ~ !:l~ !:l~ n -=2 n ~ n ~ n ~ ~~ n - '<
~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~ "
n
" " '" ~ " 0 0 0 ~, 0 " '" "
0 0 0 0; ~ " 0 0 " " 0 0 0
'0 '0 < ;;; n n " " " 0 " <"0
C C " 0. " < < ,. " E. n c
3 n n " " ~
~ ~ ~ " " " " ;; n :0 " :0
0
0 0' 5 '" a g ~. ,,' ~~ g g" 3 0'
~ E. -=2 " ~ n
" " S' r. 0 " " [
" 0 n " ~
~ ~ " " c;; n ~
:0 :0 ~ ,0. 0. :0 ~ 0. :0 ~ :0
0' 0' ~ 0 0' !!. 0' :;::l
n ,.. S C- o. n "
~ g !!, ~. ~
" r.
'" ~ S' n S' [
'" n n
~ '" n n ...
v. ~ g'
I - v. ~
-
t...> '':;: '<
,:::! I
- - - - - - - - - - - 0
'D 'D 'D 'D 'D 'D 'D '" '" '" '" '"
00 -.l 00 00 00 -.l 00 00 '" -.l 00 -.l "
'" '" '" - 00 '" V> '" ,...> '" "'''' i>
0 " 3 zo "0 "0 0 " 0 "0 0 5' 3
'0 ~ -" ~ ~ '0 ~ 0 ~ "0
n 5' :>-g n n n n " n 0 0. ?'
" 0. 0. " c- < 0. " c
3' n n n n n ~
n ~ 0 " " " " " n- o ~ ~
" c ~ g :J 3 " a ,,' 3 g 0;
~ 3 ~ ~. ~ " .:;? ~ " Z
0. S' S' 0 5' !! 0.
~ " " n " 0
~ n 0 0 0 ~ :<
0. 0. 0. 0. ~ c- o.
n ~ ~ :;::l
~ 0 0 0 c. 0
- ~ n !!. 0 - 0
n ::;> ..
!!, S' 5' r. S' ~ c
"" n ~
5' '" '" n '" 0
v. :r g'
.. t:3 ~ t:3 v. <:;
'" .:;: ;;;'
'" - '" '" 0
8 f:! .to. ~ .
-
.
~ ~ ~ z ~ '" N:D .. ~ '" ~ .. ~ ~ ~
" 3 " 3 0 0 5 0 ~ 0 3 3 3
3 3 - ""00
:>- < < < <
n " n n n ::;00 n " " n n 0 0 0
3 3 3 g n
" " " 3 c
: n n n ..,
0 n ..,
~ "0 ~ ~ ~ g
~
v. :0 ~ ~ ~ -
n g !! g ~
- 0'
0
- ..
0' c
~ I ~
" g"
c::
"
.... , ,
z .... z ....'" '" .... ..... .... "tl tIl
00 P' '" ...,,,, 00 c
> '" 0 - !"'..., - - '" ' ..... V> :!. "C
..., > 0", 0000 00 .to. ~.to. :... 0 n"
0 V> 0 V> 0 o _
-...,
='
:;;>
"""
>
'-
o
;:;:
("'J
.,..
.....
>
z
C)
t=:l
CJ)
.....
z
""i
;I>
~
.....
("'J
;I>
t;:l
;:;:
t=:l
C)
c:
t""
;>
""i
.....
o
z
~
n
"
~
~
n
a
c
c-
o
~
o
~
~
~
1:
C.
'"
<
<;
o
~
E;
o
~
'1
~
o
..,
"
~
g"
o
~
[5
.2
?;
'"
"
'"
~
!:!.
.:;:
~
*
;::
.[
c
Co
o
~
<
~.
<
~
~
:::
II
"
8
5'
s'
"
8
'"
g
c-
o:
c-
'"
!:!.
.:;:
!:!.
.:;:
o
~
'"
o
;;'
;;;-
'"
.g
g
c-
o
~
'0
'0
'-'
()
o
c-
n
l':
cl
n
'"
o
, '"
I :>
I N
I
I
I
I
o
II
[5
o
-0
o
'"
o
a
.:;:
Pre
lA.:;:
I.., ~
I ~ ~
n n
3 ""
sJl
" "
gt;"
. -
~ ..
g ~
!:!.
.:;:
;:;J
II
5' 8
g. 2:
~ s
.:;: "
.:. 8
!! '"
g
c-
a
'"
~ ~
.. 0
ZZ
- -
:>:>
:::
r. g
D~
'" -0
o 0
<-0
r. "
g fI
~. o'
" '"
~ ~
'" ~
~ o'
-
'"
'"
N
0"0
~.g
-. "
a t;'
~ =.
8 g
~~
~ o'
~ ~
.. ..
ZZ
- -
:>:>
...;
~
"0
?
."
r
~g
" -
"'.:;:
.., -0
o 0
<"0
" "
3 0;-
S =.
" 0
a '"
~
~ ~
!? o'
o
o
8
Z
-
:>
-. 0
"'"0
0."
r;; 0
- ..
.:;: 0
~~
;.:,
o
8
~
~ ~
Z....,
>'"
o
...;
"
o
o
8
?
~
:>
f?g
~.:<
"c3 z
ti ;;
g
~
'"
g
'"
'"
-
-
'"
'"
-
-'0
0-0
c-"
r;; 0
- ..
.:;: 0
~ .~
~ ~
:l "
.. ..
....
"'-
'0
8
o
V,l
'0
:>.
"
..
=>
"
0:
:l
:r:
~g
n -
"'.:;:
"" "0
o 0
<"0
" "
3 <;"
~ g'
~ ~
'" ~
!! o'
-. 0
""0
0...
r;; "
- ..
.:;: "
~~
'" '"
3 3
" ..
ZZ
- -
:>>
o
V,l
"0
o
,....
~
!'
:l;
>
~g
.. -
"'.:;:
-
'"
'"
o
Z'"
-"
>8
..
ZZ
- -
>>
;:;J
v
v
~
'1
~
..
..,
=.
~
o'
'"
0;>"
~ a
lA.:;:
o
"0
..
"
"
a
.:;:
.., "0
o 0
<"0
" "
~ ~
::: o'
~ ~
'" ~
!? o'
-
'"
'"
...
"0
~
..
c-
..
;;
~
E.
"
..
c-
o
!:!.
5'
..,
_. 0
"'"0
c-"
r;; 0
- 0
.:;: "
n~
o
'"
"
~
n
~
:>
: ~ g
~~
'"
....,
'"
zz
):;;
zz
- -
>:>
"
v
v
~
'1
~
"
..,
"
~
g'
rrg
" -
"'.:;:
o
'0
..
o
g
q
.., 0
o 0
< o.
.. <
3 R>
8 "
" ..
a 0
, "
'" '"
!!. '"
-
'"
'"
'"
n
5"
'"
..
c-
..
'"
~
s 0
~]
s' ;;
" 0
o -
~.:;:
i?
~
..
'"
'"
o
g.
~
(l
..
N
.!!.
o
n.
.:.: 0<
:Q..""
"- .
V,l
g
C
n'
..,
o
()
:>
. ..:j
;,
"
-
~
E
"
n
..,
C
[
5'
o
-0
.g
~
~
o'
'"
.....
'"
t:l
"
-
"
Z
n
"
I."
<R
c
;:;
-
g'.
()
C
.:j/
n
o
-
." .
<R
.c" .
'" [:.:.:
'0',
c-:
.i'~::,ii
:r. .c .~~
:n':~:.:;;;
.~""-< ."
'.
:..
0..
.:;:
.
;so:
;l>
'-<
o
:lO
(j
:r:
~
C)
l:J
tf.l
2
..,
~
....
(j
;l>
t:=
f;J
C)
c::
t"'"
;l>
..,
....
o
z
..
APPENDIX B:
Comparative Price and Supply Statistics
COMPARISON Or- TAXI PRICE AND SU~PLY IN :JEREGlILATEC. REREGt::-A.TEO. A::O REC:ULATEO CITI!:S
5.Mile Fare Taxis er 1 K ptlp Population Number of Taxis
Category/Cities 1985 1985(92$) 1992 1985 1992 1985/ 1992 1985 1992
_ft~~-I._:;l'!L;IIJ.'_~I'ed'~_~_'~tt!~.~\.'..;;..:.;~.~.~~ ~.-.,.~." ,.~. .....~t~,l~,~Jt..,~.',.~.j,~,;."....,. ...~...:~....'_i.';..~.;;....:..l:...~.~;. ......_' :~'" .~.~...:.~. :1~.,';';~ -.-<: "),:;::'" . . ' .: ", ""'~'.- ~ ':;_~ q1~?;; '7...>
;;:;'::0 ~'u_ ~ ---- ,C'~.20 :: S10.79 '-S~70 -'''''~ci:2~- .-.', 0':15'- ~:'! ... -';0;' _.:, '.~~, . .' ~1.;~~:~:
KansasCily 56.20 S7.27 57.50 1.19 1.30 444/ 431 530 560
Madiso" 55.83 56.83 58,40 0.42 v.52 16B ' 204 70 t07
Phoenix 56.70 S7.86 57.22 D.39 0.49 8331 10~3 325 506
Portland 56.BO 57.9B 5B.20 0.G7 0.98 365 367 24., 360
Sacramento 57.00 58.21 59.94 0.77 0.55 294 I' 401 225 219
Tampa 55.75 56.75 5B.15 1.20 0.B9 2B5 450 343 400
Tucson 56,40 57.51 57.BO 0.35 ').19 371 I 425 130 BO
Average 56.73 57.90 5B.36 0,65 0.63 3791 465 241 2B7
Median 56.55 57.6B 5B.1B 0.54 0.5' 330 413 235 290
Maximum 59.20 SID.79 S9.94 1.20 1.30 833 1.043' 530 560
Minimum 55.75 56.75 57.22 0.24 0.15 16B 204 63 62
it~"{t~!,!Jjj'tljjJl'E~?;fi -~f~1N?f E~~~ .fX~~urgl~flif:=T ~~"C'S0 -:-~-'~("'l-"C-' -FC":-';:,f'7";]!w:
Atlanta 55.BO 56.BO 57.30 3.39 ..30 42B 3QB -- ..-;..45'0..-'....,';562
Indianapohs 54.70 55.51 5B.15 0.52 0.52 705 757 366 394
Milwaukee 55.75 56.75 57.50 0.66 0.61 601l 657 400 400
Oakland 57.00 5B.21 59.40 1.29 1.16 3'9 3BB 450 450
San Diego 5B.00 59.3B 59.00 0.99 0.7B 931 1.151 920 900
Sea"l. 56.BO 57.9B 5B.00 1.15 1.32 490 530 562 700
.
Average
Median
Maximum
Minimu,-n
56.34
56.30
5B.00
54.70
57.44
57.39
59.3B
55.51
5B.23
58.0B
59.40
57.30
1.33
1.07
3.39
0.52
1,45
0.97
4.30
0.52
excluding Atlanta
Average 56,45 57.57 5B.41 0.92 O.BB
Median 56.BO 57.9B 5B.15 0.99 0.78
Maximum 5B.00 59.3B 59.40 1.29 1.32
Minimum 54.70 55.51 57.50 0.52 052
,."'~ .~ '... - .~_..~-~ 'j;l;l)!:~: ,. ~ ~...,';t'~' --:Z--"""~-~.--'_____
.....W.l:!".:I"t=...~ - rYi1S ..~....~r,..,-~.....~ >f"('I.~:;.~'--*". l;/{i '-I' __., .. ..,....-. . . .
R~;'iil8ied~Clitu..':. ../1#;;_-..... -'!J.,. ;~"',...w ...'"~:::: ';~;.::, .~. ~t'~.. Z;'\ r.~:~>' .:: "" , "--. : ~_'~_
....--- to-.- ~,.._"'_... .-t-.... _n._"i>. .'.:Jl;.. _+__ :<-to no.. _ _....
Minglon 55.BO 56.BO 5B.30 3.05 3.46
Augusta 5UO 55.04 56.40 OA6 0.58
Baltimore 54.80 55.63 S6.30 1.41 1.60
Boston 56.70 57.B6 59.10 2.6B 2.67
Buffalo 56.15 57.21 5B.75 LOB 1.06
Las Vegas 5B.50 59.97 59.00 2.53 1.87
Memphis 55.35 56.2B 56.65 0.40 0.52
Mobile 55.20 56.10 57.15 0.24 0.27
New Orleans 55.90 56.92 55.90 2.B7 3048
Orlando 55.60 56.57 $6.91 1..67 1.21
Pittsburgh. 57.BO 59.15 5B.17 1.22 0.B2
Rochester S6.90 S8.09 58.20 1. 1 0 1.26
San Antonio 56.20 $7.27 $6.90 0.57 0.8t
San Jose 56.40 S7.51 $10.60 0.22 0.33
Tulsa 55.35 S6.28 57.25" 0.52 0.60
Average
Median
Maximum
Minimum
'56.05
55.90
5B.50
54.30
1.37
1.06
3AB
0.27
57.11
$6.92
59.97
55.04
57.71
57.25
510.60
55.90
1.33
1.10
3.05
0.22
5B5
549
931
3'9
617
60B
931
3'9
'-"'~'.':'.;-
:._ n.:':'
152
240
769
5691
346 I
179
646
205
561
133
410
246
B'6
673
375
423
375
B'6
133
Note: several deregulal~ and .'eou1aled Cities are omrtled due 10 incomplete data lor 1985 Of 1992.
Oeregulaled olias indude those using minimum staodarns. as well as open entry.
~
Far.., wi.:
O.rtvtd fn)m Inl.rnatloNl Taxicab ancl U....,.,. Allocation memOer SUt'lrllys fot 1911S and 1992.
011. tor Photrn:';"'" obtained ";1. i'lt.tVi....... eonduald by PIiee Wal.mouat.
1985 lares Wtlf. con....nf41O 1892 doll." based on !he CPI lor pn...all transpon.tion COSlS (USOOL Bureau of UXlr Slalistlesl
Papulation:
Estimated Irom US Census. 1985 popuJalicn was interpolated from 198-4 and 1986 Census 'Sllrnales.
1992 ~tion was .xttapo&ated based on g~ ral. berween 19813 ancl1990 Census estimates.
642
594
1.151
36B
697
657
1.151
3BB
175
2'0
721
571
3'3
306
576
lB'
462
lB2
365
234
931
B26
366
432
365
931
175
691
506
1,450
366
73B
575
1.5B2
394
540 569
450 450
920 900
366 394
... .'-":~':~ ..~~~~~~f&
464 605
110 140
1.0B5 1,151
1.525 1.525
375 365
453 573
256 300
50 50
1 .60B 1,60B
222 220
500 300
270 295
4Bl 750
150 270
196 219
516
375
1.60B
50
558
300
1.60B
50
BIBLIOGRAPHY
.
BlBLIOGRAPlf.'
1. General Studies
Airpon Operators Council International; Worldwide Airpor: Traffic Rqort; 1985 and 1990.
Frankena. Mark and Paul Pautler; An Economic Analysis 0/ Taxicab /(egulation; unpublished paper
for the Federal Trade Conunission; May 1984.
Gallick. Edward and David Sisk; "A Reconsideration of Taxi Regulation;" Joumal of Law.
Economics, and Organization 3:1; 1987.
International Taxicab Association; Does Taxicab Deregulation Make SellSe?; March 1984.
Interm.tional Taxicab Association; "The Case Again,t Taxicab Deregulation;" 1982.
International Taxicab Association; Taxicab Fact Book; 1985 to 1992.
Paratrans,it Services; 77ze Erperiences of U.S. Cities with Taxicab Op;:n Entry; Octob~r. 1983.
Rosenbloom. Sandra; "The Taxi in the Urban Transport System;" unpublished paper; December
1983.
Seligman. Joel; The Application of the Federal Antitrust Laws 'to Municipal Taxicab Regulation;
December 1983.
Shaw. L.. Gorman Gilbert. et. al.; Taxicab Regulation in U.S. Cities: Volume I (Final Report);
October 1983.
Stalians. Gene; "Regulatory Revision and the Taxicab lndustl'y: \Vha: We Have Learned;"
presentation for the New Zealand Taxi Proprietors' Federation; August 30. 1988.
Teal. Roger; "An Overview of the American Experience with Taxi D~regulation;" unpublished paper:
1988.
Teal. Roger and Mary Berglund; "Impacts of Taxicab Der~gulation in the USA;"
reprinted from Journal of TrallSporr Economics and Policy; January 1987.
II. Case Studies
Buck. James; "The Seattle U-Turn;" unpublished paper; S~ptember 1992.
Counry of San Diego. Department of Transponation; Taxicab Stud)'; January 1978.
Gelb. Pat; Effects of Taxi Regulato!)' Revision in San Diego, Califomia; May 1983.
Gelb. Pat; Effects of Taxi Regulatory Revision in Searrle. Washington; May 1983.
Gelb. Pat; Taxi Regulatory Revision in Porrland. Oregon: A Case Stud)'; September 1982.
. /1/.) ;~, 1#-
, . ",".' .' ,I,J tv'
~;;~~@il ~~!'~0
;t}:,b .
If'
Review of
Taxicab Regulatory Changes in
Cincinnati, Indianapolis, and Seattle
prepared by
Institute for Transportation Research and Education
North Carolina State University
Box 8601, Raleigh, NC 27695-8601
for
International Taxicab and Uvery Foundation
3849 Farragut Avenue, Kensington, MD 20895
May 1998
$25 for ITlF & ITLA Members
$50 for Non-Members
@ International Taxicab and Uvery Foundation
Review of Tuicab Regulatory Owagcs in Cincinnati. lndianapolis. and Seattle
1.0
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.4
1.5
1.6
1.7
2.0
2.1
2.2
2.3
2.4
2.5
3.0
3.1
3.2
3.3
3.4
3.5
4.0
4.1
4.2
4.3
4.4
4.5
5.0
5.1
5.2
5.3
5.4
6.0
Table of Contents
IlltrtHillctioll ......................................................................... 1
Importance of the Taxicab Industry
Taxicab Organization Structure
Theory of Taxicab Regulation
Taxicab Regulation in Practice
Deregulation in the Taxicab Industry
Study Goals/Objectives
Data Collection Methodology
I
2
3
3
5
6
6
Cillcinnatl, Ohio... ..... ....... .... ..... ... ...... ..... .... ............. ...... ....... 7
Introduction 7
Historical Changes in Taxicab Regulation - 1940's to 1993 7
Motivations For the 1994 Regulatory Change 8
Key Provisions of Regulatory Changes - February, 1994 9
Impacts From the 1994 Regulatory Change 12
Illcli~JIC>lis, IJtcli~1l ............................................................. lei
Introduction
Historical Changes in Taxicab Regulation - 1970-1993
Motivations For the 1994 Regulatory Change
Key Provisions of Regulatory Changes - 1994
Impacts of the 1994 Regulatory Change
16
16
17
19
22
~~tt14e, ~8U5I1iI1~oll ............................................................... ~~
Introduction 27
Historical Overview of Taxicab Regulatory Changes - 1979-1996 27
Motivations Leading to Additional Regulation in 1996 29
Key Provisions of the 1996 Regulatory Changes 29
Impacts of the 1991-1996 Regulatory Changes 32
Discussioll: Cross-City Compllrisons ......................................... 3ei
Introduction 36
What Taxi Regulatory Changes Occurred? 36
What Were the Motivations for These Changes? 37
What Have Been the Impacts of These Changes? 38
COIlc:lltSloltS ........................~................................................ '1!i
BibUography ..................................................................................... ... .... 48 .
Instiblle for T....porwionReoean:h and_on
1.0 Introduction
This report presents the results of a study of taxicab regulatory changes in three Cltles:
Cincinnati, Ohio; Indianapolis, Indiana; and Seattle, Washington. To understand the significance
of the study findings it is first necessary to understand the context in which these regulatory
changes occurred. This introductory section of the report presents provides background
information on the taxicab industry, taxicab company organizational structures, a perspective of
industry/government regulation, and a review of the study data collection process. Sections 2.0
through 4.0 describe the regulatory changes that occurred in each of the three cities, the
motivations for those changes, and the impacts of the changes. Section 5.0 provides cross-city
comparisons, and Section 6.0 presents study conclusions.
1.1 Importance of the Taxicab Industry
Myths and perceptions about taxicabs are very different from reality. Often viewed as a service
of last resort operated by poorly qualified drivers, the industry is frequently misunderstood both
by the public and by transportation policy-makers at all levels of government. In addition to
being the mode of last resort (transportation safety net) for the elderly, disabled and poor, the
taxicab is also the mode of choice for many business travelers, tourists, special school students,
corporations transporting customers and packages, hospitals transporting blood and medical
supplies, automobile dealers transporting service customers, and a wide range of businesses. It is
an industry for which images are very misleading.
One poorly understood characteristic of the industry is its availability of service. It is perhaps
unique as a nearly ubiquitous industry that provides service twenty-four hours a day, everyday.
It serves virtually all cities and towns in the U.S., and it does so through operations which, with a
few exceptions, are locally owned. Thus, it is an indigenous industry that is available nearly
everywhere at nearly any time.
The amount and range of service provided by taxicabs in the United States is staggering. In
1986, the last year for which national survey data are available, taxicabs transported 1.43 billion
passengers (Stanley and Burby, 1988). This figure compares with about twenty million Amtrak
passengers, approximately two billion urban rail passengers, and over five billion urban transit
bus passengers (Gross and Feldman, 1994). Taxicab operators in 1986 provided this service
using 170,000 taxicabs and operating 10.1 billion vehicle-miles. Urban rail systems that same
year operated over 400 million vehicle-miles, and urban buses operated about two billion vehicle
miles. Thus, the U.S. taxi industry is ~f comparable size--depending on the measure--of urban
transit buses and urban rail systems and larger than Amtrak.
These numbers, however, underestimate the size and importance of the taxicab industry. In the
past twenty years the taxicab industry has diversified through new services, such as executive
sedans, and through contracts with public agencies, such as transit authorities and human service
providers. In 1986 nearly two-thirds of the taxicab operators provided services under contracts
with hospitals, corporations, cities, transit authorities, and human service agencies. The extent of
Review ofT:uic:ab Regul:atory Ch:anges in Cincinnati. lndi:anapolis, and Se3nlc:
contracting is evident in the fact that in 1986 only 83.2% of the vehicles in the taxicab industry
were taxicabs. That is, there were 170,000 taxicabs plus about 34,000 vans, buses, executive
sedans, and limousines operated by taxicab companies. When these additional 34,000 vehicles
are included, the taxicab industry transports 2 billion passengers per year.
1.2 Taxicab Organization Structure
In interpreting the results of this study it is helpful to understand the organizational structure of
the taxicab industry in the U.S. and in these three cities. Typical of the local taxi industries in
other large U.S. cities, the local taxi industries in Cincinnati, Indianapolis, and Seattle are
characterized by three factors:
1. Independent contractor drivers;
2. Extensive competition; and
3. A variety of organizational structures.
It is appropriate to explain how these factors are present in these three cities.
According to a 1986 national survey, more than three out of every four taxi drivers work as
independent contractors (Stanley and Burby, 1988). "Independent contractor" in the case of taxi
drivers means that the driver either owns or leases his or her taxicab vehicle and is free to work
where, when, and how he or she wishes, subject to city regulations. Independent contractors
operate as small, one-person businesses rather than as employees. Given that the ~nd toward
independent contractor status has not abated in the eleven years since the 1986 survey, it is likely
that few employee taxi drivers remain in most large cities. The taxicab fleet owners interviewed
for this study indicated all their drivers worked as independent contractors.
One of the myths of taxicab service is the belief that a single company owns all the taxicabs in a
city. The Stanley and Burby 1986 survey found that in cities over 200,000 population only 6.9%
of the responding companies operated all the taxicabs in their cities. In fact, 58.9% reported that
they operated less than half of the local cabs, and many of these were operated by owner-drivers
who owned their own cabs but operated under the auspices of a fleet operator.
This large amount of local competition is evident in Seattle, Cincinnati, and Indianapolis both
before and after their recent regulatory changes. In 1994, before it opened entry, Indianapolis
had 392 cabs licensed among three major companies, severa! small companies and cooperatives,
and 26 independent owner-drivers. In 1995, prior to implementation of the requirement in
Seattle that all taxicab operators belong to an association, there were 210 independent owner-
drivers and seven companies. There was also extensive competition among 20 companies
operating in Cincinnati prior to the relaxation of entry requirements in 1994.
These three cities also reflect the national picture of organizations within the local taxi industry.
All three cities have taxi comnanies in which some vehicles are owned by the company and
leased to drivers and some vehicles which are owned by drivers but which are operated under the
auspices and color scheme of the company. All three cities also have associations or
Ins.bIt. for Transportalion _ and Education. May 1998
2
Review of Taxic:1b Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
coooeratives composed of owner-drivers. And, all three cities have large numbers of owner-
drivers who operate as one-person companies.
The importance of these three organizational forms results from the very different ways in which
they operate. Companies, as well as some associations, often work hard to market taxi service
among local businesses, tourist facilities, and general public. Companies and associations also
typically have dispatch services for their drivers, and in most cities operate twenty-four hours a
day. Individual owner-drivers, on the other hand, seldom do marketing, are not affiliated with
dispatch services, and normally serve walk-up locations such as airports and hotel stands.
1.3 Theory of Taxicab Regulation
The underlying theory and rationale for governmental regulation of l/IXicab services is that such
regulations are necessary to correct market imperfections. Simply put, market imperfections
exist when the necessary conditions for a free market are not met (Frankena and Pautler, 1984).
Some of the most important of these conditions are: many service providers; many consumers;
and perfect information among consumers about the prices and qualities of all providers. In
many industries these conditions are met. Restaurants are an example; there are many
restaurants, and prospective diners can examine a restaurant and even review its menu before
deciding to dine there. A diner can even leave a very unsatisfactory restaurant. Moreover, each
restaurant has a clear identity and location, so an unsatisfied diner can decide whether or not to
return to the restaurant and can tell his or her friends about the quality and price of the restaurant.
There are even reviews and guidebooks rating restaurants.
For taxi service the situation is generally very different. For local taxicab consumers who
frequently telephone for taxicab service, the conditions might be met. However, for other
consumers the situation is very different. Persons hailing a cab, engaging a taxicab in a queue at
a hotel or airport taxicab stand, trying to get a taxicab in the middle of the night, or simply not
frequent taxicab users all lack adequate information on alternative taxicab providers and lack the
ability to shop for cab service. And, an unsatisfied taxicab user-unlike an unsatisfied diner-
may be unable to exit a moving cab in hopes of finding another, more satisfying one. For all
these situations there is a need for regulations that ensure the taxicab user that some level of
safety and service is met by all taxicabs.
1.4 Taxicab Regulation in Practice
Generally, taxicab regulation is a municipal responsibility. It is entirely so in most states; in a
few states, such as Pennsylvania, Nevada, Maryland, and Kentucky, there is limited state
involvement in taxicab regulation.
Taxicab regulation is of two types: (I) economic regulation; and (2) safety regulation. The
second of these is relatively uncontroversial. Cities impose certain licensing requirements on
taxicab drivers and vehicle owners. Drivers must meet age, health, driving history, and character
standards. Vehicles must meet safety and design standards. While there is sometimes
I..tilllte for TnIIlIpOIIali... R......b .... EduClllion - May 1998
3
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Chnnges in Cincinnati, indianApOlis. and Seattle
controversy over how these standards are imposed and enforced, there is fundamental agreement
that cities should impose safety regulations on taxicabs and drivers.
Such is not always the case for economic regulation. Economic regulation consists of three
types: (I) entry controls; (2) fare regulations; and (3) service requirements. Of these the latter
two are also relatively uncontroversial. Virtually all cities, other than a few very small ones,
impose some restrictions on fares, either by setting a uniform fare or by setting a maximum or
minimum fare. Service requirements include two-way communication, 24-hour service,
prohibitions on soliciting passengers, conditions under which a driver can refuse to transport a
passenger, and many other such provisions.
It is the entry controls that provide the controversy in taxicab regulation. Entry controls are
requirements that cities place on applicants for taxicab operating licenses, not on taxicab drivers'
licenses. Cities vary considerably with respect to the strictness of their entry control, and there
are six categories in which these entry controls fall. These are:
1. Fixed ceiling or medallion (30.4 %)
2. Public convenience and necessity (25.4 %)
3. Minimum standards (17.6 %)
4. Open entry (12.2 %)
5. Population ratio (8.7 %)
6. Franchise (5.7 %)
The numbers in percentages are the percentages of U.S. cities with each type of entry control
(Shaw et al., 1983). Note that one-half of the cities with open entry had fewer than 10 taxis in
the city. Also, the restrictiveness of entry in cities using a population ratio depends on the ratio
chosen. .
Of these entry controls the first and last ones elicit the greatest attention. Economists, reporters,
and taxicab regulators in other cities point to New York City, which has had a medallion system
since 1937 and whose medallions now trade for over a quarter million dollars. To critics the
New York situation represents the archetypal example of the problems of a system that fixes the
number of medallions over time. On the other hand, the elimination of all entry control (#4),
which is discussed in the remainder of this report, creates a set of other problems such as higher
fares, poor quality drivers, overcrowding at key taxi stands, poor vehicle conditions, etc. (Price
Waterhouse, 1993; Gelb, 1983a and 1983b; Zerbe, 1983; Teal, 1987).
Often lost in the debate over entry controls is the fact that there are four other mechanisms for
controlling entry. To varying degrees these mechanisms blend control over entry, the ability to
expand taxicab supply to meet demand, and the preservation of competition. The franchise
mechanism, for instance, is used by Los Angeles to limit the number of taxi companies while
allowing these companies to compete with each other and to grow or contract according to how
successful they are in this competition. The minimum standards option means that there is no
limit placed on the number of taxicab providers but each one must meet certain standards of
customer service, such as a minimum number of taxicabs, a place of business, twenty-four-hour
dispatching service,and a maximum age of vehicles. The other two mechanisms are merely
ways to expand the total number of taxicab licenses over time if demand increases.
Institute for Transponation Research and Education _ May 1998
4
Review of Taxicab RegulalOf)' Clumges in Cincinnnb.lndi:mapolis.and Seattle
1.5 Deregulation in the Taxicab Industry
During the aftermath of the airline deregulation of 1978 there was a concomitant interest in
deregulation of other transport modes, including intercity buses, trucks, railroads, and taxicabs.
However, whereas these other modes were regulated at the state and national levels, taxicab
regulation is usually a local matter, and hence deregulation was a local decision. In fact, few
cities opted for deregulation; Price Waterhouse (1993) found that 21 cities had deregulated their
taxicabs prior to 1983 and that no cities were known to have deregulated between 1983 and the
time of the Price Waterhouse study in 1993.
Still, these 21 cities--especially Seattle and San Diego-received extensive attention from
transportation regulators across the country and were extensively studied (Gelb, 1983a and
1983b; Teal, 1987; Frankena and Paulter, 1984). "Deregulation" in the case of taxicabs almost
always has meant "open entry," a term that means a dramatic reduction in requirements that an
applicant must meet in order to be granted a license to operate a taxicab. A few cities have also
experimented with deregulation of fares, but primarily deregulation has meant open entry into
the industry.
These 21 cities show the dramatic differences between economic theory and actual results.
Proponents of taxi deregulation argued that open entry would enable new, better operators to
enter the taxi industrY, thereby instilling more competition which would improve service quality
and reduce fares (Frankena and Paulter, 1984). In reality, nearly the opposite occurred as fares
increased and service quality declined. New entrants did not enter the industry; rather, existing
drivers became independentdriver-owners and congregated at airports and hotels. Price
Waterhouse concluded, "In retrospect, the effects of taxi deregulation have ranged from benign
to adverse."
Dempsey (1996) has presented the theoretical explanation for the differences between the
predictions of deregulation proponents and the actual results. He argues that, unlike the other
deregulated transportation industries, the taxi industry is characterized by low capital costs and
customers who do not have the opportunity to shop among different taxicabs. As a result, in a
deregulated environment taxicab operators have a perverse economic incentive to drive down
their costs and service quality instead of competing for new customers. The result is a
proliferation of owner-drivers who can enter the market without incurring costs for a central
office, dispatching, 24-hour service, marketing, and sit at public stands at hotels and airports.
Given the results of the 21 cities' experiences, it is easy to understand why Price Waterhouse
found only 4 cities had retained their open entry regulations and that the impetus for re-
regulating the industry came first from the airports. The recent actions by Seattle represent a full
circle return to regulation after experimenting with open entry and deregulated fares in 1979
(Zerbe, 1984; Lewis, 1995; Avants et ai., 1995). The actions of Indianapolis and Cincinnati,
however, are noteworthy as the only two cities in the past decade or so that have chosen to
deregulate their taxi industries.
Inso.... for T....ponaIi... _ ond ll<l'...~0Il - May 1998
5
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
1.6 Study Goals/Objectives
This report presents the results of an examination of recent taxicab regulatory changes in three
cities: Cincinnati, Ohio; Indianapolis, Indiana; and Seattle, Washington. These three cities are
not similar in their regulatory actions. Two of the cities have implemented open entry while the
third has moved strongly in the opposite direction. However, given that few large U.S cities
have implemented new taxi regulatory policies in the past decade, the actions of these three cities
are of considerable interest. As a result, the International Taxicab Foundation has funded this
study to examine the impacts of the regulatory changes in these three U.S. cities.
The intent of this study is to provide accurate documentation of why regulatory changes were
made in each of the case study sites. The study is also intended to clearly identify and describe
the impacts that these regulatory changes have had on service quality, local taxicab fleet
operators and drivers, the tourism industry, neighborhood groups, regulatory agencies, and
passengers.
1.7 Data Collection Methodology
In conducting this study the research team relied on flI'St-hand information collected on-site in
the three cities. Two members of the team visited each city for approximately three days each.
In addition the team followed up with telephone calls to gather additional information and to
clarify information gathered during the in-person interviews.
The in-person and telephone interviews were conducted in all three cities with key stakeholders,
including representatives from: the taxicab industry (fleet owners and taxi drivers); the tourism
industry (hotels and restaurants); neighborhood groups; and local taxicab regulatory and
enforcement agencies. These interviews were conducted following an interview guide designed
to solicit information on three primary issues:
(1) What regulatory changes occurred;
(2) Why did the regulatory changes occur; and
(3) What have been the results of these changes?
By interviewing persons with different perspectives on the taxi industry the study team
endeavored to obtain a balanced, objective answer to these three questions.
InsU.... for TllUISporllIlillll ~ IIld _on - May 1998
6
Review of Tnxicab Reguhnory Chmtges in Cincinnati.indianapolis. and Seattle
2.0 Cincinnati, Ohio
2.1 Introduction
The metropolitan area of Cincinnati covers 3,810 square miles and had a 1990 population of
1,744,124. The City supports a variety of public transportation alternatives that includes fixed-
route bus and specialized human transportation. Taxicabs are a vital component of the public
transportation network. The area is serviced by 499 taxicabs representing 44 taxicab companies.
In 1994, Cincinnati adopted a taxicab ordinance that relaxed entry into the market. While this
ordinance maintained the public convenience and necessity form'of entry regulation, new criteria
were inserted which made it much easier for applicants to demonstrate that new services would
meet the needs of public convenience and necessity and thus gain entry.
2.2 Historical Changes in Taxicab Regulations. 1940's to 1993
During World War II, a two-tier system for regulating vehicles for-hire was implemented in
Cincinnati due to wartime restrictions on fuel. tires, and vehicles. This was the first occurrence
of opening entry into the taxicab industry in Cincinnati. In addition to taxicabs that operated
throughout the metropolitan area, automobiles for hire were authorized to operate only in
suburban locations. Business for the latter operators was generated through telephone calls only;
'automobiles for hire were, not allowed to use taxicab stands. Following World War II,
automobile for-hire operators were allowed to become licensed taxicabs.
In 1986, public vehicle regillation was transferred to the Office of Consumer Protection from the
Police Department. There were a total of 348 taxicab licenses issued to serve the city.
Additional licenses were not issued due to an inability of applicants to prove an unmet need to
serve the public convenience and necessity. Yellow Cab of Greater Cincinnati held
approximately 275 of the 348 licenses and leased licenses to individual drivers who operate their
own vehicle.
In 1987, an individual submitted an application for 80 taxicab licenses and proposed this new
company would use new vehicles and outfit drivers in uniforms. At a public hearing, existing
taxicab company owners prevailed on the City Council to place a moratorium on issuing new
licenses. One council member requested that the Chief of Consumer Protection rewrite the
ordinance to better reflect his view of how the taxicab industry should be regulated. The council
member who made that request subsequently became mayor.
The City Council dealt with the proposed revisions to the ordinance on a piecemeal basis. The
only significant change that was adopted was the addition to the vehicle safety inspection
program of an annual mechanical inspection to be conducted by an Automotive Service
Excellence (ASE) certified inspector.
Institule for TlIllSpOl1Olioo _1IId I!dllClllion. May 1998
7
Review of Taxicab Rep)acory Changes in Cincinnali,lndian:apolis. and Se:anle
During 1988-1993, the City operated under an unofficial cap of 348 taxicab licenses issued. I
This was an administrative policy decision; no cap on the number of taxicab licenses to be issued
was specified in the City ordinance. No additional taxi permits were issued during this time as
no applicant could prove the need for additional taxicabs under the public convenience and
necessity requirement.
In 1993, Yellow Cab Company of Greater Cincinnati was sold to an owner of approximately 60
taxicab licenses who had been affiliated with the company and whose vehicles wore the Yellow
Cab Company colors. During this individual's tenure as Yellow Cab Company owner, there
were problems with taxicabs failing mandatory vehicle emissions tests because of disconnected
pollution control equipment in 1996. As a result, the federal government levied a large fine
against the company, which led to that owner entering bankruptcy and defaulting on his business
loan from the previous company owner. Therefore, in 1996, ihe person who had sold the
company in 1993 repossessed the company. As a result of this incident, Yellow Cab Company
lost over 100 licenses, and when it was repossessed in 1996 Yellow Cab Company operated 168
taxicabs. It was reported that the publicity generated from the vehicle emissions test failures
resulted in an unfavorable perception of the taxicab industry by several local government
officials and increased political support for changing taxicab regulation in Cincinnati.
In 1993, just prior to the open entry ordinance, Yellow Cab was the largest taxicab company.
Skyline Taxi, the second largest company at that time, operated approximately 75 taxicabs.
There were a total of 20 taxicab companies operating 348 taxicabs. There were 8 independent
owner-drivers and six with twelve cabs or fewer. About 75 pe~ent of taxicab licenses and about
90 percent of the radio-dispatched taxicabs operating in Cincinnati were affiliated with three
companies.2 .. . .
2.3 Motivations For the 1994 RegnIatory Change
There were several motivating factors that lead to the 1994 regulatory changes in the City. First,
several taxicab license holders affiliated with Yellow Cab Company of Greater Cincinnati as
well as drivers from a variety of taxicab companies made City Council members aware of their
desire to own and operate their own taxicab company. The mayor and a majority of City Council
members came to believe that a greater number of independent owner-drivers should be allowed
to participate in the industry. Also, some of these local politicians disliked the practice of
"selling" taxicab licenses and believed licenses should not have a value other than that charged
by the City. .
Another motivating factor was that regulators and City officials believed that relaxing entry
requirements would result in an improvement in the condition of taxicabs and an improvement in
service, particularly to areas experiencing inadequate service. The City was investigating
I "Taxicab Regulation in Ohio's Largest Cities," prepared by the Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions,
Dayton,OH, 1997.
2 Arthur L. Herold, "Statement of Arthur L. Herold: Webster, Chamberlain & Bean, Washington, DC, on Behalf of
Consolidated Transportation, Inc., Skyline Taxi, Inc., and Veterans & Best, Inc. Before the Law & Public Safety
Committee of the City of Cincinnati," January 29, 1991.
1nsti..1O foe T.....,....aOll _b and I!ducaIion - May 1998
R
Review of Taxic:ab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
potential means of improving the safety, maintenance, and appearance of taxicabs and improving
drivers' appearances through changes to the ordinance regulating taxicab operations.3
Taxicab company owners were opposed to open entry because they believed that drivers would
start independent companies, generating two unfavorable consequences. First, existing
companies would need to recruit new drivers to replace those who left to form their own
companies. Second, new companies would not be required to utilize central dispatching, provide
24-hour service, or provide service to all areas within the City. Each of these practices, while
enhancing the quality of service, adds to the cost of providing taxicab service. If these
requirements were to be deleted from the ordinance, existing taxicab companies would be
competing unfairly with new independent operators who would not be required to shoulder the
same cost burdens to provide service, leading to an overall degradation in taxicab service. The
existing fleets will then have to re-evaluate whether to continue to provide late-night service and
to respond to short trip requests.
2.4 Key Provisions of Regulatory Changes --February, 1994
The Cincinnati taxicab ordinance was revised effective February 1994. The 1994 ordinance
(Chapter 407: Public Vehicles, Chapter 408: Drivers' Licenses for Public Vehicles) applies to
taxicabs, limousines, handicapped livery vehicles, animal-drawn carriages, and pedicabs.
The 1994 ordinance retained the provision that applicants prove a need for service based on
"public convenience and necessity" in order to obtain a license. However, the primary criteria
specified for public officials to determine if a public vehicle license is to be issued include:
>- "Whether the vehicle for which the application is made is a suitable vehicle to be
operated as a taxicab...."
>- "Whether the applicant's proposal will increase taxicab service in areas of the city
where taxicab service levels are deemed inadequate...."
>- "Whether the applicant's proposal includes service improvements above the level of
service generally available from taxicabs currently operating in the City of
Cincinnati."
>- "The applicant's history in the operation of taxicabs or other public vehicles in the
City of Cincinnati and other communities."
>- ''The applicant's procedures for inspection and maintenance of its taxicabs."
>- ''The applicant's training procedures for its drivers."
>- "The applicant's rules and regulations governing driver's appearance and conduct."
>- "Other matters presented by the applicant or other parties which relate to the issue of
the public convenience and necessity which the director deems of value in
determining whether the application should be granted or denied."
>- "In determining public convenience and necessity the director shall not consider the
impact an applicant's business may have on the business of existing license holders.,,4
J Ibid.
· Cincinnati Municipal Code, Chapter 407: Public Vehicles, Section 407-7: Issuance of Public Vehicle Licenses,
February, 1994.
Institulc for Tnnsporwioa -.... ond _... - May 1998
9
Review of Taxicab Regulatory CIwIgcs in Cincinrwi. lndilUUlpOlis. and Seanle
The final criterion has been interpreted as removing any burden of proof on the applicant for
showing public convenience and necessity and thereby effectively eliminating any cap on the
number of taxicab licenses that the City may issue. Anyone with a vehicle passing inspection
and appropriate insurance coverage may now apply for a taxicab license and be likely to be
granted a license.
The 1994 ordinance removes any service requirement, including 24-hour service, all-city service,
and dispatching service. In contrast, however, to its hands-off approach to service requirements,
the ordinance does stipulate a minimum fare of $3 per trip.
The 1994 ordinance does not state a cap on the number of licenses that the City may issue. There
were 347 taxicab licenses issued and 20 companies in business in 1993 just prior to open entry.
Following adoption of the new ordinance, the number of licenses issued quickly rose to 587, and
the number of companies in operation rose to 40. The number of independent owner-drivers
increased to 19.
In 1998 there are currently 44 companies licensed to operate taxicabs in Cincinnati. Twenty-
three of those companies are independent owner-drivers. Another three companies are
comprised of an owner-driver plus one or more other drivers who own their own taxicab. There
are currently 639 taxicab licenses issued. However, 110 of those licenses are now in escrow for
non-usage. Cincinnati is unique among the three cities in placing into an escrow pool licenses
that are surrendered, revoked, or not renewed. The City may also place a license in escrow due
to lack of an operational vehicle. A license or licenses in the escrow pool may be reclaimed
singly, severally, or totally without a showing of need and necessity. A license placed in escrow
remains available for restoration to the owner for a two-year period. If the licensee has not
restored the license within this two-year period, the license reverts to the City. According to
regulatory personnel, escrow of licenses has mostly occurred at small companies operating 1-2
taxicabs.
Table 2.1 shows significant changes in the taxicab industry and in regulations that have occurred
in Cincinnati since 1986.
InstilUIC for TlIIIIpCldaIion Rosean:h and Educ:alion - May 1998
10
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
Table 2.1: Significant Changes in the Taxicab Industry and Regulations in Cincinnati
I CriterioD 1986 ~ 1994 July, 1997
~ ,
22 (1990)
Taxicab 33 21 (1991) 40 44
Companies 20 (1992,1993) 19 independents 23 independents
8 indeoendents
Taxicab Licenses 348 347 587 (cap lifted) 639
(cap of 348) of which
110 are in escrow
1990-91 Not Avail.
Licensed Taxicab Not Available 1,301 (1992) 1,170 1,007
Drivers 1,174 (1993)
Fares Maximum Fares - Maximum Fares - Maximum Fares - Maximum Fares-
Amount Not Amount Not $2 drop, $0.20 per $2 drop, $0.20 per
Available' Available' 1/6 mile, $12.00 per 1/6 mile. $12.00 per
hour waiL hour wait,
$3 minimum fare. $3 minimum fare.
Inspecton 3 3 until 1992 2 2
2 after 1993
Vehicle Safety - Safety - Safety- Mechanical -
Inspections Semi-Annual Semi-Annual Semi-Annual Annual,
Safety-
Semi-Annual
Liability Not Available $100,000 minimum $100,000 minimum $100,000 minimum
Insurance as of 1lI19188
Required
The number of licensed drivers currently fluctuates between 900-1100 (a 15% reduction from
pre-deregulation levels). Applicants are examined by the director of safety or his designee as to
their knowledge of the provisions of the taxicab ordinance, the geography of Cincinnati, and
local traffic regulations through a written examination.
The 1994 ordinance revisions also established a minimum fare of $3 per trip reportedly due to
the compact size of the City. A maximum fare structure has been in effect during the 1986-1997
period. Current maximum fares are: $2.00 drop charge, $0.20 per 1/6 mile, and $12.00 per hOl11"
waiting time. Fares for trips to locations outside Cincinnati are based on the meter rate plus a
surcharge. The total fare rate charged for mileage outside the City limits must be no more thail
25 cents per mile in excess of the meter rate.
, The taxicab inspector was unable to provide these amounts.
_..'" for T....ponatioo Reoean:h and I!duc:alion . May 1998
11
Review of Tuicab Regulalory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
Approximately 20 years ago there were 5 inspectors who, in addition to taxicabs, held
responsibility for inspecting City buses. There were 3 inspectors as recently as 1988. The 2
current inspectors have responsibility for oversight of all public vehicle licensing-including
limousines, animal-drawn carriages, pedicabs, and handicapped livery vehicles-as well as
inspecting taxicabs.
The 1994 ordinance revisions increased the rigor of taxicab inspections. Prior to 1995, taxicabs
were subjected only to a safety inspection. Under the current ordinance, taxicabs must pass an
annual mechanical inspection by an Automotive Service Excellence (ASE) certified mechanic,
plus semi-annual safety inspections by City inspectors. Taximeters are subject to semi-annual
inspections. The addition of the mechanical inspection requirement is perceived to be an
outcome of Yellow Cab Company operating taxicabs in poor mechanical condition and unable to
pass mandatory vehicle emissions tests during the 1993-1994 period. Failure of these tests
resulted in the federal government levying a large fine against the company and was largely
responsible for the company going into bankruptcy.
Minimum liability insurance on each licensed public vehicle, except handicapped livery vehicles
was increased through the 1994 ordinance to $100,000. Handicapped livery vehicles must be
covered by a $1 million combined single-limit liability policy (death, personal injury and
property damage). There is only one insurance company currently writing coverage for taxicabs
operating within the City.
Other current regulations affecting vehicle licenses include:
> Companies providing radio dispatch must secure a public vehicle dispatching office
license, at an annual fee of $16. Radio dispatch is not required.
> Twenty-four hour service is not required.
> Licensees holding 25 or more taxicab licenses must apply for additional licenses in
blocks of five.
> A reasonable and consistent effort must be made to operate all taxicabs within a given
30-day consecutive period, or the license may be revoked. However, licensees with
10 or more taxicab licenses may keep up to 10 percent of their vehicles out of use.
Licensees with less than 10 taxicab licenses may keep one vehicle out of use.
> Licenses may be transferred between licensed owners for a $10 fee.
2.5 Impacts From the 1994 Regulatory Change
2.5.1 Market Share
Prior to the 1994 relaxation of entry there were 20 companies in operation. Yellow Cab
Company of Greater Cincinnati, held approximately 275 of the 347 licenses issued in 1993. DUe
to the 1994 regulatory changes, other taxicab companies were started and/Qr expanded (Towne
Taxi, Around the Clock Taxi, etc.).
wnw" for TI'lIIISpCXlaIiOllIlaean:llIlld Education. May 1998
12
Review or Taxicab Regulatory Chanps in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. nnd Scanle
There are now 44 taxicab companies legally operating in Cincinnati with the majority of the City
taxicab business held by five companies--Yellow Cab Company of Greater Cincinnati (97
licenses), Skyline Taxi (77 licenses), Towne Taxi (45 licenses), Around the Clock Taxi (48
licenses), and Veterans Taxi (21 licenses). Individual license holders are also affiliated with
each of these companies-Yellow Cab Company of Greater Cincinnati (4 affiliated licenses),
Skyline Taxi (1 affiliated license), Towne Taxi (21 affiliated licenses), Around the Clock Taxi
(21 affiliated licenses), and Veterans Taxi (2 affiliated licenses). Twenty-three of the 44
companies possess one license, and several companies provide service primarily to suburban
areas.
2.5.2 Disparity Between Services Offered By Large and Small Companies
Fleet owners were critical of the disparity between service provided by the larger taxicab
companies and independent owner-drivers. The larger companies provide central dispatching,
24-hour service, and service to all areas within the City. Many independent owner-drivers
primarily serve friends and repeat customers within a limited area and do not operate 24 hours or
7 days throughout the week. Suggestions to improve this situation, which were provided by both
taxicab fleet owners and a regulator, include:
> Requiring provision of central dispatching (through either a company or a dispatching
association);
> Requiring provision of 24-hour service;
> Requiring every company fleet to have a minimum number of taxicabs.as a means of
helping to ensure that service is available to all areas of the City;
> Requiring every company to have an office location; and
)> Requiring drivers to log all drop locations.
The purpose of implementing these suggestions is to create an "even playing field" throughout
. he industry by treating all operators the same while at the same time ensuring customers that all
operators meet at least a minimum level of service.
2.5.3 Service
Taxicab dwners, regulators, and customers stated that there is currently a need for additional
taxicabs in service at night, as shown by the difference between typical wait times during the day
and at night which were cited by company owners and customers. Fleet owners reported that the
average wait time for service during daytime hours is 15-20 minu~. compared to l-l-Y:z hours at
night. The reason given for that difference is that few independent owner-drivers work at night,
and those who do work nights generally provide service only to known customers. It was also
reported that the reason for the lack of, taxicabs on Friday and Saturday nights is that the day
business is lucrative enough that drivers do not need to drive nights. It w.as declared that drivers
who are willing to work nights are particularly difficult to find in Cincinnati. Several customers
stated that the average response time to an address in a public housing project was 45 minutes
during daylight hours, but that taxicab service to that neighborhood is often not available after
5:00 p.m. This lack of service has existed for the past four years (since deregulation).
_bile forTransponad... Resean:blllld Educali.... May 1998
13
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
2.5.4 Driver Shortage
All the taxicab company owners interviewed cited a current shortage of qualified drivers. This is
the result of the relaxing of regulations on entry to the business, which has resulted in a rather
fixed supply of drivers now spread over more cabs. The difficulty of attracting new drivers to
the industry is shown through price competition in the daily lease rate charged to drivers by
companies. There have been periodic price wars among larger companies in an effort to attract
drivers away from other taxicab companies.
Fleet owners stated that current driving record requirements and the prohibition on hiring
individuals with a criminal history are excessively strict and prevent some otherwise qualified
drivers from gaining work, thereby reducing the potential labor pool.
2.5.5 Other Problems Cited
Deregulation has not led to an improvement in vehicle condition. A regulator expressed the
belief that additional enforcement personnel are needed at this time, since the number of
enforcement personnel has remained constant for the past five years despite the increase in the
number of public vehicle licenses issued. Several customers stated that the poor condition of
many vehicles had not improved since the 1994 change in regulation, and service is poor on
weekends and at night, especially in poorer neighborhoods. However, enforcement personnel
believe that taxicabs are in somewhat better condition now than prior to the relaxation of entry,
and credit this improvement to ownership of cars by independent owner-drivers. The taxicab
inspector stated there has been no decrease in the number of complaints since entry was relaxed.
The inspector was unable to provide the number of complaints received before and after
deregulation.
The larger taxicab company ownerS said that the lack of a requirement for 24-hour, 7 days per
week service and central dispatch has created differing expectations for service provided by
independent owner-drivers compared to larger companies. As one large company owner stated,
"Companies need to provide equal service. Now the four large companies provide service at
their expense; other small companies eat the gravy." Providing taxicab service late at night and
early in the morning is not profitable but is generally believed to be critical to the community. A
regulator 'believes 24-hour service should be required as a condition of receiving a taxicab
license. This regulator believes that independent owner-drivers should be accorded an
opportunity to operate their own business, but that the owner-drivers should be held accountable
for providing service 24 hours a day. His suggestion of a means to achieve these goals was that
independent owner-drivers form groups to reach some minimum required size for a company or
association, an approach which Seattle has adopted (Section 4). The association would provide a
means of providing sufficient taxicabs to provide 24-hour, 7-day service throughout the city
while allowing owner-drivers to operate their own businesses.
One practice that existed prior to the relaxation of entry and persists afterward is taxicab driverS
providing service in areas for which they do not hold valid licenses. This problem exists in the
greater Cincinnati area on both sides of the Ohio River in both Ohio and Kentucky. Cincinnati-
licensed taxicabs, with the exception of 31 vehicles permitted to operate from the Greater
-- forTlIIlSpOrlaIion _1IIlI EducaIion. May 1998
14
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
Cincinnati Airport under sublease agreements with Kentucky operators, cannot legally pickup at
the airport, which is located in Kentucky. This situation results in deadheading for all Ohio
operators except these 31 taxicabs. It also prevents a large influx of independent owner-drivers
from obtaining Cincinnati licenses and waiting at the airport with the associated problems of
overcrowding, soliciting, litter, etc.
Institute for Transponation Research and Education - Mar. 1998
15
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
3.0 Indianapolis, Indiana
3.1 Introduction
The metropolitan area of Indianapolis covers 3,532 square miles and had a 1994 population of
1,461,700. The City supports a variety of public transportation alternatives that include fixed-
route bus and specialized transportation. Indianapolis implemented a significant change in its
regulation of taxicabs with 1994 revisions to the City-County ordinance that allowed open entry
into the taxicab business and established a maximum fare structure.
3.2 Historical Changes in Taxicab Regulation - 1970-1993
The unified City/County government was implemented in 1970, creating the Consolidated City
of Indianapolis. Taxicab regulation was placed in the Controller's Office. Until the late 1960s,
there were 423 taxicabs licensed in Indianapolis. Prior to 1970, the City taxicab ordinance had
limited the number of taxicab licenses available by a population ratio of one cab per thousand
population. In 1970, that limit was replaced with a ceiling of 600 taxicab licenses. Both prior to
and following the 1970 change in the maximum number of licenses to be issued, taxicab licenses
were issued based upon a finding of public convenience and necessity. In 1972, 502 taxicab
licenses were issued. Red Cab held the majority-approximately 400-0f these licenses. Four
other companies held approximately 90 licenses, and independent owner-drivers held 10
licenses.
By 1972, Red Cab was experiencing financial and service problems. In 1973, company
employees went on strike against the company, and Red Cab entered bankruptcy and ceased.
operations in August 1973. City offici81s became concerned about the condition of the local taxi
industry as a result of Red Cab's problems. As Red Cab deteriorated, city officials suspected
that many licenses were inactive. To curb this practice and to ensure that only active taxicabs
were licensed, vehicle inspections were required every 30 days, and licenses of vehicles inactive
for over 60 days were revoked.
The taxicab ordinance had stipulated that the City could revoke any permit not in use for over 60
days. This provision was the basis for the revocation and reissuance of permits. The Controller
revoked 255 licenses during 1973.. Taxicab licenses were redistributed at two periods during
1973 through administrative actions of the Controller's Office. The first redistribution took
place in April-May of 1973, when 125 revoked licenses were reissued to new applicants.
Ninety-four additional revoked licenses were reissued in April 1974.
All the available licenses were not requested. During the second period of reissuance in April
1974, a total of 466 licenses were issued, compared to the 502 licenses that had been issued hi
April 1973. There was only one new entrant to the taxicab business through these two periods of
reissuing licenses. The other 33 recipients of taxicab licenses were individuals from within the
taxicab business, many of whom were taxicab drivers. Requirements to provide 24-hour
dispatch and to maintain a downtown office were retained but not enforced. There was no
Inslitutc forT....porlllliOll Rcsean:h and Educ:alion - May 1998
17
Review of Taxicab Regulatol)' Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and SeaRle
requirement for a minimum number of taxicabs.
In 1985, the Controller's Office again made vehicle licenses available, but there were no
applications for licenses. While the City-County ordinance allowed the Controller's Office to
issue a maximum of 600 taxicab licenses, the number of taxicab licenses issued was at the
Controller's discretion. There were 393 licenses issued in 1985. The Controller believed there
was a need for additional licenses at that time; therefore, applications were sought for additional
licenses. No applicants came forward.
In 1993, the year prior to IndianapolislMarion County adopting open entry and maximum fares,
twenty-nine taxicab companies were in operation, and 392 taxicab licenses were issued. This
represents a decrease in both the numbers of taxicab companies and taxicab licenses from 1974,
when thirty-six companies were in operation and 466 taxicab licenses were issued.
3.3 Motivations For the 1994 Regulatory Change
The primary motivation for deregulation of the taxicab industry in Indianapolis came from the
City/County government, particularly Mayor Stephen Goldsmith, who held a philosophical view
that government services should be privatized and/or deregulated in those instances in which
potential economic benefits could be realized. Mayor Stephen Goldsmith formed the Regulatory
Study Commission (RSC) through an executive order in 1991. The purposes of this commission
were to investigate the feasibility of privatizing many publicly provided services and to revise
government regulation of various boards, agencies, and commissions. A total of 61 different
municipal services were privatized or deregulated as a result of RSC studies. Taxicab regulation
was among the flfSt public services to be examined by the commission. The RSC study of
deregulating the taxicab industry focused on opening entry and changing from a City-set fare
structure to a maximum fare structure.. The study also recommended deleting the requirements
for 24-hour service and radio dispatching.
Government officials believed that burdensome regulation should be minimized, allowing
market economics to dictate business success or failure. Mayor Goldsmith stated, ''The taxi
industry is a good example of an area where regulations had completely displaced the economic
principles of demand and competition.,,6 A former member of the RSC stated that the impetus
for investigating deregulation of the taxicab industry were:
>- The ordinance was seen as restrictive to entrepreneurial activity. Taxicab drivers wanted to
be business owners, and government officials believed the ordinance unfairly prevented this
from occurring.
>- Prices were fixed. This was the only instance of a price for a service being fixed at the
municipal level.
Several taxicab drivers had approached government officials requesting the ordinance be
changed to allow entry into the taxicab business with fewer restrictions. The majority of those
drivers were African-Americans. Therefore, opening entry to the taxicab industry offered an
· "Regulation and the Urban Marketplace," Stephen Goldsmith, Cato Institute, January 1997)
InstilUte for Transporl8lion Resean:h and Education - May 1998
18
Review o(Taxicab Regulatory CIwtges in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
opportunity for govemment officials both to advance their economic and entrepreneurial
philosophy and to respond to pressure to increase minority business ownership.
Supporters of taxi deregulation included the Chamber of Commerce, the Indianapolis Urban
League, the Hoosier Minority Chamber of Commerce, the Indianaoolis Recorder, downtown
hotels and banks, and some medical providers to the elderly. Supporters believed that
deregulation would increase the level and quality of taxicab service, reduce fares, and provide
small business start-up opportunities. "Proposal 72 was introduced to improve customer service
and increase economic opportunity in the local ground transportation industry. In some areas of
the city, there is little or no service and the service is not of high quality. This proposal gives
everyone an opportunity to benefit.,,7
The improvements to be realized from implementing City Council Resolution 72, as cited by the
Regulatory Study Commission8, were:
> "Open Market Entry:
The proposal (would) lift the arbitrary cap on the number of allowable taxis.
> Price Competition:
...Operators may charge whatever they want below the existing ceiling, meaning the
proposal will allow prices to fall, but not rise above the maximum ceiling.
> Job Opportunities for Indianapolis Minorities:
Disproportionately, the Indianapolis black community is the demographic segment that
both depends upon taxis the most, and ... can benefit the most from an opening up of that
industry. The people who want and are denied the chance to own their own cabs are
overwhelmingly African-American. It is not inconceivable that adoption of Proposal 72
could lead to 100 new black-owned businesses in the first six months.
> An Improved Local Ground Transportation Infrastructure:
An unreliable and expensive taxi industry hurts retail, restaurant and convention business.
An improved taxi industry will have a positive impact upon the entire community.
> Allowing the Creation of a Local Jitney Industry:
This provision is extremely important to transit dependent people who can not afford the
high price or unreliable service of local taxis. In addition, this provision would not only
increase employment opportunities by enabling more people to get jobs, it would create
jobs and business opportunities in its own industry." .
Proponents of opening entry indicated that applicants for taxicab licenses were prohibited by
existing regulations from starting their own businesses. In August 1992, the City Controller had
attempted to award 39 new taxicab licenses by lottery. That action was blocked by a lawsuit
brought by license holders that contended the controller didn't follow established procedure.
A review of the taxicab ordinance shows that it did not prohibit single-vehicle taxicab companies
or stipulate a minimum number of vehicles for a taxicab company. The issue was really that
7 Tom Rose, Assistant to the Mayor for Regulation Affairs, as quoted in The IndianaDOlis Recorder, Saturday,
March 26, 1994.
· ''City County Council Proposal 72: Improving the Local Ground Transportation Marketplace," Mayor Stephen
Goldsmith's Regulatory Study Commission, March 31,1994.
InstibllC for TlIIIIpOltlIlion Research and Bduc:alion - May 1998
19
Review ofT3Xicab Regultl.lory Ch41nges in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Se:lnle
regulators had not issued additional licenses to applicants. While 392 licenses were issued, the
Controller's Office could have issued up to a maximum of 600 licenses. Licenses were issued
based on a finding of pul;llic convenience and necessity. Regulators did not see a need for
additional licenses based on a finding of public convenience and necessity and maintained the
number of licenses at a constant level.
All fleet operators opposed the proposed deregulation, arguing that consumer price gouging
would result, quality of service would decline, that some taxicab companies would be forced out
of business, and that drivers were being misled to believe that taxi service is easy and
inexpensive to provide.
3.4 Key Provisions of Regulatory Changes -1994
Prior to implementation of Proposal 72 on July 1, 1994, entry to the taxicab industry was
regulated by the need to prove public convenience and necessity, and the City of
IndianapolisIMarion County set fares.
The City/County Council voted to adopt Proposal 72 in May 1994, and revisions to the taxicab
ordinance became effective in July 1994 allowing open entry and changing to a maximum fare
structure. The proposal made these major changes to the taxicab ordinance:
:> Eliminated the cap of 600 taxicab licenses;
:> Replaced a set fare rate with a maximum rate, although all rates must be posted
outside the taxi and with the local government;
:> Eliminated the 24-hour service and central dispatch requirement allowing companies
to operate part-time;
:> Lifted the prohibition against hailing a cab;
:> Added licensing requirements for limousines (previously licensed by the State);
:> Changed inspection of limousines and jitneys-two mandatory annual safety
inspections plus up to three surprise safety inspections where. warranted by citizen
complaints;
:> Increased the permissible operating life of taxicabs from 5 to 6 model years
maximum; limousines and jitneys allowed a ten-year maximum vehicle operating iife;
:> Changed insurance requirements-increased the minimum liability insurance for
taxicabs from $100,000 to $300,000, but reduced the required minimum for
limousines from $1,500,000 to $300,000;
:> Increased the annual license fee to better defray costs of issuing and administering
licenses-for taxicabs and limousines from $102 to $152; for jitneys from $25 - $50
to $152;
:> Set maximum mileage and wait time rates; and
:> Implemented a maximum "pick up" charge similar to a meter drop charge.
The number of taxicab stands in the downtown area was reduced from 35 to 8. It was perceived
that some taxicab stands were taking space that could be better used for parking. A business
organization stated that the need for taxicab.s to wait in line at stands created traffic congestion
Institute for TnnsponaliOll _ and I!dueaIion . May 1998
20
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Owtges in CincinnaIi. Indianapolis. and Seattle
on some downtown streets. and that organization now states that the congestion no longer exists.
It is impossible to state that the elimination of the requirement for taxicabs to pick up customers
only at stands in the downtown area was totally or partially responsible for this change.
It should be noted that while the 1994 ordinance deregulated the taxicab industry. it actually
began the municipal regulation of the limousine industry, requiring licensing of limousine and
jitney operators and requiring inspections of limousines and jitney vehicles as well as taxicabs.
The current ordinance (Chapter 996: Public Vehicles For Hire) applies to taxicabs. limousines.
and jitneys.
Table 3.1: Slgnfficant Changes in the Taxicab Industry and Regulations In Indianapolis
Priorfo;~'14' .' :"Alterl974" Prior;firop., o.
I. ~lll!..<,. €~~'IfTI~; ~~.~... 199fi CurreDt
lIfl'll~' ,;.Clfhl...lIlf, ......
'.
10 36 29 123 106
Taxicab Companies (5 Co.'s, (4 Co.'s, (3 Co.'s, (83% one or (2 major co.' s,
Slndep.) 32Indep.) 26Indep.) two cab 104 sma1l co.'s
ooerations) and indeo.)
502 466 392 460 372
Taxicab Licenses Cap al6OO. Cap al 600. Cap al6OO. No cap. No cap.
(492 major-302 (0 Red Cab. 151 (201 Yellow. (172 Yellow, (173 Yellow.
Red -Cab. 5 I Yellow. 158 66 Indep.. other co.'s and 20 Hoosier.
Yellow, 139 other linns, 157 other co.' s Not independents 1791ndep.)
other firms; JO Indep.) Available) Not Available)
Indeo. )
Licensed Taxicab Not Available Not Available Not Available Not Available Not Available
Drivers" 631(\992)
$0.95 drop, Pick-up charge Pick-up charge
Fares Records Not Records Not $0.30 per liS (amount not (amount not
Available"" Available"" mile, $0.30 per specified), plus specified), plus
minute wait $0.40 per liS $0.40 per liS
after 1"3. mile, $0.40 per mile. $0.40 per
$6.50 min. minute wail, minute wail,
Airport. $5 downtown $5 downtown
flat fare. flat fare.
Inspectors I I I I I
Safety - Safety-3 per Safety-2 per Safety-2 per
Vehicle Inspections Not Available 4 per year; year; Meter- year plus up to year plus up to
meter -monthly 3 per year. 3 unscheduled, 3 unscheduled.
Meter-2-S Meler-2-S
oer year.
Minimum Liability Not Available Not Available $100,000 $300.000 $300.000
Insurance
"Information unavailable on number of licensed drivers due to the method of record keeping. Controller's Office
InIlilute for TaaspcxlIliaa R-..b IIld Educ:aliaa- May 1998
21
Review of Tnxicab Reguhuory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. llfld Sennle
tracks only the number of new and renewal applications processed within a given year, and licenses are valid for a 2-
year period. License period runs from applicant's birthday to birthday. The number of new/renewal driver's license
applications for the past 4 years is: 1993-155, 1994-330, 1995-242, 1996-367, 1997-313. As. of March
1998,648 public vehicle for hire driver's licenses were issued. The 1998 figure includes both taxicab and limousine
drivers.
"Information on fares and minimum liability insurance was unavailable from the Conuoller's Office. An historical
record of this information is not maintained.
The number of taxicab permits increased initially following the 1994 deregulation but has since
decreased to less than the number prior to opening entry. Thirty-two companies started within
the six months following opening entry, and 75 percent of these companies were minority- or
woman-owned. From opening entry in 1994 to 1996, the number of taxicab permits increased
from 392 to 460. City records show that 83 percent of new entrants were small, one-or two-cab
operators.
However, the number of taxicab companies decreased from 123 in 1996 to 106 in 1997. The
number of taxicab permits also decreased, from 460 in 1996.to 372 in 1997. It is difficult to
attribute the relative contributions of several factors to this decrease. Other forms of for-hire
transportation have become available in Indianapolis. For example, jitneys are now permitted to
operate in Indianapolis-Marion County. However, it was reported that no jitneys are operating in
the city. Limousines increasingly compete with taxicabs, particularly in the airport market.
Prior to 1994, there was a cap of 75 limousine licenses; there is no cap on the number of
limousine licenses under current regulations.
While the number of taxicab companies has grown from 29 to 106 under the most recent open
entry, the number of active taxicab licenses has actually decreased from 392 iri 1994 to 372
currently.
The number of licensed taxicab drivers is difficult to calculate due to City/County record-
keeping procedures. City/County Government officials were unable to provide an exact number
of active taxi driver licenses as the Controller's Office tracks only the number of new and
renewal applications processed within a given year. However, officials did state that at the end
of 1992, 631 persons were licensed as taxicab drivers and there are currently 648 taxicab and
limousine driver's licenses.
Complete historical fare information is not available from the Controller's Office. The rates
shown for 1994, prior to enacting open entry, are accurate; however, the taxicab inspector
believes that this rate had been increased just prior to that time. He was unable to conf1l1ll this or
to provide the date of the increase or the previous fare rates.
Regulation of taxicab fares has changed from a government-set uniform fare to a government-set
. maximum fare. Prior to the July I, 1994, regulatory changes, the taxicab ordinance set fares as
follows:
>- 95 cents drop charge (base rate), 30 cents per each 1/5 mile, 30 cents per minute wait
time after the first 3 minutes.
>- $18.00 per hour plus $1.50 per mile in excess of 12 miles in any hour.
>- . $6.50 minimum fare originating from airport.
,
Institule for TllIIISporlIltion _and l!duc:aliCIII' May 1998
22
Review or Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
After July I, 1994, fares were subject to the following maximum amounts:
> 1994: An undefined base rate plus 33 cents per each 115 mile, extra passenger 55 cents,
33 cents per minute wait charge.
> 1995: Base rate plus 36 cents per each 115 mile, extra passenger 60 cents, 35 cents per
minute wait charge.
> 1996 and after: Base rate plus 40 cents per each 115 mile, extra passenger 65 cents, 40
cents per minute wait charge.
One should note that no fixed or maximum charge is specified for the base rate for 1994 through
the present. Each company establishes its base rate. Fares may not be changed more than once
each calendar quarter. Current base rates range from $1.25 to $5.00. The two largest companies,
as well as most independents, charge a $1.25 base rate.
A flat fare of $5 is now an option for travel within the downtown area. Customers may request
that the meter be used instead, which in many cases results in a lesser expense, due to the
compact size of the downtown area.
Historical information on the median base rate is not available; the Controller's Office does not
track median rates or calculate them on an annual basis. This is due to the difficulty of
compiling and computing such statistics due to the frequency of taxicab companies entering and
leaving the market.
The number of taxicab inspectors has remained at 1 since 1994. Both vehicle safety and meter
inspections were required 3 times per year prior to July I, 1994. Vehicle safety inspections are
currently required to be conducted only semi-annually.
The minimum liability insurance requirement prior to July 1, 1994 was $100,000. Effective July
1,1994, the minimum liability requirement was increased to $300,000.
3,5 Impacts of the 1994 Regulatory Change
There are differing opinions on the success of the most recent open entry in Indianapolis. The
three greatest objectives cited by regulators, fleet owners, drivers, and business and hospitality
orgllnh'llion representatives to be realized from deregulation of the taxicab industry were:
> To increase business opportpnities for those desiring to operate their own taxicab
businesses, particularly members of minority populations;
> To improve customer service; and
> To open the for-hire transportation market to a variety of service options.
The first objective initially appeared 10 be partially accomplished, as shown by the increase in
the number of taxicab operators and the initial growth in the number of permits issued through
1nsIi.... for Tnnspoctadaa _1IId 1!d.....0II - May 1998
23
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. :md Seattle
1996. However, the more recent decrease in the number of taxicab permits and taxicab operators
does not support accomplishment of this objective. It should be noted that this objective is not a
transportation objective.
Opinions vary as to the success in accomplishing the second objective. Business and hospitality
organization representatives that supported deregulation believe that (at least initially) overall
customer service had improved, as shown in the following statements.
"Within 6 months of deregulation, the city reported 32 new companies had started, three quarters
of which were owned by minorities or women. Pick up rates were 12% lower for new
companies compared to existing companies. Average mileage rates were 3% lower, and the
average rate for the first mile was 7% lower.,,9
Eight months following deregulation, Indianapolis Downtown, Inc. (100 supported "the
Council's ongoing support of taxi ordinance 76 (sic). Through deregulation, we've recognized
improvements in the following areas:
>- Increased the number of individual taxicab owners/entrepreneurs.
>- Improved visibility of rate by posting on outside of taxi.
>- Improved quality standards. Newly licensed taxis are clean and well-maintained.
>- Improved access to taxis. Customer/visitors can now "hail" a cab.
>- Opened market to more limousine service."
"101 believes a deregulated taxicab industry is essential to its ultimate success as an affordable
and efficient people mover. The positive market forces from deregulation are evident. However,
taxi cabs in Indianapolis have yet to reach their highest potential as an everyday mode of
transportation for our citizens and visitors. to.,
However, 101 also recommended three changes to improve customer service. Those changes
included elimination of the $5.00 "Downtown zone" fare, moving a taxi zone, and incorporating
a "requirement to place a window slick inside the back seat taxi window which says 'Thank you
for visiting Indianapolis...How's my service? 327-5411',11 A spokesperson for Indianapolis
Downtown, Inc., stated that none of these recommendations has been implemented: 101 has not
commented since the number of taxis fell below pre-deregulation levels. but local fleet operators
stated that the reduction in total number of taxis is an objective measure of the decline in
customer service being provided to the citizens and visitors to Indianapolis.
Regulators are unsure if customer service has improved since 1994, as the City/County does not
maintain a historical record of the number of complaints recorded. A regulator stated that the
number of complaints has increased. However, most of these complaints involved customers'
perceptions of having been charged an excessive fare. Checks by the. taxicab inspector have
9 Ordinance 72 Update, Regulated Competition in the Indianapolis Ground Transportation Marketplace, Economic
Development Committee, January 19, 1995.
.0 From a letter written by Helen L. Brown, Director, Management Services. Indianapolis Downtown, Inc. to Dr.
Philip Bont, Councilman-25" District, dated March 21, 1995. .
"Ibid.
InstilU.. for TnnsporlaIion _ ond Education - May t998
24
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. lndianapolis. and SeAtlle
shown that in most instances, fares were charged correctly. With the maximum fare structure,
trip fares can vary depending upon the fare charged by a particular operator. The second most
prevalent type of complaint is that a driver did not know a destination address or took an
excessively long route.
To respond to these complaints, the taxicab inspector modified the driving test in 1997 to
determine better a driver's ability to locate specific addresses. Driver applicants are now asked
to drive to one or more street addresses as opposed to a hotel or attraction. One regulator
believed that there has been no change in service to poor, minority neighborhoods and to
individuals with disabilities. Taxicab company owners stated they did not believe service quality
had improved since open entry was implemented.
In terms of meeting the third objective, opening the for-hire market to additional service options,
there are now fourteen limousine companies in operation. Regulators and airport staff stated
there is increased competition from limousine service at the airport. Paratransit services have
also been deregulated; regulators speculated that unlicensed neighborhood jitneys may offer
increased levels of service in some areas. No jitney companies are or have been licensed by the
city. However, at least one medium-sized taxicab company and numerous independent owner-
drivers have left the taxicab industry in Indianapolis within the past three years.
3.5.1 Market SluJre
There was, and continues to be, extensive competition in the taxicab market The number of
taxicab companies operating in Indianapolis increased threefold following the periods when
permits were redistributed in 1973-74. In April 1972, ten taxicab companies operated in
Indianapolis-nine companies (A Cab, Duncan Cab, J Cab; Lawrence, Cab, Northside Cab, State
Cab, Yell-O-Taxi, Yellow Cab, Yello Taxi) plus one independent dispatchiitg association. In
April 1974, 36 companies were inoperation-4large firms plus 32 independent owner-drivers.
The number of taxicab companies remained relatively stable through June 1994, when 29
companies were in operation. The three largest companies at that time were Yellow Cab (201
licenses), Metro (41 licenses), and Hoosier (50 licenses).
Following adoption of Proposal 72 in July 1994, the number of taxicab operators initially grew to
45 companies. Currently, 106 companies provide taxicab service in IndianapolisIMarion
County. The largest company is Yellow Cab (172 licenses). Other companies include Yell-O-
Cab, Hoosier Cab, Union Cab, Budget Cab, Airline Cab, Reliable Cab, and Al Taxi. There are
now approximately 30 companies that operate only one or two taxicabs.
The number of active licenses now issued (372) is less than the total number of licenses issued in
April 1974 (466). The number of licenses has fluctuated throughout the past 25 years, reflecting
both changing regulations and changing conditions in the private, for-hire transportation
industry. For example, in November 1979, 360 licenses were issued (Yellow Cab-156,
Northside-71, consortium of State Cab/ Metro Cab/Carver Cab/several independents-68,
other independent owners-65). In June 1994, prior to implementation of the revised ordinance,
the number oftaxi licenses was capped at 600 and there were 392 licenses issued (Yellow-201,
=
InsIiIUlO for TnnspcxlIIion _ and EducaDlIIl . May 1998
25
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
Metr0--49, Hoosier-42).
3.5.2 Taxkab Company Business Failures
Some taxicab companies, particularly those with 20-50 licenses and which provided 24-hour, 7-
day, radio dispatch service, were placed in a position in which they did not have sufficient
resources to compete effectively with Yellow Cab and the independents for business. Those
companies were not able to provide service effectively throughout the entire area and at all times
of every day. Medium-sized companies also lack the flexibility and low operating costs enjoyed
by independent owner-drivers. The exit of Northside Cab Company (the third largest fleet) from
the taxicab business was attributed to conditions resulting from provisions of the 1994 ordinance.
Yellow Cab and Hoosier Cab are the only companies now providing radio dispatch and service
to all areas of the City. The owner of another company that has been in business for ten years is
now considering closing that business due to lack of profitability.
Several owners and regulators stated that many taxicab businesses started by individual owner-
drivers have failed within one year of start-up. Some regulators who advocated deregulation
admit that success has not been as positive as had been hoped, citing the many companies
entering and leaving the market. Some of these business failures were attributed to the inability
of some independent owner-drivers to replace their single vehicles when they reached their
maximum age threshold of six model years.
3.5.3 Fares
According to fleet owners, deregulated fares cause confusion with customers. Visitors arriving
at the airport are directed to the first vehicle in the taxicab queue. Visitors may not realize that
fares can differ among taxicab companies.
Several regulators and representatives of the business community believe that the $5 downtown
fare should be abolished in favor of a return to using metered fares. Metered fares are less
expensive than $5 for many trips within the downtown area, and the use of metered fares would
result in cost savings for many customers. Interestingly, Indianapolis Downtown, Inc., which
had advocated implementation of a Downtown Zone in 199412 reversed that position in 1995,
and recommended charging by the meter within the downtown area. 13
An airport representative said that fares have increased since they were deregulated. A study of
fares done two years ago (after deregulation) showed Indianapolis alnong the 15 most expensive
cities in the US for taxicab fares. As a result, airport staff stated they may investigate the
feasibility of requiring lower fares for trips originating at the airport.
An examination of inflation-adjusted fare amounts shows that fares have risen a faster rate than
the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for the 1993-1996 period. The cumulative increase in the CPI
12 From an attachment to a letter from Helen L. Brown, Director. Management Services, to Dr. Philip Borst,
Councilman. dated March 28, t994.
13 Letter from Helen L. Brown, Director, Management Services. to Dr. Philip Borst, Councilman. dated March 21,
1995.
_bite for Transportation Researtb ....1!ducali0ll - May 1998
26
Review ofT:uticab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
was 8.6 percent for the period. Using this multiplier, the 1993 fares of $0.95 base rate, $1.50 per
mile, and $18.00 per hour wait time would increase to $1.03 base, $1.63 per mile and $19.55 per
hour wait in 1996. This is significantly less in all categories than the 1996 actual prices of $1.25
base rate (typical charge used by most operators, although this rate varies from $1.25 to $5.(0),
$2.00 per mile, and $24.00 per hour wait.
3.5.4 Qualified Drivers
Indianapolis, similar to Cincinnati, is enjoying a period of economic growth and low
unemployment. In addition, many drivers for larger companies have started their own taxicab
businesses. Owners of two of the larger companies in Indianapolis cited difficulty in acquiring
sufficient numbers of qualified drivers. There is a relatively fixed pool of taxi drivers that is now
serving a greater number of companies. Regulators acknowledged this problem. In 1994 alone,
40 Yellow Cab drivers started their own businesses. Another company owner mentioned the loss
of approximately one-third of that company's drivers over the past three years, stating many of
those drivers had become independent owner-drivers.
3.5.5 Other Problems Cited
It has been reported in the media that some drivers are unable to communicate effectively in the
English language and are unable to comprehend customer requests.
Regulators and two taxicab company owners believe the lack of requirements for radio dispatch,
24-hour, 7 -day service, and a central office location have resulted in the creation of a two-tier
. system of service. Larger companies provide service to all areas of Marion County .at all times,
and independent owner-drivers provide service at times and to areas at the discretion of
individual drivers. A regulator also stated that the lack of a requirement in the taxicab ordinance
for a central office location has m~e it more difficult for enforcement personnel to contact
taxicab operators.
Finally, company owners believe that the lack of hiring additional enforcement personnel
concomitant with the initial increase in the number of licenses resulted in insufficient
enforcement activity. The Controller's Office is now responsible for administering and
enforcing regulation of limousine and jitney companies in addition to taxicab companies.
Instilllle for Transpotlalion Resean:h and EducatiOll . May 1998
27
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati.lndi;:mapolis, and Seattle
4.0 Seattle, Washington
4.1 Introduction
The City of Seattle covers 84 square miles and had a 1995 population of 532.900. The Seattle
metropolitan area (King, Kitsap, Pierce, and Snohomish Counties) contained 3,020,000 people
within a 6,300 square mile area. The City supports, though a regional transit authority, a variety
of public transportation alternatives that include fixed-route bus, specialized transportation, and
light rail. In 1979, both the City of Seattle and King County opened entry and allowed taxicab
companies to set their own rates. Seattle permanently closed entry in 1991; King County
followed in 1992. In 1996, the City of Seattle revised its ordinance to implement a minimum
standards taxi regulatory approach.
4.2 HIstorical Overview of Taxicab Regulatory Changes -1979-1996
Prior to 1979, King County and Seattle each regulated both taxicab entry and rates. Entry was
restricted according to a population ratio, and the City and County Councils set rates. In 1976,
King County, the City of Seattle, and the Port of Seattle embarked on a program to regionalize
taxicab regulations and licensing. The intent was to standardize fees. and regulations,
enforcement, and rate review procedures while maintaining adequate service levels throughout
the county. For example, the County and the City allowed reciprocal licensing for vehicles and
drivers.
In 1979, the County and the City passed ordinances opening entry and deregulating fares.
Deregulation resulted in problems peculiar to each jurisdiction. For example, the airport had a
surplus of taxicabs and problems with taxi drivers refusing short fares and poor conditions of
taxicabs. The County and the City found that open rate setting resulted in severe abuses as
evidenced by one company filing a $10 drop, $50 per mile charge. Each jurisdiction passed
ordinances or implemented procedures to address these unique concerns. However, the variance
in rates among different taxicab operators created consumer confusion resulting in a consumer
perception of price gouging. It was not unusual for a traveler to pay a different return fare for
transportation between the airport and downtown. Many taxicabs were also perceived to be in
poor condition (Zerbe, 1983; Lewis, 1995; Gelb. 1983a).
In 1984, in response to these problems, the County returned to regulated entry by placing a
moratorium on the issuance of new taxicab licenses and returned to setting taxi rates by
ordinance. The City maintained open entry but limited fares by implementing a taxi rate ceiling.
The County's entry moratorium expired in 1985; returning the County to open entry; however,
fares continued to be set by ordinance. Also, in 1985, the Port placed a moratorium on the
issuance of permits to operate at Sea- Tac Airport. This was because the number of airport
permits had grown to 236, a number that airport staff deemed excessive. .Airport staff stated that
there was confusion among customers from the variance in fares, the poor condition of taxicabs,
and poor customer service that resulted from deregulation. The airport, as a major milrket, had
attracted a great number of taxicabs, creating long waits for drivers between trips. The airport
Inslitute for TroaspodIIIi... _.... Educalion . May 1998
29
Review o( TuicAb Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
implemented the moratorium in response to these conditions as one step in an overall process to
improve airport taxicab service. The Seattle-Tacoma International Taxicab Association (STIT A)
was formed in 1989. The purpose of forming this association was to place all taxicab operations
at the airport under the aegis of a single entity, facilitating administration of ground
transportation services. This association became, and remains, the sole taxicab operator licensed
at the Sea- Tac International Airport.
King County placed a moratorium on the issuance of new taxicab licenses in 1986, when an Ad
Hoc Taxi Committee was formed to study and recommend a method for determining the
optimum number of taxis to operate in the County. The ordinance was revised as a result of the
work of that Committee. First, a moratorium was placed on the issuance of new taxicab licenses.
Second, a process was developed to establish rate and entry recommendations based on objective
data. The County began to gather revenue and expense data on a quarterly basis from each
licensed taxicab owner in July I, 1988. These revenue/expense data were used by the County to
establish an average net profit, which provided regulators with an indication of the industry's
financial health and viability. When these data were contrasted with optimum and actual service
response times, regulators could develop a better-informed view of the taxicab industry.
A Regional Taxicab Commission, which included representatives from King County, the City of
Seattle, and the Port of Seattle, was formed in September 1988. The purpose of this Commission
was to recommend taxicab rates, entry restrictions, and other related revisions to the King
County Code. Recommendations on entry were submitted in February 1990. Those
recommendations included increased standards for licensing and operations of taxicab vehicles
and for-hire drivers. The Commission's term expired on December 31, 1990, before fmal rate
recommendations were submitted. The Executive Staff of the County and the City jointly
drafted an ordinance incorporating many recommendations of the Regional Taxicab Commission
in the fall of 1990.
On January 14, 1991, the City of Seattle adopted Ordinance No. 108357, limiting entry in the
City. The King County Council passed Ordinance No. 9986 on June 10,1992, restricting entry in
the County effective September 6, 1992.
On August 17, 1992, the County Council passed Ordinance 10498. In addition to raising fares
from $1.20 base ratel$1.40 per mile to match the City meter rate of $1.80 base rate/$1.80 per
milel$.50 per minute wait, this ordinance:
> Continued entry restrictions;
> Capped the number of taxicab licenses at 561;
> Changed the quarterly data collection process to an annual filing;
> Eliminated the mandated use of the net profit ratio in rate and entry
recommendations; _
> Enhanced the mechanical certification process, and safety and sanitation requirements
for vehicles;
> Increased the number of mandatory safety inspections; and
> Increased for-hire driver standards for entry.
Institum for TIIllIpOClIlioa IlaOlIn:h IIId 1lducaIi0ll- May 1998
30
Review of Tuicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. lndianllpolis. and SeaRle
The impetus for this change to greater regulation came from the tourism and hospitality
industries. Both the hospitality industry and City regulators stated there was a lack of control
over taxicabs. Fare rates were not standardized and could be set at excessively high levels, some
drivers lacked English language skills, some drivers lacked sufficient geographic knowledge to
drive customers to requested destinations, and some drivers refused short trips.
In August 1995, King County and the City of Seattle entered into an interiocal services
agreement. This granted authority for the County to issue City of Seattle for-hire driver's
licenses as an agent for the City, and for the City to issue County taxicab vehicle licenses as an
agent for the County. In addition, the agreement granted authority for County licensing
inspectors to enforce the City taxi code as agents for the City and for City licensing inspectors to
enforce the County taxi code as agents for the County. This specialization allows licensees to
apply to only one agency to obtain both licenses.
4.3 MotivatioDS Leading to Additional Regulation in 1996
By the mid 1990s, several downtown businesses, such as the Westin Hotel and Clipper
Navigation, and organizations representing business and tourism interests requested increased
regulation of taxicabs. Spokesmen for the business and tourism industries indicated that many
taxicabs were in poor condition, some drivers lacked geographic knowledge of the City, some
passengers with short trips were refused service, and some foreign guests were not transported
via the shortest possible routes. Passengers complained that fares were inconsistent. Le.. one fare
was charged from the airport to a given hotel and another fare was charged on the return trip to
the airport. In addition, some drivers were reported to lack English language. skills. The mayor.
and several council members were supportive of a more cooperative and coordinated regulatory
effort between the County and the City. Some members of the taxicab industry also believed
additional regulation would be beneficial to the industry.
These problems were determined by the City to be artifacts of the 1979 open entry, after which
many independent owner-drivers entered the Seattle taxi market. Despite the various steps taken
by the city, county, and airport to re-impose entry restrictions, there were in 1995 approximately
210 independents and 7 companies operating in Seattle. Most of these operators had no place of
business and could not easily be located by the one on-street taxi inspector. Recognizing the
magnitude of the service and enforcement problem it faced, the city brought in a peer review
team of current and former taxi regulators from other cities. This team issued a report that called
for increased self-enforcement by the industry (Avants et al., 1995). The ordinance enacted by
the city in 1996 implements the recommendations of the peer review team.
4.4 Key ProvisloDS of the 1996 Regulatory Changes
In fall 1996, the City of Seattle changed its taxicab regulations effective January I, 1997. The
City ordinance contains some new requirements that move the city significantly toward tighter
control over service quality and greater industry self-enforcement. Most significantly, taxicab
license holders are now required to belong to associations, associations are required to meet
1Dsli1ll1lO farTnlIIpCldOIion _.... _.... Mal 1998
31
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
service standards such as providing dispatching, providing twenty-four-hour service, having at
least 15 cabs, and using the same color scheme, trade name, and dispatch services. Radio
dispatch is required for all taxicabs operating in the city. This requirement can be met by use of
a mobile radio telephone service until December 31, 1999. After that date, the requirement can
only be met by using two-way radio communication. Each association is also held responsible
for the services of its affiliated cabs through a point system for rule infractions.
It should be noted that this new ordinance does not restrict entry. Each association may grow
without limit, so new operators can always enter the market. Likewise, there in no limitation on
the number of associations, so new associations can be created at any time. Taxicab associations
must:
>- Maintain a business office which is staffed between 9 am to 5 pm;
>- Ensure that each affiliated taxicab is insured as required;
>- Accept on behalf of any owner or driver of an affiliated taxicab all correspondence
from the Director of the Department of Finance (taxi regulator) to that owner or
driver;
>- Collect and provide information on operations and customer complaints; and
>- Pay all penalties that are assessed against the association, affiliated taxicab licensees,
or affiliated drivers.
Associations may be comprised of one or more companies and/or "independent taxicabs". An
"independent taxicab" is defmed as "a taxicab that, prior to October I, 1996, shared a central
dispatch service with 9 or fewer other taxicabs. Independent associations now include Emerald
City Taxi, Northwest Taxi, and Royal Taxi.
The City also required all drivers to retake the written examination and demonstrate English
language proficiency to renew their license. These changes affect approximately 50 percent of
County licensees who hold City licenses as well as County licenses.
Refer to Table 4.1 for a summary of changes from 1979 to the present.
IasdIUIO fllr TIIIIIpClIlIlion __ ~OII . May 1998
32
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
Table 4.1: Significant Changes in Taxicab Industry and Regulations
During Period Prior to
Criterion Prior to Open or Open Entry Limiting Entry Current
Entry In 1979 (1979.1984\" In 1"1
Taxicab Companies or 7 Companies,
Associations 57 -80-85 210 10 Associations
indeoendents
421 City -520 City City Not 645 City,
Taxicab Licenses 402 County 426-648 County Available, -850 County
561 in County (includes Co. only and
combined Co.ICity
166 Airoort
1,865 Total
446 Co. only
Licensed Taxicab Drivers Not Available Not Available 1329 Total 818 Co. wi
City Endorse.
601 City only
(Drivers may affiliate
w/up to 3 assoc.)
County: SO.9O County: $1.00 County: $ 1.20 CitylCounty:
drop, SO.70 per drop, $1.20 per drop, $1.40 per $1.80 drop, $1.80 per
Fares mile, SO.12 mile, SO.30 wait mile, SO.35 wait mile, SO.5O wait per
wait per per minute, per minute, minute, $0.50 extras
minute. SO.50 elttras. SO.50 elttras over 2.
over 2.
Inspectors Not Available Not Available 1 City 1.5 City
1 CounlY 1 CounlY
Safety: 2 per Mechanical: Annual, by
Vehicle Inspections Not Available Not Available year; ASE certified mechanic;
Meter: once per Safety: up to 3 per year;
year. Meter: once Del Year.
Minimum Liability Not Available Not Available Not Available City: $50,OOOIaccident;
Insurance Required $25,OOOIperson; $50,000
There was one taxicab association in operation prior to implementation of the revised Seattle and
King County ordinances in .1991. The Seattle Tacoma International Taxicab Association
(STIr A) served as a model for the taxicab associations now required in the City of Seattle. The
City has changed from regulating 106 companies and independent owner-drivers prior to January
I, 1997 to ten associations to enhance control and service. .
The number of vehicle licenses increased throughout the period from 1979 to the present. Exact
numbers of vehicles licensed in each jurisdiction are not available fQr all periods. Also, some
vehicles are licensed for operation. only in King County. Other vehicles are licensed for
operation only in the City of Seattle. Some vehicles carry joint licenses. In addition, vehiCles
licensed to operate at Sea-Tac International Airport may be licensed to operate in either or both
of the other two governmental jurisdictions. Compounding this confusion, under the interiocal
service agreement of August 1995, King County now performs all driver licensing, and the City
of Seattle now performs all vehicle inspections for both jurisdictions. There are currently 645
Inslitu.. forTtIIIIpClIlIlionRae....llnd l!ducaIion. May 1998
33
Review of Taxicab ReguLatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seanle
City-only licenses, approximately 850 County-only and combined City/County licenses. Of the
166 Airport licenses currently issued, 13 have City endorsements; the remainder have County
endorsements.
The same inter-jurisdictional conditions apply to driver licensing. There are a total of 1,865
taxicab drivers now licensed. Of that total, 446 have County only licenses, 601 have City-only
licenses, and 818 have County licenses with a City endorsement.
Uniform fares now apply to both King County and the City of Seattle. Both the City and the
County deregulated fares in 1979, allowing taxicab drivers to set their own rates. In 1984, the
County returned to established fare rates, and the City created a rate ceiling. The City adopted
its ceiling rate as the established fare rate through the 1991 ordinance. In 1992, the City and
County fares became identical. Note that this uniform rate is a result of circumstance, not a
requirement of current regulations. City and County officials expressed the belief that a common
fare rate is likely to become adopted as part of both ordinances in the near future as part of
continuing efforts to coordinate taxicab regulation in the area.
Both the City of Seattle and King County have typically employed 1-2 taxicab inspectors during
the past 20 years~ There are currently one County Inspector and 1.3 City Inspectors, with plans
to hire another City inspector at 50% time.
A semi-annual safety vehicle inspection was required for both City- and County-licensed
vehicles until 1995. At that time, an annual safety inspection performed by an ASE-certified
mechanic became an additional requirement. Up to 3 safety inspections may be performed on
vehicles in one year, based upon violations cited at the initial inspection. Taximeters are
inspected annually. The City under the auspices of the 1995 interlocal service agreement now
- performs all vehicle inspections for both the City and the County. -
Current requirements for vehicle insurance coverage are a minimum of $50,000 per accident,
$25,000 per person, $50,000 property damage. These requirements have not changed for several
years. Certificates of Insurance must now include coverage for underinsured motorists ($25,000
per person, $50,000 per accident).
-4.5 Impacts of the 1991.1996 Regulatory Changes
4.5.1 Taxicab Associations
City regulations effective January I, 1997 required all City-licensed taxicabs to belong to a
taxicab association as of May I, 1997, effectively ending autonomous operation by independent
owner-drivers. Independent owner-drivers may still own and/or operate tlllticabs in Seattle but
must be members of an association. A "Taxicab Association" is defmed as "a person or
organization licensed. ..that represents or owns at least 15 taxicabs licensed by the City that use
the same color scheme, trade name, and dispatch services. An individual person may be a
taxicab association as long as that individual owns or represents at least 15 taxicabs and
Institute for T.......- R-..b IIld 1!dw:ali0ll - May 1998
_~- 34
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Ctumges in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. 3nd Se:lttle
otherwise meets the requirements of (the City taxicab ordinance),,14.
Taxicab associations provide a mechanism for increased supervision of drivers, for making
taxicab service more customer-focused, and for enabling taxi operators to grow according to how
well they serve the public. They also bear some responsibility for the conduct and performance
of their member taxicabs. Taxicab associations are assessed penalty points for specific violations
of the ordinance, vehicle, and safety standards. Violations are classified according to three levels
of severity. Class A violations are the least severe, and involve violations of vehicle standards.
such as failure to carry a map of Seattle and the region published within the last two years, or
operating requirements. such as failure to maintain a business telephone in working order during
all hours of operation.
Class B violations are moderate in severity, and involve infractions of vehicle safety standards,
and lack of adherence to procedural requirements for associations. Class C violations are the
most severe, and include operating without a valid vehicle insurance policy or valid licenses IS.
Monetary penalties are assessed against a for-hire driver or the owner of a taxicab or for-hire
vehicle for each Class A, B, and C violation found away from the City's inspection facility.
These monetary penalties range from $30 for the first Class A violation in a year to $1,000 for all
Class C violations. A vehicle re-inspection fee is assessed against a for-hire driver or the owner
of a taxicab or for-hire vehicle for each Class A, B, and C violation found at the City's inspection
facility. Penalty points are assessed against the driver or vehicle owner's taxicab association for
all violations. Penalty points range from 2 points for the first Class A violation against an
affiliated driver or vehicle owner in one year, to 20 points for all Class C violations by an
affiliated driver or owner.
In addition to accumulating penalty points for violations attributed to aff1liated drivers and
owners, associations may also be assessed penalty points for violations attributable to association
actions. If an association accumulates more than 5 penalty points per affiliated vehicle, on
average, it must pay a penalty of $100 per affiliated taxicab. An accumulation of more than 7
points per affiliated vehicle, on average, results in an additional penalty of $150 per affiliated
taxicab. An accumulation of more than 10 points per afflliated vehicle, on average, results in an
additional penalty of $250 per affiliated taxicab. Penalty points are accumulated on an annual
basis, according to a September 1 through August 31 schedule.
4.5.2 Market Sluue
There are now a total of ten taxicab associations operating in the City of Seattle. In addition to
STITA (166 licenses), associations now include: Emerald City Taxi (20 licenses), Farwest Taxi
(117 licenses), Graytop Cabs (123 licenses), North End Taxi (24 licenses), Northwest Taxi (20
licenses), Orange Cab (99 licenses), Redtop Taxi (15 licenses), Royal Taxi (38 licenses), and
Yellow Cab (176 licenses).
" Seattle Municipal Code. Chapter 6.31 O.IIOV, October 21, 1996.
" Refer to Seattle Municipal Code. Sections 6.310.320 and 6.310.330 for complete details of violations and their
classification.
JnstiIUIll for TrlInsporllIlio -.. and Education - May 1998
35
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
There has always been a lot of competition in the Seattle taxi industry. There were 57 companies
operating prior to implementation of open entry in 1979. During the period of open entry in both
the City and County from 1979-1984, approximately 80-85 companies were in operation at any
given time. Just prior to the recent regulatory change in 1996, there were 7 companies plus 210
independent owner-drivers in the city.
4.5.3 Vehicle Age Limit
An eight-year maximum vehicle age requirement is being phased in over a three-year period
from 1997-1999. The current maximum allowable vehicle age of nine years applies through
August 31, 1998. As of September 1, 1999, no vehicles greater than eight model years in age
will be allowed as taxicabs in the City of Seattle. This vehicle age limit does not apply to King
County taxicabs. .
4.5.4 Customer Complaints
Under the new ordinance, passenger complaints involving a City-licensed taxicab are forwarded
to the appropriate driver, vehicle owner, and association for resolution. Written responses from
all these parties are required within 10 days of receipt of the complaint. If a response is not
received, the allegation is deemed to be true, and the City may then take disciplinary action.
King County specifies an identical process with the exception of the involvement of the taxicab
association, as membership in an association is not required for County-licensed vehicles.
The number of complaints of poor service from downtown hotels and the Port has decreased
since additional regulatory requirements were imposed in 1996. The Westin Hotel no longer
requires a special decal in order for a taxicab to provide service on its property. A representative
from Clipper Navigation stated that his company has heard fewer complaints about poor taxicab
service since association membership became required for taxicab operators. City staff have not
noticed a significant reduction in the number of formal complaints received direcUy from
dissatisfied customers. There are no records of the numbers of complaints received.
4.5.5 Driver Training/Examination
All applicants for a taxicab driver's license in SeattlelKing County must attend a 2-day training
course provided through the City of Seattle and taught by industry members. In 1995, the City
began offering a 8 hour class (now expanded to 16 hours) that covers defensive driving, personal
safety, geography, city/county rules and regulations, customer service. Applicants must also
complete a one-week training course provided through their respective associations. This course
includes two days of on-the-road experience with a licensed driver from that association.
All drivers' license applicants must pass a written test on City/County rules and regulations and
local geography plus an oral English language examination developed in cooperation with
educators from the local community college.
InstilUle for T....podaliOll R_ and l!ducaliOll - May 1998
36
Review of Tuxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. lndillrUlpOlis. and Seattle
4.5.6 Other Problems Cited
All those who were interviewed expressed overall satisfaction with the state of taxicab regulation
and the level of service provided. All parties (regulators. taxicab industry members. and tourism
industry and business community representatives) interviewed perceived the current regulations
to be an improvement over open entry and fare deregulation. The only negative comment was
that some members of the taxicab industry believed that enforcement of some provisions of the
ordinance is too strict. For example, all drivers are required to take the English language test and
pay the associated fee. Regulators stated that the number of customer complaints might rise in
the short term, due to the requirement that all taxicabs post consumer information boards listing
the Taxicab Hotline phone number for complaints. However, regulators expect the number of
complaints to decrease in the long term, as associations become more involved in providing
more responsive customer service.
Inslilllle lor Transporlllion _II1II Education. May 1998
37
Review or Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. lndi3tlapOlis. omd Sunle
5.0 Discussion: Cross-City Comparisons
5.1 Introduction
Three questions form the basis for this study:
1. What were the taxi regulatory changes that occurred in each city?
2. What were the motivations for these changes?
3. What have been the impacts of these changes?
Based on the fmdings in the previous three sections we can now discuss how the answers to
these questions vary among these three cities. Later, in Section 6, we draw conclusions about
taxi regulatory changes in these three cities.
5.2 What Taxi Regulatory Changes Occurred?
The regulatory changes made by Indianapolis and Cincinnati are similar to each other and to the
regulatory changes enacted in 1979 in Seattle. However, these changes are nearly opposite to
those recently made in Seattle.
Indianapolis adopted ooen entrY. deleted its requirements for twenty-four-hour service, removed
its requirement for radio dispatching, removed its prohibition on hailing taxis, increased the
maximum age of taxicabs from five to six years, and established maximum fare rates. Cincinnati
adopted ODen entrY through an extremely lenient public convenience and necessity regulation in
which any applicant can obtain a taxi license just by stating where the applicant intends to
provide service. The Cincinnati system explicitly prohibits the city from considering any
impacts on existing operators in granting new licenses. In addition, Cincinnati removed its cap
on the number of licenses and eliminated its requirement for twenty-four-hour service while
imposing a minimum ($3) fare on trips.
Seattle, on the other hand, continued to move away from its earlier open entry experiment and
increased rel!ulation by requiring all cabs to be affiliated with an association, by requiring a
minimum of fifteen cabs per association, and by requiring twenty-four-hour service and radio
dispatching. The requirement for radio dispatch can be met by use of a mobile radio telephone
service until December 31, 1999. After that date, the requirement can only be met by two-way
radio communication, to ensure use of central dispatch through each association.
Cincinnati and Indianapolis are clearly similar in their taxicab regulatory changes. Both effected
open entry, although Cincinnati did so by retaining its public convenience and necessity clause
but making it extremely easy to meet this standard. Both cities also reduced service
requirements for taxicab operators by deleting their requirements for twenty-four-hour service,
for dispatching, for a place of business, and for all-city service. Curiously; however, Cincinnati
also moved toward increased regulation by establishing a minimum fare for taxi trips.
Indianapolis relaxed its maximum vehicle age requirement from five to six years.
Josan"" for Transportalion Research IIld I!ducalion - May 1998
39
Review ofTlUi~b Regulatory Changes in CincinRllb. Indi:lfUlpolis.and Seattle
Seattle provides an interesting counterpoint as well as an indication of what can be expected to
occur in Indianapolis and Cincinnati. Seattle in 1979 implemented deregulation not dissimilar to
the changes recently enacted in Cincinnati and Indianapolis. The recent changes in Seattle's taxi
regulations can be seen as a 'continuing move toward re-regulation in response to service and
enforcement problems emanating from the earlier deregulation experience. Given the pattern
that Price Waterhouse (1993), Teal (1987), and others have noted in deregulation experiences,
one can expect that both Indianapolis and Cincinnati will experience service problems that will
lead them to re-regulate their taxis.
5.3 What Were the Motivations for These Changes?
The motivations leading to the taxicab regulatory changes in these three cities differ
considerably.
In Seattle the impetus for the 1996 changes stemmed directly from concern among the business
and tourism communities that taxi services were of poor quality and were an important
detrimental faCtor in the attractiveness of Seattle as a tourism and business destination. These
groups believed that the taxi industry should either be more strongly controlled by the city or else
more self-regulated, hence the requirements for affiliation with associations, for twenty-four-
hour service, and for a point system for rule infractions.
While these industry concerns led directly to the City's increased taxi regulation, these concerns
were but a step in the continuing process of remedying the impacts of the earlier experiment with
deregulation in Seattle. As noted in Section 4, the city, county, and airport each took significant
re-regulatory actions during the prior ten years, all designed to reverse the effects of open entry.
In 1995, the City invited a peer review team of taxi regulators to review its taxi regulatory
situation (Avants et aI., 1995). The peer review team pointed out the difficulty in enforcing any
meaningful service standards with a small enforcement staff and an atomized taxi industry of 217
operators. It was the recommendations of this peer review team that were legislated into law by
the City in 1996.
Cincinnati also reacted to problems within the taxi industry and dissatisfaction with the quality of
taxi service. Unhappy with earlier confrontations with elements of the taxi industry over
requests for new permits and tired of problems within .the industry, the City reacted much as did
Seattle did in 1979 when it, too,deregulated its taxi industry. Cincinnati might be described as
reacting to problems rather than adopting a philosophy of government action.
This was not so in Indianapolis. Indianapolis adopted taxi deregulation as part of a philosophical
approach to government action. Inspired by a mayor who advocated less government
involvement in private enterprise, the City formed a commission to examine ways to reduce
government regulations of all types. It elected to implement taxi deregulation despite its earlier
negative experience with a limited form of deregulation in 1973 and 1974. .
Indianapolis also differs from the other two cities in that its motivations expanded beyond
transportation objectives. Sometime during the consideration of its new taxi regulations the City
Insu..te (or T....podlIlion Research llIld Education. May 1998
40
Review of TaxiCAb Regulalmy Changes in Cincinnati. lndianapolis. and Seattle
adopted an objective of increasing the number of new job opportunities in the taxi industry,
especially for minorities. Thus, in Indianapolis the deregulation initiative also became a social
and jobs initiative, another fact that resembles the deregulation action of Seattle in 1979. It
should be noted that the experience of Seattle and other deregulated cities has been that attempts
to make the taxi industry a vehicle for social change have worked at cross purposes with
passenger service quality objectives, e.g., higher fares, poor quality vehicles, short trip refusals,
fewer centrally dispatched vehicles, etc. (Price Waterhouse, 1993).
5.4 What Have Been the Impacts of These Changes?
5.4.1 Level of Competition
Even prior to the regulatory changes in these three cities there was extensive competition within
the three taxi industries. In Seattle there were more than 220 operators, of which 210 were
independent owner-drivers. In Cincinnati there were more than twenty operators before open
entry, and in Indianapolis 29 operators. This level of competition is just within the taxi industry
in each city and does not include the competition between taxi operators and shuttles, vans,
limousines, buses, and cars. Thus, regulatory changes were not needed in order to provide
competition for taxi operators in these three cities.
In fact, in Seattle the intended impact of recent regulatory changes was to decrease governmental
involvement in regulation of the taxicab industry while providing more control over operators
and preserving competition. The 210.owner-drivers were required to join associations, and the
result has been a much-reduced number of taxi providers: 10 assoc::iations.
In Indianapolis there has an increase in the number of operators. Currently, about 104
independent owner-drivers and two companies compete for passengers. This large number of
owner-drivers is also similar to what occurred in Seattle after its 1979 open entry and what has
been reported by Price Waterhouse to occur in other open entry cities.
In Cincinnati there has also been an increase in the number of operators: from about twenty to
forty-four. Here, too, the pattern exists of more independent owner-drivers (15) after
deregulation. However, the growth of independent owner-drivers in Cincinnati has been
dampened by the fact that the airport is located in Kentucky and has not been deregulated. Thus,
unlike other deregulated cities where independent owner-drivers have become overcrowded at
airports, such is not possible at the Cincinnati airport.
5.4.2 Size of Industry
One of the expectations of advocates of open entry is that new taxi operators will enter the
industry after open entry. This hope was particularly evident in Indianapolis, which established
as one of its objectives that minorities would enter the industry as taxi operators.
In Indianapolis there has been a decrease in the total number of taxi permits after the most recent
Insd_ for Transporlllioa _1IId Bducalioo - May 1998
41
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. IndianapoUs. and Seattle
open entry (392 to 372). A similar decreased occurred in 1973-74 (502 to 466). One possible
reason for this decline is the emergence of new competitors to taxi service, such as airport
shuttles and executive sedans. Another factor may be that--contrary to the assertions of open
entry advocates--there was no pent-up demand for taxi permits before open entry. This
explanation is bolstered by the fact that the Controller's Office had not issued all the available
taxi permits prior to the 1994 deregulation. One older taxi company has failed and left the
industry after open entry.
In Cincinnati there has been a substantial increase in the total number of permits after open entry
(347 to 499). Currently there are an additional 117 that have been suspended by the City for
non-use.
No recent evidence exists regarding whether people from outside the taxi industry have entered
the industry after open entry. However, for the 1973-4 open entry in Indianapolis only one
person from outside the industry applied for a taxi permit; the other new permit holders were
former drivers or owners (Gelb, 1983b). Anecdotal evidence from interviews indicates that few
new operators from outside the taxi industry have entered the industry since open entry in either
Indianapolis or Cincinnati.
5.4.3 Industry Structure
The local taxicab industries have become more disaggregated in both Cincinnati and Indianapolis
and more concentrated in Seattle. Indianapolis now has 179 independent owner-drivers,
Cincinnati has 44, and Seattle none.
5.4.4 Service Requirements
Both Cincinnati and Indianapolis have relaxed their service requirements by deleting their
requirements for twenty-four-hour service, places of business, and radio dispatching. Seattle
implemented a maximum age (8 years), dispatching, and twenty-four-hour service requirements.
5.4.5 Enforcement
Enforcement is critical to the effectiveness of taxi regulations. On-street enforcement agents
handle many enforcement matters, such as vehicle inspections, responding to complaints or
emergencies, tracing lost articles in cabs, and checking equipment and insurance. The
enforcement burden is greatly increased with more taxicabs, more taxi operators, and more
independent owner-drivers without business locations.
These three cities are evidence of the reluctance of city governments to spend much money
hiring taxi inspectors. Cincinnati has decreased the number of its taxi inspectors from 3 to 2
during the implementation of open entry. Indianapolis has maintained just one inspector, as has
Seattle, although Seattle has recently added a half-time inspector. Thus, while the need for
Insti.... for TfIIIIJlOIlIlIoI_'" Education. May 1998
42
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinn:aD.. Indianapolis. and Seanle
enforcement has increased, the amount of enforcement personnel has decreased.
The low-level of on-street enforcement raises serious questions about the efficacy of the
regulations. Simply put, the enforcement requirements increase with the number of operators
and with operators who do not have fixed places of business. In such situations taxi inspectors
have great difficulty in simply locating taxi operators, and routine enforcement matters, such as
articles left in cabs, become very difficult to adjudicate.
Seattle, recognizing that enforcement is critical but that it was not able to hire enough inspectors
to deal with its taxi service problems, opted to increase the level of self-enforcement in its taxi
industry. Thus, it adopted the requirement that all taxis belong to associations and that
associations exercise responsibility for their member taxis.
5.4.6 Fares
Table 5.1 shows the current fares in Cincinnati, Indianapolis, and Seattle. It should be noted that
distance and wait time rates shown for Cincinnati and Indianapolis are maximum allowable rates,
and that actual rates may vary by taxicab company.
Table 5.1: Fare Rates
.-.1)'pe~.-;..
.~.
.>.,
Drop Charge
$2.00 (maximum)
''Pick-Up Charge"
allowed but amount not
specified (typically
$1.15-$5.00 .
$1.80
Distance Charge
$0.20 per 1/9 mile
Wait Time
$0.50 per minute
Minimum Fare
$3.00
$5.00 .
Other
Surcharge not to exceed Extra passenger: $0.65
15 cents per mile for maximum
trips to other
cities/areas.
$8.00 (maximum) $10.00 plus Pick-Up
e.
Extras: $0.50 each
passenger over 2.
$9.00
WtItulC for TIOIIIpOIlIIion _1IIId I!ducalion -May 1998
43
Review of Taxicllb Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and S~nle
It should also be noted that Cincinnati is unique among these three cities in having a minimum
fare ($3) per trip.
5.4.7 Age of Vehicles
Two of the three cities have a maximum age requirement for taxicabs:
Cincinnati:
Indianapolis/Marion County:
Seattle (City):
No maximum age
6 years
8 years (by August 31. 1999; 9 years through
August 31, 1998; King County does not have a
maximum age requirement)
It should be noted that in Seattle the local airport authority implemented a seven-year vehicle age
limit in 1989. Not only did this requirement predate the adoption of a maximum vehicle age by
the City of Seattle, but also it is more stringent than the City's regulation.
5.4.8 Customer Satisfaction
When gathering information for this report there was a great deal of discussion regarding
customer satisfaction-what is the quality of service as perceived by those using, regulating, and
providing taxicab transportation. In most instances throughout the country customer satisfaction
is largely a subjective matter, supported only by the number of complaints received by
regulators. The number of complaints is tracked for a period of several years, and trends of
increasing or decreasing numbers of complaints are noted.
Instead of this passive approach King County instituted a system of tracking response times for
taxicabs at selected points within the County. A schedule of optimum average response times
was established, and actual response times are calculated annually from reviews of dispatch and
trip sheet records maintained by taxicab companies. Actual response times are compared to
optimum average times to determine the performance of the industry in meeting customer
requests 'for service. Information on response times for the past ten years demonstrates
consistent performance within the established standards.
In addition to tracking pickup times the City and County have. each established a definitive
process for handling both telephone and written complaints. Complaints from customers using
City-licensed taxicabs and received on the Taxi Hotline (296- T AXl) are referred to the
appropriate taxicab association for resolution. Audits include a review of association complaint
logs to verify satisfactory resolution of complaints.
In addition to gathering information on service response time questionnaires distributed to King
County taxicab patrons gather information on driver conduct/appearance and taxicab condition.
Summary information from those questionnaires is presented in Table 5.2.
Institute for Transpor1llliOll Reseaaob ond EduaIlion - May 1998
44
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Scanlc
Table 5.2: Results of King County Surveys
~~ 1990 1991 r tm 1993 1994 1995 1996
.....
Well Maintained 70% 48% 59% 72% 69% 58% 74%
Dinv. but tmadrenair 22% 32% 29% 14% 26% 32% 18%
Dirtv. DOOr condition 8% 20% 12% 7% 5% 10% 7%
Driver CGaduetl
A-_
Excellent 71% 28% 42% 55% 35% 32% 55%
AcceDtab1e 17% 59% 43% 39% 52% 47% 34%
Not Accenrable 2% 14% 15% 4% 13% 15% 9%
Average Wait Time 13 16 11 10 13 10 8
(Minutes)
Wait Time Satisfactorv 85% 69% 85% 81% 89% 84% 95%
Cincinnati does not require a taxicab company to implement or follow specific customer service
procedures. The taxicab ordinance only stipulates procedures and penalties for taxicab drivers
and owners who violate provisions of the ordinance. There is no formal city-wide passenger
complaint process nor formal procedure for handling customer complaints.
Section 996-133 of the Indianapolis taxicab ordinance stipulates that anyone knowing of .the
misconduct of a liCensee may present a complaint to any police officer of the City or to the
controller. The controller is to investigate the complaint with the assistance of the Indianapolis
Police Department or the Marion County Sheriff, if necessary. The controller then notifies the
licensee in writing that charges have been f1led against himlher and of the time of a hearing on
those changes. .
5.4.9 Driver Training and Exami1uztions
Cincinnati requires that all applicants for a public vehicle license show evidence of at least six
months' experience in operating a motor vehicle or successful completion of a course in the
operation of a motor vehicle given by a approved school. or both. Applicants are required to
complete successfully written tests of knowledge of both the taxicab ordinance and City
geography. Applicants must cOrrectly answer at least 15 of 20 written questions and correctly
match the locations of at least 30 of 35 local businesses/attractions. While the ordinance states
that the application is to set forth that the applicant is able to speak, read and write the English
language, there is no such statement on the application form.
Applicants for a taxicab driver' s licens~ in Indianapolis must pass a written examination and a
practical test. Areas in which applicants are questioned include:
1. The applicant's qualifications;
2. The applicant's knowledge of the provisions of the ordinance and other relevant
statutes, ordinances, and regulations;
3. The applicant's knowledge of the geography of Marion County and the surrounding
counties;
lutilula fw TlOIlSpOrlation Reseon:b aad Educalion . May 1998
45
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
4. The applicant's ability to communicate in English with customers; and
5. The applicant's skills in operating a motor vehicle, which may include a driving test.
A driving test has been developed and implemented to ensure that applicants can demonstrate
practical use of their knowledge. According to the Taxicab Inspector, use of this test has reduced
the number of complaints about drivers' lack of geographic knowledge and/or use of a longer
route than necessary to reach a destination.
King County has tested for-hire drivers as a prerequIsite for licensure since 1985. The
examination is comprised of two parts~rdinance knowledge and geography knowledge. The
examination tests an applicant's knowledge of regulations governing fare determination, driver-
passenger relations, conduct, ability to understand oral and written directions in the English
language, vehicle safety, and the geography of King County and the surrounding area. Of those
who have taken the examination from 1985 through 1996, 4,901 passed, and 1,479 failed.
Applicants for a County-only license may take the test as often as the test is given during their
6O-day pending period. Applicants for a City of Seattle license may take the test two times. If
they fail both attempts, they must wait 60 days before they can reapply and take the test again.
Applicants do not receive a temporary license until they have passed the written examination.
""
5.4.10 Fees.
Each of the three cities charges fees for license application and renewal for both taxicab and
driver licenses. Each city also charges one or more other fees, linked to the regulatory structure
in place (Table 5.3). .
Institute for TransporIation _.... EducaIi<m - May 1998
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Ch:utges in Cincinrwi. Indianapolis. and Seattle
Table 5.3: Summary of Fees
Fee CindDD8d IndiaaapoUs Seattle
Taxicab Association! $16 annual for $750 annual for Taxicab
Disnatchin2 Office disoatchin2 office None Association
Late Fee None None $75
Taxicab Change of Not Applicable Not Applicable $50
Assoc. Affiliation
$161 annual,
Taxicab License $80.50 on or after July $100 annual $240 annual City
I, $10 initial application $140 annual County
fee.
Late fee (renewal) None None $24 Citvl$14 Co.
Chan~e of Eauioment None None - $50 Citv/$25 Co.
City: $240 Sept-Feb
Change of Owner $10 Transfer None $120 Mar-Aug
$0 Julv 16-Au~ 31
City inspection fees $30lhour, I hour
Vehicle Inspection included in License Fee Not Applicable minimum, for re-test of .
taximeter
Vehicle Re-Inspection None None $20 Class A violations,
$50 Class B violations
Insoection Schedulin~ None None $20
Meter Re2istration None None $5
Suspension None None $50
Reinstatement
Driver License $14 initial annual, $5 $18 bi-annual $55.annual
annual renewal
Add/Change Affiliation Not Applicable Not Applicable $20 (maltimum of 3
associations)
Driver License Late Fee None None $10
ID Photo None None $2
Replacement License $1 I" replacement of ID None $5
Card, $2 subseouentlv.
Driver Training! None None $45 training for new
Examination applicants; $30 Oral
En2lish Proficiencv
~
A review of comparative costs shows that SeattlelKing County is the most expensive jurisdiction
of these three cities in which to license a taxicab. However, there appears to be a positive
correlation between the amount of regulatory activity and the fees paid. Though the costs of
regulatory fees are higher in SeattlelKing County than in Cincinnati or Indianapolis, satisfaction
with the regulatory structure and with taXicab service is also greater in SeattlelKing County than
in the other cities.
Institute for TllIIISporIlIlion Research and Educali.. - May 1998
47
Review of Tuicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. Indianapolis. and Seattle
6.0 Conclusions
This study focused on three aspects of the taxicab regulatory changes in Indianapolis, Cincinnati,
and Seattle:
a. What regulatory changes were implemented;
b. Why they were implemented; and
c. What the impacts have thus far been of these regulatory changes.
Based on the findings and discussion in previous sections it is now possible to draw conclusions
about the regulatory changes in these three cities.
1. The regulatory changes in Cincinnati and Indianapolis are similar to those of Seattle in
1979 but are opposite those of Seattle In 1996.
Both Cincinnati and Indianapolis enacted local ordinances to effect open entry into their taxi
industries. These actions are directly opposite of the 1996 actions of Seattle in requiring all
taxicabs to affiliate with associations and for associations to be responsible for the actions of
their taxicabs. However, the actions of Cincinnati and Indianapolis are very similar to those of
Seattle in 1979 when it, too, deregulated by opening entry and relaxing fare regulations. This
similarity suggests that the re-regulation experience of Seattle may be indicative of what may
occur in Cincinnati and Indianapolis in the future.
2. There was a competitive taxi market in each city prior to deregulation.
A common perception of taxicab service is that one or a few taxi companies control the market
and open entry is necessary to bring competition to the industry. However, in all three of these
cities a high level of competition existed prior to enacting of open entry.
3. These three cities appear to follow a common pattern described by the literature.
Price Waterhouse (1993), Teal (1987), Gelb (1983a,b), Dempsey (1996), and Frankena and
Pautler (1984) all point out a common pattern that follows open entry in local taxi markets.
Usually the fares increase and independent owner-drivers who service taxi queues at airports.
hotels, and train stations obtain additional permits. A bifurcation of the industry results with
companies focusing on neighborhood trips and independents serving the taxi stands. The
problems resulting from too many cabs at these stands then cause the aiiports and perhaps hotels
to institute their own controls over the waiting cabs. Subsequently, the municipal governments
respond by enacting entry controls. The result is that regulation is re~imposed. which has
occurred in all but four of the twenty-one open entry cities examined by Price Waterhouse.
Impacts from the regulatory changes in these three cities generally follow this pattern. An
Insutute for Transportation Resean:h nnd Education . ~y 1998
49
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Change!; in Cincinnati.indianapolis. and Seattle
opportunity has been created for fares to rise in Indianapolis in the period following
deregulation. The cost for a typical 5-mile trip with the fare rates set prior to the implementation
of Proposal 72 was $8.45; that trip may now cost up to $10.00 plus a "Pick-Up Charge" at the
maximum rate now in effect. The price of a trip now varies among different operators due to the
regulation by maximum rate; the typical price for a 5-mile trip calculated according to rates in
use by the two larger companies in July 1997 was $9.00 and $11.25. The lack of a uniform price
can be confusing to visitors accustomed to a set rate for all taxicabs. The price for a 5-mile trip
is now a maximum of $8.00 in Cincinnati and a set rate of $9.00 in Seattle.
The level of service varies among the three cities. In Cincinnati, the number of taxicab
companies doubled from 1993 to 1994, during the initial period of relaxed entry. From 1994 to
1997, there has been only a ten percent growth in the number of companies. Small independent
owner-operators are reported to primarily serve downtown hotels and "personals." There has
been difficulty in getting taxicabs to respond to service requests from low-income areas both
before and after the regulatory changes according to residents. Residents and a regulator cited
the difficulty of acquiring service during evening hours.
In Indianapolis, open entry has not resulted in an increase in the number of taxicabs; however,
many independent owner-operators congregate at already well-served locations such as the
airport and at downtown hotels. In both Indianapolis and Cincinnati, there is a disparity in the
level of service provided by larger companies using radio dispatch and independent owner-
operators using cellular telephones. The larger companies offer 24-hour, 7-day service
throughout the metropolitan area, while the smaller taxicab companies tend to offer service
during fewer hours and to smaller service areas.
The Seattle requirement that all taxicab owners belong to a taxicab association has placed
additional responsibility for providing satisfactory customer service within the taxicab industry.
Representatives from the hospitality and tourism industry reported a high level of satisfaction
with operations under the current regulatory structure. The extent to which customer satisfaction
has increased as a result of the driver training and testing programs is unknown. There were no
perceptions from individuals who were interviewed in Seattle that any particular geographic area
lacked an acceptable level of service. The supply of taxicabs at the airport is limited to those
provided by one contractor.
4. Indianapolis experienced only a brief increase In taxi permits after its most recent open
entry.
The number of active taxicab licenses in Indianapolis increased from 392 prior to opening entry
to 460 in 1996. However, the number of taxicab licenses then decreased. In the 1973-4 open
entry there was not even an initial increase in pennits, and the number of pennits fell from 502 to
466. For the most recent open entry the number of pennits--after initially increasing--fell from
392 in 1993 to 372 in 1997.
The Indianapolis experience with decreases in the number of taxicab licenses illustrates an often-
overlooked fact about taxi markets: the existence of entry controls does not necessarily mean that
InstilU" for TnlllSpot1aIion R_.... EduClltion. M.y 1998
50
Review of Taxicab Regulatory Ch:1nges in CincinRllli. Indianapolis. and Seanle
there is a pent-up demand for taxi permits. Taxi operators face competition from a variety of
other transportation providers as well as private autos. The removal of the cap on the number of
limousine licenses (75) in Indianapolis as part of the revision of the vehicles-for-hire ordinance
resulted in an increase in the number of limousine licenses. Fourteen limousine companies are
currently in operation with 89 licensed limousines. The 1994 ordinance revisions also allowed
jitneys to operate in Indianapolis-Marion County. No new jitneys have been licensed in the city.
5. The impacts of open entry are dampened in Cincinnati because airport is not
deregulated.
One of the common occurrences after open entry has been the growth of the numbers of
independent owner-drivers serving taxi stands, especially airports. The reason for this influx is
that owner-drivers are able to wait at airports and eventually get trips without having to invest in
radio dispatching or advertising. In Cincinnati, however, the airport is located in Kentucky and
hence was not affected by Cincinnati's open entry ordinance. Thus, the city has seen only a
modest number of independent owner-drivers (15). Since most of the problems with open entry
have first been manifested at airports and other major traffic generators, one can expect that
Cincinnati's problems with open entry will be dampened as long as the airport is not opened to
all Cincinnati cabs.
6. Seattle demonstrates the long time required to remedy the effects of open entry.
Nearly two decades have passed since the beginning of Seattle's eKperiment with open entry.
Although the airport, city, and county all took actions during the 1980s to re-regulate, as recently
as 1996 the city was still coping with effects of open entry in terms of service complaints and too
many operators to enforce effectively. Prior to the most recent regulatory actions of 1996, the
city was still trying to regulate 217 operators, of which 200 were one-cab companies and most
without places of business. Thus, the effects of open entry--especially the growth of independent
owner-operators--lingered far beyond the open entry time period, making the re-imposition of
quality controls very difficult.
Instiblte for Trunsporllltion Reseuch IIld Education. May 1998
51
Review of Tuicab Regulatory Changes in Cincinnati. lndianapolis. and Se:1ttle
BmLIOGRAPHY
Avants, S., G. Gilbert, and B. Lupro (1995) "Peer Review of Seattle Taxicab Regulation,"
Report prepare for City of Seattle, Department of Finance.
Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions (1997) "Taxi Regulation in Ohio's Largest Cities."
Dempsey, Paul S. (1996) "Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation and Reregulation: The
Paradox of Market Failure," Transportation Law Journal, 24: I, pp. 73-120.
Frankena, M., and P. Pautler (1984) "An Economic Analysis of Taxicab Regulation," Bureau of
Economics, Federal Trade Commission.
Gelb, P. M. (1983a) "Effects of Taxi Regulatory Revision in Seattle, Washington," U.S.
Department of Transportation, Report No. UMTA-W A-06-0019-83-1.
Gelb, P. M. (1983b) "Taxi Regulatory Revision in Indianapolis," U.S. Department of
Transportation, Report No. DOT-TSC-1409-20.
Goldsmith, S. (1997) "Regulation and the Urban Marketplace," Re2ulation, January.
Gross, Marilyn, and R. Feldman (1994) "National Transportation Statistics: 1995," Bureau of
Transportation Statistics, U.S. Department of Transportation, Report No. DOT - VNTSC-
BTS-94-3.
Lewis, P. (1995) "Cabbies Will Soon Have To Shape Up Or Hit the Road," Seattle Times, July
19.
Price Waterhouse (1993) "Analysis of Taxicab Deregulation and Re-regulation," Prepared for
International Taxicab Foundation.
Shaw, L.C., Gorman Gilbert, C. Bishop, and E. Pruitt (1983) "Taxicab Regulation in U.S. Cities,
Volume I: Final Report," Report for Urban Mass Transportation Administration, U. S.
Qepartment of Transportation, Report No. DOT-I-84-35.
Stanley, M. T., and R. J. Burby (1988) "A Statistical Prof11e of the Private Taxicab and
Paratransit Industry," Report prepared for Urban Mass Transit Administration, U.S.
Department of Transportation.
Teal, R. F. (1987) "An Overview of the American Experience with Taxi Deregulation," Halda,
Inc., Irvine, CA.
Zerbe, R. (1983) "Seattle Taxis: Deregulation Hits a Pothole," Re2ulation, NovemberlDecember,
pp. 43-48.
Institute fotT....portalion Research and Education - May 1998
53
TRANSPORTATION
LAW
JOURNAL
INDUSTRY LEADER IN MULTI-MoDAL LAH; ECONOMICS & POLICY
UNlVERSITI' OF DEl'.'\'ER . COLLEGE OF LAW
Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation &
Reregulation: The Paradox of Market Failure
PAUL STEPHEN DEMPSEY
VOLUME 24 . t'UMBER t . SU~lMER 1990
rn.,."o. '.
;' ......
~ ~+;. E
., "". +
""OCI.a.1\O
Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation &
RereguIation: the Paradox of Market Failure
Paul Stephen Dempsey'
.
.
TABLE OF COSTE""TS
I. Introduction.........................................:..... 74
II. Historical Antecedents of Modern Taxicab Regulation .... 76
Ill. Contemporary Statutory & Regulatory Criteria Governing
the Taxi Industry. . .. . . ... . . .. . . . . . . .. . .. . . . . . . .. . .. . . . . .. . 77
A. New York: .. .... .. .. .. . .. .. .. .. .. .. . .. .. .. .... .. .. . '" 78
B. Los Angeles... .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . .. . . .. . . . . . .. .. . 78
C. Houston.............................................. 79
Copyright CJ t996 by the author
. Paul Stephen Dempsey is Professor of Law and Director of the Transponation Law
Program at the University of Denver. He fonnerly served as an attorney with the Civil Aero-
nautics Board and the Intentate Commerce Commission in Washington. D.C. .
Professor Dempsey has ..ntten more than tony law review anicles and six books: AVI^no~
LAw &. RE.GULATION (two volume$!. Butterwonh 1993); AUU.lN[;, DEREouU\TloN &: LAlSSI!.Z
FAlRE MYTHOLOGY (Quorum Books. 1992): FLYI"'C BUNO: TUE FAILURE OF AUUJNE DEREG.
ULATION (Economic Policy Institute. 1990); THE SOClAL AND ECONOMIC CONSEOUENCES OF
DEREGUUlr.TIQN (Quorum Books. 1989): LAw de. FOR.EJON Poucy fJ'o/ INTERNATIONAL AVIATION
(Transnational Publishers. 1987); and LAW &. ECONOMIC REGuu..nON IN TR.^NSPORTA"ON
(Quorum Books. 1986).
Dr. Dempsey holds the following degrees: A.BJ.. J.D.. University of Georgi~: LL.M..
George Washington University: D.C.L. McGill University. He is admitted 10 practice law in
Colorado. Georgia and the District of Columbia.
The author would like to thank Greg Hall. John Joiner de. Sam Scinta. J.D. candidates. Uni.
versity of Denver. for their assistance in the preparation of this aniele.
73
74
Transportation La... Journal
[VoL 24:73
.
,
D. Chicago............................................... 81
E. St. Louis.. " . . .. . . . . . . . .. . . . . .. .. . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
F. Boston................................................ 83
G. Minneapolis........................................... 84
H. Denver................................................ 85
N. The Economic Characteristics of the Taxi Industry. . . . . . . P
A. Industry Size and Structure ........................... 87
1. Radio-Dispatched Cabs ........................... 88
2. Tne Cabstand Business. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
3. Cruising Cabs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
4. Public Contract Service~. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. .. . . . . . . . 89
B. Industry Costs......................................... 89
C. The Passenger Market. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
1. The Transportation Disadvantaged ................ 90
2. Non-Residents. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
3. Affluent Residents................................ 91
V. Market Imperfections & Theoretical Explanations
Therefor .................................................. 91
A. The Absence of a Competitive Market...... .... '" .. . 91
B. Imperfect Information & Transactions Costs......... . . 93
C. Externalities ........................................... 9-1
D. Cross-Subsidies and Cream Skirruning ................ . 96
E. Economies of Scale & Scope......... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
F. The Absence of Sound Economic Conditions. .. . . . . . . . 97
VI. Bipolar Views on Regulation a!1d Deregul2.tion ........... 100
VII. Empirical Results of Open Entry in the Taxicab Industry. 102
A. Entry................................................. 102
B. Operating Efficiency and Productivity. ............ .... 105
C. Highway Congestion. Energy Consumption &
Environmental Pollution .............................. 106
D. Price.................................................. 107
E. Income................................................ 110
F. Service................................................ 111
G. Administrative Costs.................................. 114
VlII. Summary of the Empirical Results of Taxicab
Deregulation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ... . .... . . .. . . . . ..... .. .. .. . 114
IX. The Need For Goverrunental Planning & Oversight....... 116
I. INTRoDucnor;
During the last fifteen years. Congress has deregulated: wholly or
panly. a number of infrastructure industries. including most modes of
transpon-airlines. motor carriers. railroads. and intercity bus compa-
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 75
nies.' Deregulation emerged in a comprehensive ideological movement
which abhorred governmental pricing and emry controls as manifestly
causing waste and inefficiency, while denying consumers the range of
price and service options they desire.2
In Z:. natio:1 dedicated to free market capitalisnl, go\'crnmcfital re-
straints on the freedom to enter into a business or allowing the competi-
tive market to set the price seem fundamemally at odds "ith immutable
notions of economic liberty. While in the late 19th and early 20th Cen-
tury. market failure gave birth to economic regulation of infrastructure
industries, today, we live in an era where the conventional wisdom is that
government can do little good and the market can do little wrongJ
Despite this passionate and powerful contemporary political/eco-
nomic ideological movement, one mode of transportation has come full
circle from regulation. through deregulation, and back again to re-regula-
tion-the taxi industry. American cities began regulating local taxi firms
. in the 1920s. Beginning a half century later. more than 20 cities, most
, located in the Sunbelt. totally or partially deregulated their taxi compa-
nies. However. the e"-perience "ith taxicab deregulation was so pro-
foundly unsatisfactory that \irtually every city that embraced it has since
jettisoned it in favor of resumed economic regulation.
Today, nearly all large and medium-sized communities regulate their
local taxicab companies. Ty-pically, regulation of taxicabs involves: (1)
limited entry (restricting the number of firms. andlor the ratio of taxis to
population). usually under a standard of "public convenience and neces-
sity," [PC&N] (2) just, reasonable. and nondiscriminatory fares. (3) ser-
vice standards (e.g., vehicular and driver safety standards, as well as a
common carrier obligation of nondiscriminatory service. 24-hour radio
1. Such legislation includes the Air Cargo Deregulation Act of 1977. the Airline Deregula-
tion Act of 1978. the International Air Transportation Competition Act of 1979. the Staggcl'l
Rail Act of 1980, the Motor Carrie: Act of 1980, the Household Goods Transportation Act of
1980. the Bus Regulatof')' Refonn Act of 1982. the Civil Aeronautics Board Sunset Act of 1984.
the Surface Freight Forv.arder Dereg:.llation Act of 1986. the Negotiated Rates ACl of 1993. the
Trucking Industry Regulatory Refor::-: Act of 199~. and TItle VI of the Federal Aviation Act of
1994. Sa g(nerally. PAUL DEMPSEY & WIll-lAM TUOMS. LAW & ECONOMIC REGl:LATlON IN
TRA"lsPORTATlON (1986). and PAL:'L DEMPSEY. ROBERT HARDAWAY & WILUAM TIIOMS. AVIA.
nON LAW & REGULATlO!'; (1993). l\'ote however. that although the U.S. Congress has pre.
empted much of state and local regulation of the airline. railroad. and trucking industries.
economic regulation of the suriace passenger transportation industry has remained largely un.
touched by federal preemption.
1. Sa. (.~.. PAL'L DEMPSEY, TltI: SOCI,'L & ECO'OMIC CONSEOUE:-;CES or- Di:REGU~.
no,,", (1989): PAUL DEMPSEY & As DReW GOETZ. AIRLINE DeRJ:GULATION & LAISSEZ FAJRl:.
MYTlIOLOGY (1992)
3. Sa r"ural(v Paul Dem;Js.ey. Marker Fai"ure a.'ld Re~ulalon: Failure As CalalvSIS for
Polmcal Change: The Choice 8enwen Imperfecl Re~u{atlon and Imperfecl RegulatIOn. 46 WASil.
& LEe L Re..... 1 (1989)
.
.
76
Transportation Law Journal
[VoL 24:73
dispatch capability. and a minimum level of response time). and (4) finan.
eial responsibility standards (e.g., insurance).-
1his anicle explores the legal, historical, economic. and philosophical
bases of regulation and deregulation in the taxi indust'}" as well as the
empirical results of taxi deregulation, The paradoxical metamorphosis
from regulation, to deregulation. and back again. to regulation is an inter~
esting case study of the collision of economic theo'}' an ideology. with
empirical reality, We begin with a look at the historical origins of taxi
regulation,
II. HISTORICAL M'TECEDE1>'TS OF MODER'" TAXlCAB REGULATlOl'<
Hackneys (horse dra\\TI coaches for hire). the predecessors of to-
day's taxicabs, were regulated shonly after they appeared on the streets
of London and Paris between 1600 and 16205 In 1635, Charles I ordered
that London hackneys be licensed so as "to restrain the multitude and
promiscuous use of coaches, "6 Nineteen years later the British Parlia-
ment adopted a regulato'}' regime which Iimitcd the number of
hackneys7
In the U:li:ed States, governmental regulation of private firms,
rather than public o\\TIership. has been deemed the appropriate means of
protecting the public interest in economicaliy viable modes of transpona-
lion,S Although some attribute comprehensive regulation of taxicabs to
the Great Depression. in fact, regulation began in earnest during the
1920s.9 In the 1930s, the gro\\1h in unemplOyment and unsold
4. Su Michael Kemp. Ta..ricab Sen.'ice, in PARA-TRANSIT: N!:GLEC"TtD OPi'IOSS FOR UR.
BAS MOBn..rrr 64 (Urban Institute 1984): DEMPSEY &:. THO~fS. supra note 1. at 1: Roger Teal &:.
Mary Berglund. The l~pa;ts of Ta;ticab Deregu:<llion in the USA. J. TRAKSP. Eco.'.;. & POL'y 37
(hn, 19S7).
5. D3\;d \\!iUiams. Injormation and Price DttamifUJlion in Taxi Marktt.S. 20 Q. Rz:v. OF
EcoN. &:. Bus. 36 (1\.181). AetuaUy, common carrier liability owes its origins 10 Roman Law,
beginning about the year 200 B.C. Sa DEMPSEY & THO'''lS. supra note 1. at 2.
6. U.S. DEP'T OF TRAMI'.. TAX1CAB RI::Gt..:LATIO" I" U.S. CITII::S 5 (1983).
7. [d. at 6. The London Hackney Caniage Act of 1831 (as amended in 1~3) was the first
comprehensive taxicab regulation ordinance: Gene Stalians.. R~~u/atory R~yuiun and th~ Taxicab
Industry: What Wt Ha\'t Ltarntd 1. Address before the 50th Annual Convention of the New
Zealand Taxi Proprietors' Federation. Wellington, New Zealand. Aug. 30. 1988.
8. WlllJAM BARKJ:;R & MARY BEARD. URBAN T AXTCABS: PROlll.EMS. POTE!'>rflAL AND
PLANNING. r,.; PROCEEOINGS 01" TIll:: CONFERENce ON TAXIS As PUBLIC TRA""SIT 40 (Univ. of
California, 1978). Modes of Iranspon which were not economically \.iable in the market (e.g..
urban railwa~"S. Amtrak and the U.S. Postal Service) were provided by ~overnment in a process
John Kenneth Galbraith is said 10 have referred to as "Lemon Socialism."
9. MARK FRANK[:-.lA & P.'\t.:L PAL'TLER. AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS or TA.-O::JCAfI Rt;GULA.
TIC'" 75 (Fed. Trade Comm.. 19R4); Su Kemp. supra note 4. at 65_ "The campaIgns of profes-
sional cab associations for vehicle licensing during the late 1920$ were a direct response to the
disruption in the market crealed by hil-and-run entrants."; su aLfo Edward Gallick & David
Sisko A Ruo/tSldua(lon of Taxi R~,u!arlOn. 3 J.L. Eco!'o'_ & ORG. 117. 1:;3 (J98i).
.......
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 77
automobiles produced a drastic increase in the number of taxicabs.lO
While fewer people could afford to ride a taxi, the number of taxicabs
skyrocketed, while occupancy rates and revenue per taxi declined. J 1 Ca-
pacity and demand were moving in opposite directions.
An editorial published by tho lI'asninglOr; Pos: it; h"1ucr:; 1933 illus-
trates the public's perception of the chaotic state in which the taxicab
industry found itself:
Cut-throat competition in a business of this kind always produces chaos.
Drivers are working as long as sixteen hours per day. in their desperate ef-
forts to eke out a living. Cabs are allowed to go unrepaired. . . .
fogether v.'ith the rise in the accident rate there has been a sharp decline in
the financial responsibility of taxicab operators. Too frequently the victims
of taxicab accidents must bear the loss because the operator has no re-
sources of his o....n and no liability insurance. There is no excuse for a city
exposing its people to such dangers.12
Economists of the era argued that taxis were a declining cost indus-
try: excessive competition between numerous small operators decreased
carrier eLt1ciency and increased consumer costs. 13 The U.S. Department
of Transportation also sununarized the tenor of the times:
Tne excess supply of taxis l~d to fare wars. extortion. and a lack of insurance
and financial responsibility among operators and drivers. Public officials
a::.d the press in cities across the country cried out for public control over the
t3..xi industry.
Tne response was municipal control over fares. licenses. insurance and other
aspects of taxi ser.ice.14 .
III. CONTEMPORARY STATIJTORY AND REGULATORV CRITERIA
GOVERNING THE TAx! INDUSTRY
Virtually all municipalities engage in taxi industry regulation under
state legislation requiring or permitting such regulation. which itself acts
under the guise of the state's police power. Although sometimes chal-
lenged as unconstitutional on various grounds. or preempted by federal
law, these statutes and municipal ordinances have been nearly universally
10. Su GORMA!'.' GILBERT &:. RODCH.T SAMLiCLS. Tllc T AXICAS: AN URBAN TRANSPORTA.
TIO!'.' S:.:RVIVOR 149 (1982).
II. FH.A!'.'KI:....A &:. PAL.L!:H.. suora note Y. at 75.
12. Taxicab Chaos. WASIl. Pos!. Jan. 25. 1933. editorial page.
13. Sandra Rosenbloom. Th~ Taxi In ,he Urban Transpon S.vslem. TII[;' PRIVATe OIAL
Le:-:GC TO PUBLIC TRANSP'ORTATIO'" r Charles Lave. ed.. 1984). Similar arguments were made in
the 192()s and 19305 in favor of regulating the ttucklng industry. Su Paul Dempsey. Running On
Empn' Trucking Datguuuion and Economic Th(ory. 43 AOMI~, L. Re.... 253. 304.306 (1991)
1':, U.S. Dcp',[ OF TRA~SP.. supr.:s nOte 0. at 6.;
78
Transponation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
upheld.'S
Typically, taxis are regulated at the local level. \\ith city or county
boards restricting the number of firms and number of taxis (with the issu-
ance of medallions), and setting prices (usually on a mileage basis),
safety, insurance and service standards. Their decisions are given ex-
trcm~ deference by reviewing courts. In this section. several oi the ap-
proaches to economic regulation oi taxis in some of the nation's major
cities are examined. As we shall see. their similarities are far more nu-
merous than their differences.
.
.
A. l\Ew YORK
The state of l\ew York permits its municipalities to adopt ordinances
which require the registration and licensing of taxicabs.'. New York mu-
nicipalities may also establish restrictions concerning parking and passen-
ger pick-up and discharges." Jurisdiction to promulgate rules and
regulations concerning the supervision and operation of taxis has been
vested in the Police Commissioner." Typically. the municipal ordinances
require that taxis be insured for specific amounts.'9
New York City has regulated its taxis since the 1930s. Medallions
were limited to 11.787 in 1937,20 causing the medallion price to reach ex-
orbitant levels, itself generating some measure of legitimate criticism of
taxi regulation.
B. Los ANGELES
In contrast to New York, which permits municipalities to enact taxi
regulations, the Texas and California state statutes require municipalities
to regulate the local taxi industry."l These municipalities may enact ordi-
nances which regulate entry, such as "controls, limits or other restrictions
15. Su e.g." Golder. State Transit Corp. v. ell)' of Los Angeles 726 F.2d 1430 (D.C. Cir.
1983). cen. denied. 105 S. 0. 1865 (1983). Here. a municipality's taxicab regulation sun;vcd
scrutiny under the Sher.::an Act. as it fell under the "state action" exemption to that legislation.
Although Title VI of the Federal Aviation Act of 199.: preempted intrastate reg:ulation of motor
carriers of propeny. it die not preempt intrastate regulation of the transportation of passenger3.
The Bus Regulatory Reform Act of 19l:i2. although providing (or Interstate Commerce Commis.
sion review of intrastate entry. eX)t and rate regulation. did not apply to the taxi industry. s,~
also Rudack v. Valentine. 295 N.Y.S. 976 (1937) (taxi statute unsuccc:ssfully challenged on
grounds that it violated claimant's due process rights).
16. N.Y. Gen. Mun.! 181(1).
17. ld.
18. Su Teuch v. Ml..::-phy. 256 N.Y.S.2d 25 (1965)
19 S~~ Foley \'. McKnealley. 325 N.Y.S.2d 165 (1971).
20. Peter Suzuki. UnrtKu.Jaud TaxIcabs. 49 TRANSP. Q. 129, 132 (1995)
21. California's statute is typical:
{Elvery city or COUnty shall protecl the public health. safety. and welfare by adopting
an ordinance or resolution In regard 10 ta:ucab transportation service rendcred In
19%] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 79
on the total number of persons providing the services, rates, safety and
insurance requirements" and other requirements which will "ensure safe
and reliable passenger transponation service,"22
The city of Los Angeles requires an applicant to prove "public con-
venience and necessity" in order to gain entry into the taxicab industry,
with entry, rates and business practices governed by the Los Angeles
Board of Transponation Commissioners23 In evaluating the PC&N cri-
terion, the Board may consider the applicant's financial capability, evi-
dence that existing taxicabs "are not, under efficient management,
earning a fair and reasonable return on their capital devoted to such ser-
vice, , ,", that existing taxicabs ". . . are or are not, under normal condi-
tions, adequately serving the public. . .", and ". . . whether existing
services are meeting the need or demand. "2'
The Los Angeles ordinance includes the typical requirements of in-
surance,2S an approved identification system of color and signage,26 me-
ters,2? rate regulation.2' a requirement that the driver take the most
~ direct route29 and not charge more than the prescribed fare,30 and de-
scribes the circumstances under which a driver or vehicle permit may be
temporarily or permanently suspended or revoked.31 The rules adopted
by the Board of Transpo:tation Com."!l.issioners indude precise safety reg.
ulations (including maximum age of vehicles, inspection, maintenance, re-
pair, seat belt and 'other requirements), cleanliness of vehicle. counesy
and honesty of driver. and common carrier service obligations.32
C. HOUSTON
The licensing of new entrants under the Houston municipal Code
requires a hearing by the city Depanment of Finance and Administration
vehicles for caIT)ing not more than eight persons. excluding the driver. which is oper-
ated v.;thin the jurisdiction of the city or county. . . ."
CAt... GOV'T CoOE t 53075.5 (West Supp. 1996). The California Public Utilities Commission
may not regulate the 1OCJ.1 taxi induslf')' if it is already licensed and regulated by the city. People:
v. San Francisco. 155 Cal. Rptr. 319 (1979). Tens requires the municipahty to regulatc not only
the arca within its jurisdiction. but also jointly o.....'T1ed municipal propeny and propeny "in which
thc municipality possesscs an ov.l1crship intcrcst." Tt::x. LOCAL Gov',., t 215.004 (West 1995)
22, Tt::x. locAL GOV'T CoDE AN!". ~ 215,004 (West 1995).
23. Los ANGEt.r.S M1..'"l'-'. Coot.. ch. \'11. an, 1. H 71.00. 71.12.
24. Jd. i 71.13.
25. Jd. P1.14.
26. td. Ii 71.16. 71.19. 71.20. il.21.
27. Jd. i 71.21.
2S. Jd. i 71.25.
29. Jd i 71.23.
3U. Jd. i 71.24.
31. Jd. Ii 71.01 .71.10.
32. DEPT. or TRA!"sP.. Clli' or- Los Al"Gl:LJ:s. T ^XlC^B RL'Ll:S ^ND REGUL^TIO'-":S OF TIll:
BOARD OF TRA....SI'. COM."1':-; (1991)
.
.
80
Transponation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
under a "public convenience and necessity" standard, in which applica-
tions are denied unless the applicants are able to prove, by clear and con-
vincing evidence, that the standard is met." In assessing the PC&N
standard, the director of the Depanment must evaluate the nwnber of
vehicles to be operated, the effect of new entry on traffic congestio:J (\'e-
hicwar and pcdestrian), the number of pernuts in operation, the irnpact
on existing permit holders, and "any other facts the director may deem
relevant."34
33. HOl':STO~. TEX.. CODE OF ORor:-:A:SCES ~ 46.66 (196S). The Houston Code requires all
applications for the $400 taxicab permits to be filed in January of ("ven-numbered years for a
hearing the folloVwing month. Ordinance 93.155 of the City oC Houston amended ~ 46-&.: of the
Houston Code. requiring taxicab permit hearings to be held in even-numbered calendar years,
where previous hearing were conducted annually. The director oi the department of finance and
administration conducts the hearings under a "public convenience and necessity standard" in
which aU applicants are denied unless they are able to provide clear and convincing e\idence
that the standard is met. HOUSTON. Tex., CoOE OF OROI~ANCES ~ 46-66 (1968). However. the
director retains absolule dIscretion in determining whether public convenience and r.ecessit)'
requires the issuance of additional permits. since Houston ordinances require the dlrec;tor to
camide:- nct or!Jy eml:n::ra:ed fac:o:-s such as effects or. traffic congestior.. the number 0: exis:i::g
penni!s in operation. and potential economic impact on existing permit holders. but 3;SO "a.;)
other facts the director may deem relevant." The Houston Code ~ 46-66 provides in p.!;.:
I;: de;:ennining whether public convenience and necessity require the issuance of the
tuicab permit 10. the application, the d:reClor shall take mto consideration:
(3) Nu.rnber of vehicles to be operated.
(6) The effect of ac!ditional vehicles upon the traffic congestion. vehicular and pedes-
trian alike.
(10) The total number of ta:ucab permits in' operation.
(11) Whether the requirements of public convenience and necessit)'can be met a.",:d
complied with or.l)' by the lssuance of additional permits.
(12) The resulting er:ec: cpon the business of existing perrr.;t holders and upor. exist;::g
agencies of mass transponation in the city
(13) Any other faCtS the director may deem relevant.
34. The taxicab business in Houston. Texas, has traditionally been controlled by Yellow Cab
compa.ny. which prior to 1993 held almost 70% of the 2.098 annual pemtits issued by the City of
Houston. Cab Du~xulallon Dra....J Praise. Criticum. HOl.'STO~ POST. Sept. 13. 1993. 1;-. Sep.
tember. 1993, The Houston City Council voted to award 49 new taxicab permits. predominantly
to smaller cab companies. in an effort to respond to a rosier economic outlook and a perceived
need for more competition in the industry. The partial deregulation by the City Council slgnalec
a new approach by the Regulator')" Affairs Office of the City of Houston in allowing an i~creas('
in the nUr.lber of permits. an action whIch was '-'igorously opposed by Yellow Cab. In adc!aion 10
the increase in the number of taXIcab permits in Houston. the cit~. increased the taxi fares slightly
from S1.50 for tbe first 2'11 mile and SO.30 for each additional 11145 mile 10 S1.50 for the f:rsl1f9
mile and $0.30 for each additional 2.'9 mile. while ellmlnating a provision providing a maximum
p~r-cab fare for trips \\;thm the do.....mO....il area. HOuSTo..... Tex.. OROI~^NCE.J 93-9 (1993)
Flat rates to Houston In:ercontlnemaJ Airport (IAH) and maxImum waiting time charg:s also
ir:cre3sed under the am:=nd=c ordinance. so while Houston has increased the level of laXJcab
competition by allo\\1ng easier em!!. It appears that pncmg controls ",ill remain in ('teet 10
prt:vent fare wars among the larger ta.'{i fleet
Despite Houston's rela.'{allon of entr.... the city retains fi~ control of the taxiear- ~outes
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 81
D. CHICAGO
The Municipal Code of Chicago provides a system of strict regula-
tion of license acquisition and fare selling." The code is typical of the
entry criteria imposed bv most cities on the tax.i industry. It requires that
new entry be permitted only where consistent \\ith the "public conven-
ience and necessity", which is to be determined with an evaluation of
public demand, safety, the economic impact on competitors, and the
wages, hours and conditions of drivers.36
.
.
between the city and its two major airports. IAH and William P. Hobby Airport (HOU). Any
taxicab depaning eIther airport ",ith passengers is required to pay a fial fee to cover the city'!>
administrative and related expenses. and pricing to and from IAH is controlled by a flat rate
scheme based on the division of the city of Houston into seven zones. Taxicab standing queues
have been established at JAH. limiting passenger pick up to only those cabs that are operating
under a valid city permit. and eligible cabs may receive a pnority reassignment (thereby moving
to the front of the queue) if the taxicab returns to the departure zone ....ithin fony-live minutes of
its previous depanure. HOUSTO:S, TEX., Com: OF ORDI_"^SCJ:S ~ 46-26 (1968). Although the
city of Houston co:-ainues to regulate the lucrative airpon routes. and general meter pricing. it
remams to be seen what effect relaxed entry standa:-ds ",ill have on Houston's taxicab business.
One Houston City Councilman has suggested that relaxed entry has signaled the death k.nell of
regulation. Cab Der~gu/.o.lion Draws Praue, CritiCISm. HOl:STo:"O POST. Sept. 13, 1993, City
Councilman Frank Mancuso is quoted as saying: "In my opinion. we no longer regulate cabs. It's
that simple. Everyoody and anybody is going to be au! there now. It doesn'l bode well 10 lose
complete control like that:"
35. CHICAGO. Ill.... Mus. CODE, ch. 4-348-040 (1956):
Ir. determining whether public con'..enience and necessity require additional taxicab
set\lce. due consideration shall be given to the follo....i.::.g.
1. The public demand for taxicab set\i.ce:
:!, The effect of an increase in Ihe number of taxicabs on the safety of existing ..-ehicu-
lar and pedestrian traffic:
J. 1n.;: dice. of i::creased compcti:ior:.:
a. Or: revenues of taxicab operators:
b. On the cost of rendering taxicab service. including provisions for proper
reserves and a fair return on investment ir: propeny de,,'oted 10 such seno'iee;
c. On the wages or compensation. hours and conditions of service of taxicab
chauffeurs:
4. The effect of a reduction. if any, in the le..'el of net revenues to taxicab operalors on
reasonable rates of fare for taxicab service:
5, An~' other facts .....hlCh the commissioner may deem rele..-ant.
If the commissioner shall report that public convemence and necessity require additional
taxicab service. the council. by ordinance. may fix the maximum number of taxicab licenses to be
issued. not to exceed the number recommended by the commissioner.
36. CIIICAOO. Iu..., Mvr-;. CODE. eh, 4-348 (1956). In 1960. the public vehicle license com-
missioner of Chicago .....as granted authority to Issue additional taxicab licenses up to a maximum
of 4.600. increasing the prior limitation of 3.701 medallions. Under Ihe municipal code. the com-
missioner was required to repon a finding of "publ:c convemence and necessity" based on public
demand. traffic safety considerations. industry comoetltlon efiects. and commissioner'dlscretion,
before licenses could be increased up to the 4,600 ceiling. Over the last twenty-five years. taxi.
cab medallions were predorrunantly in the hands of the two largest cab companies. Checker Taxi
Company' and Yello..... Cab Company These t.....o compames controlled SO'}o of the Chicago
licenses. promptlOg the Chicago City Council to pro?ose the Issuance of 1,500 additional licenses
in 199~. to be distributed Q\-'er a three \'ear penoe, ....11n open emf" slated for 19Y1 Faced ....'th
82
Transponarion La... Journal
[Vol. 24:73
E. ST. LoUls
The St. Louis city ordinance is also typical of those governing the taxi
industry. It establishes a Board of Public Service to issue certificates of
PC&N, determined on the basis of:
[\1,']hct:;,c:- t:-:::: cc::::;.::::s c- ::--:.::: l-~bL: rcqL:.1:~ :..:.::: propose":: c ;"ddltIO':ai ta\-
icab senice within the CIty: that existing taxicab service is Dot sufficient to
properly meet the needs of tbe public: the financial responsibility of the ap.
plicant; the number, kind. type of equipment and color scheme proposed to
be used: tht: ir:crcased t:-affic congestion and demand for increased parking
space upon the streets of the city whid~ I"'.lay result. and whether the safe use
of the streets by the public, both vehicular and pedestrian, "ill be preserved
by the granting of the additional license; and other relevant facts as the
Board may deem ad....-isable or necessary.37
.
.
Vehicles must be painted in distinctive colors" and must be "in a
thoroughly safe condition for the transportation of passengers, clean, fit,
of good appearance and well painted. "39 Taxis must be equipped with
posted fares and taximeters, with fare schedules filed \\ith and approved
the prospect of rapid deregulation. Checker and Yellow Cab forged an agreement y,ith the City
of Chicago. providing an increase: in medallions of 1.100, coupled v.ich the: relinquishing of 1.300
l7lecailior.5 by Checker and Yellow Cab for reassignment. over a ten year period. Ann Marie
l.Jpi:1Shki & Jar.c: Tanner. Taxi Deaf Gw Council's OK Afur lJ Barrie Royal, em. TRlB., Jan. 2S,
19S5. at Cl. Cl. The: new and relinquished licenses arc: awarded to independent drivers by lot-
tery. whose m:!.rket s:tare .....ill increase: to 59% by 1998.
Chicago's mO\'c::nent toward liberalized entry \\ill panicularly impact medallion o....nen.
who received $20,(0) on the open market for a medallion in 19S5. With each issuance of a
medallion through the louery. the medallion value: drops. as lottery ""inners are able to lImit
the::- taxicab license investment to 5250. Toe Chicago a~reement may also affect taxicab fare
reg'.:latior.. in which the Chicago City Council has been uaditionaliy hesitant to increase fares.
Despite rate increases of roughly 30% i~ March. 1990. Chicago's rates were signifi.:.:lntly lower
th3:'. those of-other major U.S cities. Su James Strong. Time to Dig Duptr for Taxi Rides. C1u.
TRia.. Mar. 9.1990. a: C4, C5. Rate increases made by the City of Chicago in 1991 were the first
S!ri~ 1981. Jerry Feldman. the president of Checker Taxi Company. Inc.. testified before a City
CO'..l::cil heanr.g in 1991 :hal a three-mile t::!.xi ride i:1 Ch:cago which costs S3.60 would be at least
S6.50 in Los Angeles. .55.50 in Philadelphia, and S4.60 In New York City
\\'ithin three years. Ihe City of ChIcago survived a challenge to its deregulation scheme
when Checker and Yellow Cab were detennined to have violated Ihe 1988 ordinance b~' setting
up "sham companies" which finan.:ed the purchase of licenses for drivers in return for Ihe driver
putting the medallion up for collateral. P. Davis Szymaczak. Clt,v G~ts Rar~ Vwor.\' Ov~r Cah
Companies. CHI. TRI9.. May 24.1991. at C2. If the driver defaulted on the financing. Ihe medal.
lion passed to the cab company. effectively circumventing the cilY's goal of limiting Ihe market
share of Checker and Yellow Cab. AJlhough the City of Chicago was able 10 keep the move to
liberalized entry alive. !!iven the resistance by the large taxicab companies in Chicago. it is un-
clear whether the market ",,;11 be open in 1981:\. or whether Ihe City will for'ge another limited
reg~!ation agreement.
.'1. ST. LaVIS. Mo.. ORDI~"....ccs 58795. ~ 8.98.023
3S ld.18.98.113
39 ld! 8.98.10;
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 83
by the Board of Public Service.'o To ensure compliance, vehicles shall be
inspected annually.4l Liability insurance must be maintained.'2 To elimi-
nate conflict between drivers, specific rules of conduct apply at taxi
stands:
Taxicab drivers entering a taxicab stand shall do so from the rear. and shall
progress toward the front thereof whenever the opponunity to do so is pres-
ent. The drh'er in the foremost position shall be entitled to serve the first
customer arching at that location, pro\ided. however. that should the cus-
tomer elect to employ any other taxicab. he shall have a free cno'ice thereof
at all times.43
A common carrier obligation is imposed on drivers to accept all po-
tential patrons, except service "to anyone who is intoxicated or may pres-
ent a personal safety hazard, and . . . any person in funherance of any
unlawful purpose. "44
,
.
F. BosTo~
Legislation promulgated by the Massachusetts legislature in the
1930s gavc the police commissioner of Boston the power to authorize not
more than 1,525 taxis to "suitable persons, firms and corporations who
are owners .of vehicles known as hackney carriages. . ."45 Regulations
promulgated by the Boston Police Commissioner call for a S10 fee for a
hackney carriage license, and a S2 fee for a hackney driver's license,
probably th" lowest such fees in the nation." Nonetheless. because of
the limitcd number of medallions issued. the market price for an existing
medallion has approached S90.000 in recent years"7
In 1989, metered fares were increased 19%. raising the fare for a
two-mile trip from 53.50 to 54.30.48 Boston Police regulations also call for
annual vehicle inspections.49 a card displaying rates in the rear compan-
ment of the taxicab,>" etiquette in taxi stands." appropriate driver ap-
40. [d. 118.98.107.305.
41. [d.~; 8.98.155-167.
42. [d. I; 8.98.172-173. 185.186
43. [d.; 8.98.425.
44. [d. I 8.9K4-I9.
45. AClS of 1930. ch. 392. 14.
46. Su CITY OF BOS1'ON. RULI~S A"'O Rcct.":LATlOSS ESTADLlSlmO BY Till! POLlCr: COM
MISSIOr-;r:R FOR THr: C~ or- BOSTON FOR HACKNCY CARRIAGCS ANt) HACKNl!Y STANDS 'N
ACCORDANCE WtTH CIIAPTl!R 392 or- Tilt:. ACTS or: 1930. as Qm~nd~d, ~~ 2. 4. Su also, CnT' or
BOSTO~, HACKNey CARRIAGe TRAfSI....C M^~t.;l\L,
..n. Suzuki. supra. note 20, at 130
48. Mark Muro. Roa.ch~ lO BOSlof! Cab Om'us: Ta.k~ a. Hlk~. B051 0'" GLOUC. July 29. 19S9.
at loS
JQ CITY or BOSTO~. supra note 40. ~ 7
50 Id ~~ 8. 17.
5l ld, ~ 12
M
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
pearance" and behavior.53 including a prohibition against tranSpOITLtlg
dead bodies.'4
G. MIS"EAPOLlS
The :.1innecpolis T2..xic2.b Ordinance h2.s tr..:cc: pu;-poscs: (1) to
achieve ". , , a better cab service for the riding public, , ,"; (2) provide
"greater safety and protection to the public, , ,"; and (3) establish "better
operating conditions for cab o\\ners and drivers. "55 In detennining
whether the public convenience and necessity warrant new entry. the city
council must conduct a hearing, at which the following criteria shall be
considered:
,
,
ITJhe level and quality of service being provided by existing taxicab opera-
tors: whether additional competition would improve the level and quality of
service or the degree of innovation in delivery of services; the impact upon
the safety of vehicular and pedestrian traffic: the impact upon traffic conges-
tion and pollution: the available taxicab stand capacity; the public need and
demand for service: the impact on existing taxicab operators; and such other
factors as the city council may deem relevant.S6
The Minneapolis ordinance also specifies requirements regarding the
qualifications of new entrants, requiring the city council consider:
[TJbe financial eapabillty and responsibility of tbe applicant: the applica."l's
prior experience in the taxicab business: the level and quality of taxlcab ser-
vice pro\ided by the applicant in the past in areas in which it has operated;
the experience aDd competence of the applicant's drivers: the applicant's
prior record of compliance v.ith the taxicab ordinance including complaints
and disciplinary actions against drivers and vehicle O\\i1ers: the applicant's
prior record of service complaints: the age and condition of the ,,'chicles pro-
posed to be licensed by the applicant: and such other factors as the city coun-
cil may deem relevant.57
Drivers must be courteous,'" assist passengers.'. accept all paying
passengers"o give them receipts upon request'" not smoke \\ithout their
permission"" not overcharge them.b3 drive safely...... carry liability insur-
52. [d. ~ IS.
53. Id. \! 15.20.
5~. [d. ~ 2S. It is unclear .....hether the taxi driver must Jettison a passenger .....ho dies in
transa.
5S MINNEAPOLIS. Mf~:-'. TAXICAB ORDINA:'-ICI::S ch. 341 (1993)
56 Id. 1341.270('1.
57 Id 1341.270rbl
58 Id! 341.100
59 Id ~ 341.110.
61l Id. 1341.170.
61IdI341.200
6:. Id ~ 3.JI.250(dl
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 85
ance,6S and pass a driver training course,"" The ordinance goes so far as
to prescribe the clothing drivers shall wear, prohibiting as outergarmets:
"T-shirts, underwear, tank tops, swimwear, jogging suits, body shirts,
shorts, cut-ofts, trunks, or similar attire, , , ,"67 Licenses may be revoked
or suspended for good cause after notice and hearing.66
H. DENVER
.
.
While most city governments regulate their own taxi companies, Col-
orado is something of an anomaly in that the state Public Utilities Com-
mission [Puq regulates the taxi industry of Colorado's major cities69
Until 1994. entry licensing in the Colorado taxi industry was governed by
the standard of "regulated monopoly";70 beginning in 1994, it was gov-
erned by the standard of "regulated competition. "71
Under the prior "regulated monopoly" regime, no finding of public
convenience and necessity for additional common carrier authority was
justified unless the applicant could demonstrate that the existing opera-
tions were substantially inadequate," for "the existence of an adequate
63. Id.! 341250(n). Rates are dealt ~ith in 11341.710-810.
64. Id.! 341.120.
65. Id.! 341.500.
66. Id.! 341.380.
67. Id.! 341.130.
68. Id! 341.980.
69. n;:e Cok:-aco Ie~i~:a:ur: author.z~d its pue to issue certificates to mOlor vehicle carri-
ers in 1917. 191i Colo. Sess. La\\'!.. ch. 110, t 35. In 1969. it declared common carriers to be
public utilities. 1963 CR.S. ~ 115-1-2(5} (Perm. Supp. 1969) and 1963 CR.S. ~ 115.9.2 cited in
Miller Bras.. Inc:. v. Pub. UtiI. Comm'n. 185 Colo. 414, 421. 525 P.2d 433. 4~5 (1974); Section 40.
10-105(2). c.R.S. 1973.
70. Prior to 1967. motor common carriers of propeny were governed by a statutory provi-
sion restricting: new entT)' under a standard of "regulated monopoly." In 1967. the Colorado
legislature changed the standard to one of "regulated competition." Su Denver Cleanup Serv..
Ine. v. Pub. Util. Comm'n, 192 Colo. 537. 541. 561 P.2d 1252. 1254 (1977) (by changing the law,
""'lthout question (the General Assemblyj intended to protect the public health. safety. and
general welfare b)' providing a framework for the better transponation of persons or property."
71. Judicial and agency precedent interpreting the impon of the parallel 1967 statutory
change is instructive as to the standards to be employed in considering the parallel legislative
change in 1994 by the Colorado legislature of entry standards governing taxi companies,
n. The Colorado Supreme Coun observed that:
[U)nder the policy of regulated monopoly. additional common carrier authority was not
granted where adequate service was already being rendered. .. In accordance with
this theory of regulated monopoly. we have held that a common carrier serving a par-
ticular area is entitled to protection against competition so long as the offered serYice is
adequate 10 satisfy Ihe needs of the area. and no finding of public convenience and
necessity for common carner service IS justified unless present service offered in the
area is inadequate:.
Milier Bros., Inc. v. P'ub. Uti!. COr.'lm'n, 185 Colo. 41~, ~22, 525 P.2c! 433, 446 (197~).
"Under [the concept of regulated monopolyj an applicant for a competing cenifieate was obliged
to show 'substantial' inadequacy in e;ustlOg sen/ices." 185 Colo. at 430. 525 P.2d at 451
86
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
.
.
and satisfactory service by motor carriers already in the area is a negation
of public need and demand for added service by another carrier. "7)
The Colorado Supreme Court held that while inadequacy of existing
services may be considered by the PUC in a "regulated competition" en-
vironment, it is no longer the controlling criterion that it had been in 2
"rc;uI2te: r.oo~opojy" regime." Under the "regulated competition"
standard, the controlling criterion is the "public interest" or the "public
need. "75
In its seminal decision of CM. Morey 1'. Public Uti/ities Commis.
sior.76 [Morey I!J, the Colorado Supreme Court observed that the consid-
eration of the public need for safe,. adequate, dependable, efficient and
reasonably priced transportation services warrants an evaluation of the
impact that potential new ent!)' may have in creating excessive or de-
structivc competitionn In assessing new entry proposals for taxi service
in Colorado, the issue of destructive competition is at the heart of an
assessment of the public's interest in avoiding impaired transportation
services Or higher rates. Neither can "regulated competition" reasonably
be interpreted as supporting unlimited entry.78
73. Ephnam Frelfhtways. Inc. v. Pub. Util. Comm'n. 151 Colo. 596.380 P.2d 228 (Colo.
1963); Colo. Transp. Co. v. Pub. Uti!. Comm'n, 158 Colo. 136. 143.405 P.2d 682, 686 (1965) (taxi
company seeking lO provide bus sen.ice failed to prove inadequac:' in existing senices).
74. Miller Bros..!:':e. v. Pub. Uti!. Cor1".:r.'n. 185 Colo. 41-1. 431.32, 525 P.2d 433. 451 (1974);
CM. Morcy Y. Pub. Uti:. Comm'n, 196 Colo. 153. 156.582 P.2d 685. 687 (1978).
75. eM. Morey. 1% Colo. at 157-58. 582 P.ld at 688: CM. More)' v. Pub. Uti!. Comm'n.
629 P.2d 1061. 1065 (Colo. 1981) (hereinafter Mo,~y Il). In assessing the e\idence. the public
need is broader than the indi\idual need~ or preferences of an applicant's Customers. In deter-
mining whether a public need e:tis!s. the PUC may consider the needs and preferences of the
v.itnesses .....ho testify ir: favor of the appliCJ.nt. although they are not determinative. Morey 11.
629 P.2d 1061. 1066 (Colo. 195!). The pub:lc nee': cor:sists of the needs of the: public as a whole.
IJ a! 106i.
i6. Mur~y II. 629 P.2d 1061. (Colo. 1981).
77. Tnc: Court held:
As a corollary of our holding. !hat the "public need" is broader than the individual
needs ilnd prefere::=es of a~ at'plica~,'s custor.-:et'1. we agree than the Commission may
conSider the impact additional compelllion ma~' have. not only on the conflicting eco-
nomic Interests of competing carriet'1. but also on the abiluy of existing carriet'1 to pro.
vide thc:ir CUstomers and the public ~enerally .....ith safe. efficient and economical
transponatlon semc.es. The obligation to safeguard the ~ener31 public against the im-
paired Se:rv1ces and'or higher rates accompanying destructlve Or excessive competition
is at the heart of the policy of regulated competition,
/d. at 1060 [citations ommedj. "Because of this obtigation. the: pve can require a carrier to serve
unprofitablt: routes that are important to certain segments of the population as a condition of
granting it ::Iuthority to operale more lucrative routes." Durang:o Transp.. Inc. v. Durango. 786
P.2d 428. 4~ I (Colo. 0. App. 1989) .
7R. In .\(or~y II. the Colorado Supreme COUrt amrmed the: PL"C. \l,'hich d'enied a new appli-
cation on thl,' basis of evidence which established tha::
The market for trar:sportatlon sen.'lces In the affected areas was relatively inelastic;
The: llDCratln2 caoacities of e:xis{inl!: common camen. v.'c:r~ underutihzed:
The llt'lc:ratlng rc:ve:lues of eXlstin!!- C3rrien. were l("l\\": and
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 87
IV. THE ECONOMIC CHARACIERlSTlCS OF THE TAXI INDUSTRY
A. INDUSTRY SIZE & STRUCI1JRE
Taxicab companies comprise a $6.5 billion industry employing nearly
300,000 people,79 of whom 225,000 are drivers.so It has been estimated
that the taxicab industry transports more passengers than all U.S. mass
transportation systems combined'"
The taxi industry is a common carrier form of urban transportation,
differing from its mass transit rivals in that it is privately owned, operates
over public streets on no fixed routes, and provides door-to-door (or
point-to-point) service in small vehicles on behalf of." and at the direction
of, individual or very small numbers of patrons,,2 Typically, the contract
between the driver and passenger is informal and ad hoc. Wherc regu-
lated, the price is usually based on the distance (and sometimes the dura.
. Additional competition for present and prospective business would seriously impair
~ the abililY of existing carriers to continue to provide efficient and economical service to
the public
Morey II. 629 P.2d at 1066.
The Colorado Supreme Caun subsequently reaffirmed each of these principles In Trans.
Western Express. Ltd. v. Pub. Util. Com:;:'n. 877 Pld 350 (Colo. 199~), the Supreme Coun
ccncluded that the entr)' standard of "regulated competitioa" is to be applied as follows:
1. Under the dcelri'ne of regulated competition. the controlling consideration is the
"public need" or the "public interes:." Jd. at 353:
2. The burden of proof in e5:;:.':I115::':;-,'; r:.:!J:i: n=::c is en the applicant. Jd.:
3. Tne public need is broader than the individual needs and preferences of an appli.
cant's customers. and consists of the needs of the public as a whole. [d. at 354:
~. !,he public need is advanced by "safe. efficient, and economical transportation serv-
IceS. Jd.;
5. The PUC may consider the adequacy or inadequacy of existing services in deter-
mining the public need. [d.;
6. The Commission may consider the impact of additional competition on the -eco-
nomic health of existing carners, as well as their ability to provide the public with safe,
efficient and economical service. [d.:
7. "Providing for the public need and regulating competition demands that some reo
straints be placed upon inter-carrier competition therefore avoiding destructive compe-
tition." Id. at 353. n.7 citing Morey 11. 629 P.2d 1061. 1066:
K "The doctrine of regulated competition requires the PUC to deny an application
for common<amer authority if I!ranting the application would create 'excessive' or
'destructive' compctiuon." Id. at 353; and
9. "Regulated competition is not synonymous with deregulation." Id. at 354 cUing
Mor~y J/629 P.2d at 1066.67.
79. Su Roy SAMPSON, 1::1' AL, DOMJ:STIC TR^~SP'OR"^TJO~: PRACTice. TlIl::ORY, A."O
POUCy 150 (6th ed. 1990).
SO. ENO TRANSPORTATI01" FOUNOATIO:-';, TRA..SPORT^T101" I.... AMI:.RICA 62.C12th ed.
1994)
81. Rosenbloom. supra note 13
8~. Roger Teal. TtuLs As Public Trar-sil. PROCI::I:.nr..GS or TIlI:. CONFI:.RI::NCr. os TAXIS As
PUBLIC TRANSIT 3 (UnI\'. of California. 1978): County of San Diego Dep't of Transp.. T^XKAlI
STUDY 0 (1978). Su Roy S^MPSON. M^RTI:-; F^RRIS &:. DAVID SCHROCK. DOMI::STIC TR^S'i
PORTATION: PRACTICL TIII:.ORY. A~[,) POLICY 150 (6th ed_ 1990).
88
Transportarion Lalli Journal
[Vol. 24:73
tion) of the ride..' Airport vans and limousines differ in that they
typically operate over fixed routes while taxicabs proceed directly to the
destination designated by the patron."
The taxi industry may be divided into several distinct segments:
.
.
1. Radio-Dispcrchcd Cabs
The radio dispatched portion of the taxicab industry involves a cen-
tral dispatching system whereby patrons call by telephone and cabs are
sununoned by radio.' Taxis are equipped "ith two-way radios. and fleets
are typically larger and have centralized maintenance and repair facili-
ties.86 Economies of scale have been acknowledged to exist in this seg-
ment of the industry due to indivisibilities of the inputs employed in
marketing. dispatching. and management, as well as the need for a suffi-
ciently large fleet to provide adequate service v.ithin reasonable time
v.ithin a designated service territory.'7 Thus, this segment of the industry
is likely to be relatively concentrated." In most cities, the telephone or-
der market accounts for 70%-80% of the overall demand for taxi
service.89
2. The Cabstand Business.
Cabstands exist v.ith queues for both taxis and passengers at concen-
trated locations such as airports and hotels.
3. Cruising Cabs.
The cruising cab business consists of taxis driving along streets on
which pedestrians congregate, searching for a random patron to hail
them. It is profitable only in downtown urban areas of large cities where
a high density of potential riders exists at random locations; the cruising
cab business does not work well in cities \\ith low density populations.90
83. Kemp. supra note 4, at 57.
84. Jd.
85. FRANKE!'OA &:.. PAL,l.:r,R, supra note 9. at 11.12.
86. Kemp. supra note 4.
87. fRANKENA &:.. PAL"'T1-ER. supra note 9. at 54.~5; GILBI!RT &. S^MUIl.LS. supra note 10. at
150 ("When revenue. and hence profit. is considered. . . it appcan that larger firms do have
accc:ss to significant economies of scale. First. they are more likely to be able to respond quick.ly
to trip requests than arc many small finns serving the same area independent of each other:').
Su also Teal &. Berglund. supr(J note 4. at 49 ("Costs for a new entrant include radio equipment.
facilities, personnel and a fleet large enough to pro...;de responsive cily-wide service where there
are thought be 'economies of scope....). .
88. Teal &. Berglund, supra note 4, at 38.
89. Jd. at 39.
90. Chanoch Shreiber. Th~ Economic R~a.sons for Priet (Jnd Entry RtKUlation or Taxicabs:
A Rtjoindu, 15 J, TRANsr. Ecos. & POL.'y 81. 82 (1981),
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 89
4. Public Contract Services.
Sometimes a public agency contracts v.ith a taxi company to prO\ide
one of more of the following services:
(A) traditional fixed route tra.'1si: or dewand-responsivc seniccs in low-
density areas, or late at night. often in lieu of existing Cued-route services;
(B) leeder services to fixed routes;
(C) paratransit seniees lor special target groups such as the poor. the eld-
erly. and the handicapped:
(D) involvement in user-side subsidy program: and
(E) brokerage services matching travelers to the most cost-effective pro-
\ider for each service.91
B. INDUSTRY COSTS
The costs of entry into the cabstand or cruising segments of the taxi
industry are exceptionally modest. consisting principally of a chauffeur's
license. a down payment on a car. four re-tread tires. a few gallons of
gasoline, and a couple of quarts of oil.
In the radio dispatch segment of the industry. fixed costs include the
purchase price of a fleet of automobiles. depreciation. regular mainte-
nance, the radio dispatching equipment and personnel to run it, market-
ing and advertising costs, insurance, driver training. and license and
pertnit fees. Variable costs in the industry are generally a function of
distance. duration and destination which consume variable rates of fuel.
oil and labor.90 Labor expenses have been estimated to constitute 50%
of the cost of taxi service.93
Many costs are joint costs, spread over the outbound and inbound
segments of the journey. A trip without dead heading enjoys two seg-
ments of revenue over which to spread both fixed and variable costs. For
example. a thrity-mile passenger trip to a commercial airport enjoys a
high probability of returning v.ith a paying passenger. while a thirty-mile
passenger trip to a remote suburban community has a high probability
the taxi v.ill return empty'"' The relationship between cost and revenue
of these two equivalent trips v.ill differ significantly because of the exist-
ence or non-existence of a pa)ing patron on the return leg of the jour-
ney.9~ In the absence of regulation. a taxi driver has a strong incentive
either to refuse service to a patron seeking transportation to a remote
community from which there is unlikely to be a return trip (or to charge a
Yl. Rosenbloom. nou /3
92. Su Gallick &. Sisko supra note Y. at 117.8.
93. Teal & Berglund. supra nme 4, at 4~
9~. Galilck & Sisko supra nme Y
95 ld
90
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
price much higher, on a per-mile basis, than is charged elsewhere), and to
queue for profitable trips at cabstands.9'
Where profits are inadequate (as results for example, where entry is
deregulated) the principal costs which can be trimmed are drivers' wages,
vehicle maintenance, and the purchase of new equipment. However. taxi
driver wage rates are already among the lowest in the labor force97
C. THE PASSENGER MARKET
The market for taxicab services can be divided into several distinct
segments, each with its Olm demand characteristics:
1. The Transportation Disadvantaged.
The "transponation disadvantaged" include the elderly. unem-
ployed, handicapped. children and low-income persons. In fact. a large
proponion (perhaps most) of the users of taxicab service are persons of
low income9S For example, a 1970 study of taxi use in Pittsburgh re-
vealed that 58% of those who used taxis regularly did not own an auto-
mobile: 60% of the trips were made by housewives, students, or
unemployed, retired or incapacitated indi\iduals99 The 1975 National
Personal Transportation Stud)' revealed that 60% of all taxi services are
provided to the transponation disadvantaged. A Federal Trade Commis-
sion study concluded that, "the low-income population spends higher
shares of their income, and often simply more dollars, on taxis than does
the high-income population. "100
Hence taxis play an essential role in transponing the disadvantaged.
low mobility. and lower income segments of the population.lol The poor
are panicularIy reliant on the radio dispatched segment of the markel.I02
2. Non-Residents.
In large cities. the market also consists of a substantial number of
oUl-of-town business. convention or vacation visitors.103 These travelers
do have a competitive alternative in the form of remal cars. although usu-
ally at a much higher price than taxicabs."'" Business travelers also may
not be as highly sensitive to the price of taxicab service since many are on
96. Id. at 120.
97. Teal & Berglund. supra note 4. at 49.
98. Su supra note 13.
99. TeaL supra note 82
100. FRANKEN A & P"L.LER. supra note 9. al 3.
101. See GtLBERl &:. S",\"(I;ELS. supra note 10. at 11~
102. FRAl'o'K.El"A &:. PAL,LCR. supra note 9. at 12.
103. Su Teal. supra note 82. at 14.
I~ BARKER & BCMW. supra nOte l:\. at 4~
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 91
theit company's expense accounts.105
3. Affluent Residents.
The wealthy are not financially burdened by the regular use of taxi-
cabs, and enjoy the personalized nature of the service and its conven-
ience'06 In certain densely populated cities, particularly those in the
Eastern United States, with their congested streets and limited and ex-
pensive parki:ig. a large nu;:nber of resideI4tS fmd u prin:te automobile an
inCOI1Vefljent way to travel.
.
.
V. MARKET IMPERJ'ECTIONS
A. THE ABSENCE OF A CO"-IPETlllVE MARKET.
In the cabstand market, the "firsl in, first out" rule severely restricts
comparative shopping by consumers.107 In both the cabstand, and the
cruising cab market, competitive shopping is impractical. and the transac-
tion costs to prospective passengers of finding the taxi with the lowest
price can be problematic. lOB One Source summarized the practical
problems with competitive shopping at cabstands:
First, space on airport or botel stands is usually severely limited and cabs not
at the head of th.e hne often do not have a safe manner in which to pull out
from the queue when hired. Second. there is no way in which one cab can be
made [Q wait while a prospective passenger goes shopping.109
Another observed:
fThe cab stand market) is a system that impedes price competition. because
it puts drivers in a stronger position ilian customers. . .. Moreover. airport
customers arc unlikely to dicker \\ith or refuse a cab that seems to be as-
signed to them. especially when they do not know local fares or know tbat
legal fares may ,..ary. or wben they are on expense accounts and not much
concerned about costs. . . .
In cab lines. . . the deterioration in quality also occurs because there can be
little competition on the basis of either quality or price.11U
Given these practical difficulties, it is not at all clear that a competi-
tive market for taxi services either exists or can be created.111 As one
105. FRANKENA & PAL!TLER. supra note 9. at 129.
106. Su BARKER &. BCARD. supra note H al 44: GIUlt:.RT &: SAMUI:L!i. supra note JO. at Ill:
SAMPSON. ET AL.. supra note 79. at ISCJ.
107. FRANKENA & PAUTLCR. supra note 9. at 142.
lQ.8. GIU!ERT & SAML'CLS. supra nOle 10. at 151: FKASKENA &. PAL.'TLER, supra note 9, al 51.
109. GIU!ERT &. SAMUCLS. supra note 10. at 152.
110. Richard Zerbe. Jr.. Stau(e Taxis' Dut~ulation Hits a Pornolt. ReG. (Nov.-Dec. 19831. al
43.46.
111. "Suppl~' and dema:1d analYSIS is inapplicable to the cruiSing taxicab markel, The: condl'
92
Transportation La... Journal
[Vol. 24:73
source observed, "It is not certain. . . that a 'market' in the pure eco-
nomic sense even exists."!12 Moreover, visitors from other cities may be
unaware of the prevailing price for taxicab services, or whether the pas-
senger is protected from exorbitant pricing by a regulatory authority.lI3
Absence of a competitive market exists not only at cabstands, but in
the cruising market as well. Competition in the cruising market is un-
likely unless a number of taxis congregate in a single location at the same
time the patron is present.1I4 One commentator lamented the absence of
a traditional competitive market in the taxi business, noting that time is of
the essence in the procurement of ta.xi services:
Commuters almost always grab the first cab that drives by. as opposed
to shopping for a taxi like. say. a restaurant, where the choices are arrayed
and where the business v.itb the best or most efficient service v.ins. AU of
which means that the fruits of a free market-namely that competition al-
lows the best to thrive and prompts the worst to go broke-are lost. Ulti-
mately. deregulation in the cab industry provides an incentive for all
involved to offer the cheapest service allowable,ltS
,
.
The spatial nature of the industry inhibits price shopping. thereby
creating somewhat inelastic demand.!!6 Professor Chanoch Shreiber put
it best:
Unlike other atomistic markets. a taxicab market in which cruising is
the main method of operation will seldom give rise to pricing competition.
In most .industries sellers are at a fixed location. and customers have the
ability to shop around for price and return to the seller offering the best
terms. A seller can thus, by reducing his price expect to gain more business.
since some customers shopping for price \\ill s\\itch to him from his competi-
tors. Not so in the case of taxicabs. An individual cab operator. acting inde-
pendently. ca....mot gain more passengers if he alone reduces his price below
the going market rate.II7
Professor Shreiber goes on to point out that because a prospective
tions for reachmg equilibrium. specified in supply and demand analysis. cannot exist in the case
of taxicabs. and. the point of interaction between the supply and demand for taxicab rides is nOI
an equilibrium position." Shreiber. supra note 90. at 298.
112. GU..BERT & SAMUEUi. supra note 10. at 151-
113. FR.ANKEI'l^ & P ^UTllR. supra nOle 9. at SO.
114. James Foerster & Gorman Gilbert. Taxicab Deregulation: Economic Consequences and
Regulatory Choices. 8 TR^NSP. 371. 383 (1979).
115. Christopher Georges. D.C."s Checkered Cabs: Why Washtn.(lon.s Taxis Art' America's
Worst. W^SIll~GTON POST. Mar. 21. 1993. at Cl. 0.
116. Richard Coffman. The Economic Reasons for Prla and Entry Re,fUlation or Taxicabs: A
Comment. 9 J. TR"".SP. ECON. & POL'y 288 (1975): David Williams. lnfo;.mallon and Price Dr.
raminarion in Taxi Markers. 20 Q. ReV. &ON. &. Bt.:s. 36. 37 (1981).
117. Chanoch Shreihc:r. The Economic Reasons for Price and Enm. R~,f!ulalion of Taxicabs. 9
J. TR^~~P. Eco.... & POL'" 268. 27U (1975)
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 93
passenger who values his or her time "ill not likely turn down the first
available cab on the basis of price, this mll have an "upward pressure on
the price. "118 A consumer hailing a cab from a sidewalk has an incentive
to take the first taxi encountered, because both the waiting time for the
next cab and its price are unknownI19 Paradoxically, in an open entry
regime, prices tend to rise while vehicular utilization rates tend to falP20
Potential patrons for whom price is a determinative factor, but time is
not, may take the bus, subway, or some other form of public transport, .
where and when it is available. However, little cross-elasticity of demand
appears to exist between the taxicab and mass transit industries. for most
taxi demand is time sensitive'21
,
,
B. IMPERFECT INFORMATION & TRANSACTIONS COSTS.
The free market competitive model assumes consumers have "per-
fect information." Yet consumers buying taxi service in a deregulated
market often have little comparative pricing or service information, for
the opportunity costs of acquiring it are high. As one source observed,
,.there is little incentive for price comparison for the occasional taxi user,
as transaction costs (in time and effort) are high in relation to the poten-
tial savings (less than $1 for a $5 to $6 trip)."l22
It is, quite simply, difficult for a consumer to assess the quality of
transportation service at the time it is ordered, for transportation is in the
nature of a "credence good"-one that cannot be examined prior to con-
sumptionY3 A prospective patron can tell something about a taxi \isu-
ally by the make and model of the automobile. as well as its dents,
scrapes and paint job. But not until s!he enters the taxi "ill srne know
how long the trip will take or how circuitous the trip will be, how smooth
and comfortable the ride "ill be. how knowledgeable and courteous the
driver may be. and whether the price mil be a fair one.
The efficient acquisition by consumers of useful information on pric-
ing is problematic in the cab stand and cruising markets. for reasons ex-
plained above. Comparative shopping on the basis of price is difficult
even if fares are posted because of the number of variables which com-
prise the total price-drop, mileage. wait time, baggage. and additional
passenger charges.
Economist Alfred Kahn has observed several problems emerging
from destructive competition. including consumers having a "limited abil-
118. Jd. at 271.
119. Teal &. Berglund. supra note .t. at 3b.
I~O Foerster &. Gilben. supra note 114. at 378
111. Shreiber. supra note 90. at 82-
1::. Teal &. Berglund. supra note 4. at 50
123 DEMPSEY & GOeTZ. supra note 2. at 276
94
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
ity to judge the quality of products and hence to keep it at acceptable
levels even when they have a "ide range of competitive suppliers to
choose from. "124 Given that comparative shopping by patrons for the
best price/service combination is severely circumscribed by the absence of
a true competitive market. regulation of prices and senices can signifi-
cantl)' reduce consumer transactions costs. thereby increasing the number
and variety of taxi trips.l2'
C. E^TERI<ALlTIES.
An external effect of a transaction is the positive or negative impact
upon a person not a pany to it126 The negative externalities of taxicab
ser.ice are felt by other users of finite road and highway resources. and
the environment. Again. Professor Shreiber observes that h[tJaxicabs im-
pose various external costs. Mainly. they increase traffic congestion and
raise the level of air pollution. . . . The price of a ride in a system of free
entry "ill cover only the private cost. The social cost per ride, which
includes the externalities, \\ill necessarily exceed the price."'27
It has been argued that restrictions on entry increase efficiency by
reducing the street congestion and air pollution caused b)' an excessive
number of vehicleslo6 Garrett Hardin. i.r1 his powerful.essay, "The Trag-
edy of the Comrnor..s," provides ir:sight as to tr.e C'cono:rJc forces leading
a rational wealth maximizer to advance his 0\\11 economic interests by
externalizing his costs:
PI:t:J.!"e a p3sturc open to all. It is to be expected that each herdsman
v.i11 try to keep as many cattle as possible on the commons. Such an ar-
rangement may work reasonably satisfactorily for centuries because tribal
wars, poaching. and disease keep the numbers of both man and beast well
below the caff)ing capacity o~ the land. Finally. however. comes the day of
reckoning. that is. the day when [he Ion g.-desired goal of social stability be-
comes a reality. At this point. the inherent logic of the commons remorse-
lessly generates tragedy.
As a rational being. each herdsman seeks to maximize his gain. Explicitly or
implicitly. more or less consciously. he asks. "What is the utility to me of
adding one more animal to my herd?" This utility bas one negative and one
positive component.
(I) The positive componenl is a function of the increment of one animal.
124. AU"RED KMr-;. 11 ECO~OMICS or REGlJL^TIO~ 176 (1971).
125. Gallick &:. Sisko supra note 9. at 117. 119. 127.
126. Dempse~', supra note J. al 17.
127. Shrelber. supra note IIi. at 27-1
128.. Sa FR......~KC...^ & P,\L"TLCk. supra note 9. at 38. 42 C"fTlhe operation of taxicabs on
con~es[ed streets slo.....s dowr. other road users. increasmg their lime and money COStS of
travel."). IJ at 3,S
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregularion 95
Since the herdsman receives aU the proceeds from the sale of the additional
animal. the positive utility is neatly +1.
(2) The negative component is a function of the additional over-grazing cre-
ated by one more animal. Since, however, the effects of overgrazing are
shared by all the herdsmen, the negative utility for any particular decision-
making herdsman is only a fraction of 1.
Adding together the component partial utilities. tbe rational herdsman con-
eludes that the only sensible course for him to pursue is to add another
animal to his herd. And another. . .. [b Jut that is the conclusion reached by
each and every rational herdsman sharing a commons. Therein lies tbe trag-
edy. Each man is locked into a system that compels him to increase his herd
\\;thollt limit - in a world that is limited. Ruin is the destination toward
which all men rush, each pursuing his own best interest in a society that
believes in the freedoms of the commons. Freedom in a commons brings
ruin to all. 129
In an environment of excessive competition created by excessively
liberalized entry, the city streets are commons, the taxi companies are
herdsmen, and the taxis themselves are callie. Every additional taxi on
the street brings the taxi company additional revenue (panicularly where
driver leasing creates an intermediate market between the taxi firm and
its customers),13o although average taxi revenue will fall for all taxis as
the streets become congested v.ith more vehicles than necessary to meet
aggregate passenger demand. Since each individual taxi company has an
incentive to increase the size of its fleet beyond the collectively rational
level, according to Hardin. "[r]uin is the destination toward which all men
rush. each pursuing his own best interest in a freedom that believes in the
freedoms of the commons. "13t
As we shall see in greater detail below, excessive taxicab entry has a
negative impact in terms of industry productivity and profitability. But
Hardin's main thesis is not about the economic decline of herdsmen, but
of the negative externality of another son - pollution. He says:
In a reverse way, the tragedy of the commons reappears in problems of pol.
lution. Here it is not a qu~stion of taking ,something out of the commons.
but of putting something in. . , , The calculations of utility are much the
same as before, , , . Sinc~ this is true for everyone, we are locked into 'a
system of 'fouling our 0\\11 nests: so long as we behave only as independent,
rational. free-enterprisers. 1'::;
The pollution impact l'[ allov.ing an excessive number of underutil-
~ed automobiles on the streets for any environmentally consciol)s com-
129. Garrett Hardin. The Trar:.',;', of rhe CnrnmonJ, SCIE:'iCC. Dec. 13. 196ts. at 1243
13U Su Teal &. Berglund. st.:;:'~.l ::.ote .;. at 54.
131. Su Hardin. Jupra note !.:..:
132 Id
96
Transportation Law Joumal
[Vol. 24:73
.
.
munity is manifest. Hardin funher points out that one means of avoiding
the tragedy is by ascribing private propeny rights, or in effect, "de-com-
monizing" the commons. Licensing is one mechanism for creating such
propeny rights, for no rational herdsman will overgraze land which is his.
nor will a taxi company flood the streets within his cenificated service
territory "..ith an excessive number of vehicles.'33
Still another externality involves the impact taxi service has upon a
city's image, for the economy of a city as a whole may be adversely af-
fected by poor or highly priced transportation set\ices. The taxi is the
first and last impression a city will make on visiting tourists. convention-
eers, and businessmen. A city's hotels, restaurants, airpon, convention
and business traffic, are dependent upon ubiquitous. reasonably priced,
and efficient on-demand taxi semce134
Further, non-discriminatory pricing based on average costs can serve
a significant social objective of assuring reasonably priced semce to less
affluent passengers or more remote communities. in effect requiring
cross-subsidization by more .affluent patrons or dense markets. In re-
viewing taxi regulatory issues, the U.S. Department of Transponation has
observed, "[c]ross-subsidization, per se, is not automatically frowned
upon if designed to meet some public policy objectives. "135
D. CROSS-SUBSIDIES AND CREAM SKIMMING.
Most governmental authorities insist. by regulation or local ordi-
nance, that licensed taxis operate as "common carriers." That is, taxis are
required to provide service to low-density areas or at nonpeak times with-
out pricing discrimination (i.e.: the same distance-based fare be charged
to all on an "average cost" basis)136 Thus. dense markets cross-subsidize
low-density and impoverished areas; peak traffic cross-subsidizes off-peak
service.
Unlimited or excessive entry causes owner-operators to gravitate to
high-peak high-density traffic. predominantly at the airport and hotel
cabstands. As one source noted:
Vioen gypsy. or unlicensed, taxis siphon business and profits they se.
verely limit the profits that licensed carriers need to sustain other required
services. The possibility of opening entry to a taxi market also raises fears
that newcomers would focus on these more lucrative areas. and experience
in some cities bas validated these fcars.137
133. Su ~~nera/ly. Dempsey. supra note 3. at 17-2i.
134. GILB!!Rl & SAMUr.l..S. supra note to. at 153-4.
135. U.S. DEP'T or TRM.SP.. su.pra note 4.
136. Su Gallick &. Sisko supra note 9. at 117.
137. GtLSt!RT &. S^~n.;CL..S. su.pra note to. at 153: Su x~nually Suzuki. supra note 20. at 129
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 97
Deregulation results in some trips becoming very expensive while
others decrease in price. with the cost of service no longer averaged over
space and time. Professor James Foerster and Gorman Gilbert observed:
Persons \\-ith a low ability to pay. but a high need for transportation.
may DO longer be abie to use taxi service.
These results might occur because there will no longer be any geographic or
inter-temporal cross-subsidization. . . . The elimination of whatever cross-
subsidies now exist 'without income transfers could lead to socially undesir-
able resuJts,13S
And. as noted above. given that demand for taxi services is often
time sensitive. economic regulation can reduce the transaction costs of
comparative shopping.l3O
E. ECONOMtES OF SCALE AND SCOPE
Given the minuscule economic barriers to entry. one intuitively
would not expect there to be economies of scale in the taxicab industry.
Yet the per passenger overhead costs of marketing. advertising. dispatch-
ing. accounting. and cab maintenance generally decline as the size of the
company's fleet grows. An ability to provide ubiquitous service also sig-
nificantly enhances. the marketability of the firm's product in the radio-
dispatch market. for passengers thereby enjoy shorter waits. beller ser-
vice. and one-stop shopping. reducing customers' transaction and oppor-
tunity costs.
Economies of scope are also present in the taxicab industry. A com-
pany which dedicates its primary business to the radio-dispatch market
can easily park temporarily idle cabs in hotel and ai'1'ort queues. A taxi
company can easily dedicate capacity to the express document delivery
business.
F. THE ABSENCE OF SOUND EcosOMIC CONDITIONS.
Absent regulation. few economic barriers impede entry in the
owner-operator cruising and cabstand markets - all one needs is a
chauffeur's license and a down payment on car. An open entry regime
tends to put too many taxis on the roads when they are least needed.
thereby injuring the economic health of existing firms and their drivers.
Professor Shreiber observed:
138. Foerster & Gilben. supra note IIJ, at 3l:S5.
139. "Given that the demand b~' riders 15 general1~' for immediate service. the aggregate
search performed by riders and dri"'e~ would tend to be extremely COSIly," Gallick &. Sisko supra
note 9. at lIX: "IRJegulation can Increase the number and ,,'ariety of tax.! trips h~' reducln!! search
COStS" Jd. at 119.
98
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
In the absence of legal restrictions. the number of cabs most probably will
vary i:::l the opposite direction to general business conditions. Very little skill
is required to be a cab driver, and not much money is needed to buy or rent
a car that can be used as a cab. The absence of barriers (0 entry makes cab
operation the natural occupation to turn to for those that are unemployed.
The disadvantage of such fluctuations is that they v.ill bring abou: a larger
supply of cabs when tbere is less demand for them (i.e.. in times of recession)
and a smaller supply of cabs whcn thc demand for them rises (in times of
prosperiry). Moreover, cyclical fiuctuarions will tend to hurr those who
make cab driving their permanent job - their income will necessarily de.
cline sharply in times of recession. Restrictions arc needed to prO\ide some
income stability for these drivers. who will anVV,'3V sufier in times of reces-
sion because of the decrease in demand.140 . .
,
,
Thus, the supply of labor and equipment by the industry appears to
have an inverse relationship with the level of economic acti\;ty.141
Professor Shreiber wrote his pragmatic assessment of the economic
characteristics of the taxicab industry in 1975. He was criticized at the
time because the competitive model was not rejected on the basis of em-
piricaltesting.l42 Yet, as we shall see, the empirical results of deregula-
tion confirm. rather than reject, Professor Shreiber's analysis.
Professors Lester Telser of the University of Chicago and William
Sjostrom of the University College Cork have argued that various modes
of transport are subject to core theory, which '.really amounts to saying
that competition just isn't possible in some industries. . . ."143 Core the-
ory emerged from game theory. 2nd as we shal! see, offers a fascinating
insight into the question of why the taxicab market fails to perform the
way one would expect under neo-c1assical economic theory.
Game theory is broken down into two general types of '.games". or
market en\;ronments - cooperative. and non-cooperative. The former
are those in which the players (buyers and sellers in a market environ-
ment) can communicate and fonn coalitions so as to best meet their indi-
vidual needs. Players make decisions as to which coalition they should
enter based on individual needs: any large-scale benefit which arises for
the players is simply a by-product. In non-cooperative '.games:. (such as
the infamous "prisoner's dilemma") players are unable to communicate,
and therefore any decisions made are not based on mutuality.144
140. Shreiber. supra note 117. at 275-76
141. Williams. supra note 5. at 36.
142. RIchard Coffman. supra note 116. at 290.
143. Timothy Smith. Why AIr Travd DMsn', Work. FORn;~c. Apr. 3. 1995. at 41. 46: Su
Wilham SjOStrom. Anlltrust Immunuy for S;llppln~ Conf~r~nces: An Emptv Cor~ Approach. 8
Al'o'TITRUST Sew- 19 (1993): William Sjostrom. Price DUCflmtnauon by 5htpptn~ Confaences.
LoGISTICS.& TRA~sP. REv. 207 (1992)
lJ~. Set ROBCRT AxeLROD TltE EVO:..t:TIO__ or COOPCRATlO'" (}9:-\.1)
1996] Taxi lndusrry' Regularion, Deregulation & Reregularion 99
Core theor)' is a subset of cooperative game theor)'; a core is formed
when the coalitions are aligned in such a way that no player can advance
his needs by defecting to another coalition or operate on his own. By
contrast, an empty core arises when players can continuously form new
coalitions which bring better players. Whether a core exists or not de-
pends on the number of players in the game, and the market environ-
ment, or rules of the game.
Several economists have described various alternatives for which a
taxi trip reflects an empty core.'45 Professor John Shepard Wiley, Jr.,
proffers an illustration of a market with an empt}' core:
,
,
For exarnple. say that three strangers are \\illing to pay up to $7 each for a
cab to the airport. Two cabs stop nearby. Each cab can carry one or two
passengers. and each driver is willing to make the trip (with either one or
two passengers) for a minimum of $6. Given these demands and costs, the
worst-off or excluded player can block any arrangement by tempting some
players to abandon others fa; a more attractive arrangement. Suppose: for
instance passengers A and B force driver X do\\'D to her minimlL"TI $6 total
fare. thus };elding. for A and B a fare of S3 each. As a result, passenger C is
stuck pa)i.ng at least 56 to travel alone with driver Y. But driver X could
gain an added S2 by dumping B and offering C a ride for S5-which C
should accept becC'.use 2. S5 fare is cheaper than a 56 fare. This new coalition
between X. A and C however. is vulnerable in turn to raiding by the ex-
cluded players. Y and B. Now passenger B faces a tnp alone y,;th driver Y
at a fare of at least 56. and both v.il1 improve their lots if they attract passen-
ger C v.ith a S4 fare offer. which Y and B split between themselves and
which C will prefer to the 55 that C pays as a member of the existing X-A-C
coalition. TIlls coalition instability occurs for every possible cOr.1bination of
players.146
As Professor Abagail McWilliams points out. an empt}' core exists
when each and every coalition can be outbid by a rival coalition, so that
the market cannot achieve stability; quantity and price fluctuate con-
stantly.'47 With an empty core, the market tinds itself mired in unsatis-
factory results, unable to achieve competitive- equilibrium. Another
source summarized this illustration of dysfunctional economics more
succinctly:
Imagine, for instance. a market in which a taxi holds two people. and only
two. Three people are waiting at a taxi stand. bound for the same destina-
tion. and two taxis show up. How much does it costs a taxi to make the trip
145. Sa e.g., George Biulingmayer. Decreasing Avaogf' COSI and CompellllOn: A Nf'w Look
a: the Add.\'ston Pipf' Case. 25 J.L & Eco:s. 57. XI-82 (1983).
140. John Shepard Wiley. h. Anmru.it and Corf' TJuory. 54 U. CIll. L. Rev. 556.560-61
(1987).
1.t7. Sa Abagail McWilliams. R,thmklnf Hon:.onral Market ReStrlctions In Defense of Co.
opaaltor. in Empn' Corf' Markw. 0 R(\'. Eco.... & BL':). 3 (1990)
100
Transportation La... Journal
[Yol. 24:73
doesn't depend on the Dumber of passengers. One taxi driver can try to
make the same amount of revenue by offering the third passenger a (are of
S20, but tbat passenger \\illlikely take a bus or not travel at all. rather than
pay that much. So the second driver tries to upset the first driver's arrange-
ment. undercutting his fare for (wo passengers. You can see what happens:
Any price agreement struck by i1 coalition of two passengers and one taxi
can be upset by a slightly bener offer from the other taxi (or the other pas-
senger). cascading until it is no longer profitable 10 operate one of the
taxis,l':S
Professor Telser found six prerequisites for an empty core: (1) de-
mand is unceI1ain or periodic; (2) plant capacities are large relative to
demand; (3) plants exhibit increasing returns to scale; (4) plants have
fixed capacities; (5) there are avoidable fixed costs; and (6) it is costly to
store the product.'40 Several modes of transpoI1 exhibit these character-
istics including. as noted from the hypotheticals. unregulated taxicabs.
The remedy advanced by Telser is that some measure of cooperation be
allowed to producers in these markets. although such intra-industry collu-
sion would be antitheticalta contemporary antitrust notions.
Of course. a long-recognized alternative remedy ta destructive com-
petition has been economic regulation. which allows the market to stabi-
lize along a more satisfactory axis.
VI. BIPOLAR VIEWS ON REGULATION AND DEREGULATION
UnfoI1unately. much of the political debate over whether taxicabs
(and. indeed. any other mode of transpoI1ation) should be regulated or
deregulated has become highly ideological and polarized. The propo-
nents and opponents of deregulated entry ha\'e two vastly different \~ews
of what such a change in regulatory policy would produce. ISO
14,S. Smith. supra note: 143, at 45~6.
149. L~STER TCl.SCR. ECO~01\.lIC THEORY ^....o THe CORe (University of Chicago Press
1971:)); COMPCTIT10.... COLLLiSION 1\....0 GAME TlIEORY (Aldine and Athenan. 1972): Coopera-
tion. Comptrirwr.. and Efficitnn. 18 J.L. & Eco:>o;, 271 (1985):
150. Some proponents of regulation of have urged that entry controls arc: necessary to:
Ensure taxicab owners a saw~factor)' Income:
Ensure: the finanCial responsibility of laxic;Jb owners;
Prevent traffic con'l!:c:stion;
Protect mass transtt systems: and
Avoid destructive competltlon among. taxi Q\o\'TlC:rs and operators:
Edmund Kitch. c:t al.. Tht Rtguloflon of Tazicabs in Chico?o. 14 J.L. & Ecos. 285.321.25 (19711.
L~.s. DOT LiRB"... MASS TRANS!'. AD....f!.'.. TIII:. ApPUC^TIO~ OF Till: FI::DI::R^L A~TITRtJS'1
LN.."..S TO ML'.....CIP^L T^X1CAU R(;ca;LATlo!'O 32 (1983) .
Opponents of re~ulatlon have ar~ued that these limitations
Increase taxicab fares;
Unfairl~' llmi: competHlon: and
Raise re~ulator:'- costs
L'.$. DOT LRD^'" ,\1^ss TRA",sr' '\D"1Io,; . supra. al 32
1996] Ta~:i Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregular/on 101
Proponents of deregulation argued that eliminating pricing and entry
regulation of the taxicab industry would lower prices. improve sen'ice.
and prO\'ide a wider variety of price and sen'ice options dictated by con-
sumer demand. thereby fostering efficient resource allocation.l5l As one
source observed, "the argument is ohen made solely on ideological
grounds: the competitive free market in search of profit ,,'ill always pro-
\'ide better and more efficient sen'ices, "'52 More specifically. it has been
alleged that deregulation would:
Produce more taxi senice and faster response times;
Create service innovations and sen;ce expansion to poorly served
neighborhoods;
Lower fares: and
Reduce government costs by eliminating oversight of pricing, ser.;cc and
entry. IS)
Most of these predictions have been based on free market economic
theory which has driven much of deregulation in transponation since the
. late-I970s, insisting that government creates distonions which thwan
.
market incentives for producti\'ity. efficiency. and lower consumer
prices!S< Unfonunately. as we have seen. the taxi industry fails to reflect
the perfect competition model described in micro-economic textbooks.
Professor Roger Teal, who has written extensively on the subject of taxi-
cab deregulation. offered an explanation for the wide divergence between
free market predictions of what deregulation should produce, and the
empirical reality of what it actually has produced:
The emphasis placed by L'ldustrial organization principles on ac[uaJ condi-
tions in l:larkets (a..,d on the distortions which monopoly power crcares in
real-world markets) proves more useful than simple micro-economic theory
15J "Students oi economIcs and urban transportation frequently cite the limitatlon on the
number of taxicabs in most American cities as a clear case of unwise government poltcy. They
aq:ue thaI a limitation on the number of cabs can only operate to raise the pnce and decrease
the supply oi taxicab semce as compared to that which would othen\1se be providec" KITCII.
CT AL.. supra note 150. al 285. ("The au:hors of this anicle share the academIC Vlev. nJ Id. Su
also ROGCR TCAL & l\'IARY BJ:RGLl::"OD. EXPLAINI....G TIIJ: J."1PACTS or TAXICAB Dr:.R(<.il:LATlO'
II'--' l'lIr:. USA:: (1986); ROGER TEAL. El AL.. UKUI\I'--' TRA"'SPORTATIO.-.; DCR..EGL"LATIO>'; I": ARI.
ZO"'A 26 (1983): GILBERT & SAMLTCLS. supra note 10. at 146.
152 Rosenbloom, supra note 13.
153. FRI\NKCNA &:. PAL'TLER. supra note Y. at 75: PRICE \VATERIIOlJSE. A"'ALYSIS OF TAXI-
CAB DERcGVLATlO~ AND RE.RCGL"LATIO-"; I. 6 (19QJl: Teal & Ber!!lund. supra not~~. at 39. In
Contrast. opponents of derep:ulation contend that deregulation Ylill:
Result In poorer service:
Reduce safety:
Produce less accountability: anc
Proc'-lce less reiiabiillY.
PRier: W.'\TE::RllOl:Sr:.. supra at I
15~. See, e.g. PAL.L DEMPSCY. TIlt SOCIAL &.: Eco-,;o,"IlC CO:"-;SJ:OL'C:-;CCS or DCRCGl:L\
TlO.' (1989): Dc.\-1PSCY & GOCTZ. supra nOlt: 2: p,u L DC..1PSCY. C1 AL.. supra note 1
102
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
for analyzing the impacts of taxicab deregulation. Simple models of compet.
itive behavior involving atomistic producers selling to completely-informed
consumers are often used. but tbese theoretical generalizatioDs of ideal types
provide no useful or interesting explanations for the results observed in tbe
dominant tau markets - telephone orders and cabstands.1S5
Similarly. Sandra Rosenbloom. a scholar whose earlier literature em-
braced the unregulated free market position on this subject. concludes:
Unfortunately, an examination of empirical data on regulatory reform of the
taxi industry to date shows few of the benefits claimed by proponents.
IMJoSl anticipated economiC outcomes did not materialize. The irony is that
free-market private taxis simply don't act like entrepreneurs in a free
market.156
,
,
VII. EMPtRICAL RESULTS OF OPEN ENTRY ,:< THE
TAXICAB INDUSTRY
Yet we need not rely on the theoretical assumptions of what unlim-
ited entry "ill produce. We have empirical results which we can assess to
detennine what deregulation of the taxicab industry has produced.
Before 1983. some twenty-one cities deregulated taxicabs in whole or
part.l57
The eXperiences of these cities reveal that taxicab deregulation reo
suited in:
1. A significant increase in new entry;
2. A decline in operational efficiency and producthity;
3. An increase in highway congestion. energy consumption and environmen-
tal pollution:
4. An increase in rates;
5. A decline in driver income;
6. A deterioration in service: and
7. Little or no improvement in administrative costs.
Let us examine each of these results.
A. ENTRY
Deregulation proponents were correct in their predictions that re-
moving entry restrictions would result in increased entry into the indus-
try. Because of the low cost of entry into the taxicab business (i.e.. a
driver's license. and a dO\\TI payment on an automobile ).IS. deregulation
155. Teal & Berglund. supra note: 4. a: 4; [citation omlUed. a:1d the Kihg's English spdlmg
employee in the angmal)
150 Rosenbloom. supra nOte 13
157 L'S DeP'T OF TR^'sr.. supra nOle 6. at III
15S. Shrelber. supra nOle ] \'7, at 275
1996J Ta.xi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 103
.
.
produced a sharp increase in the number of new taxis on the road, rising
an average of 23 % in the deregulated cities, 1S9 In Phoenix, the number
of taxis in active service increased by more than 50% in the first year of
deregulation.l60 In Atlanta, which deregulated in 1965, the number of
vehicles more than doubled, from approximately 700 before deregulation,
to 1,900 in 1970.161
Most new entrants were independent ovmer/operators or small firms,
who concentrated their taxis at cab stands at hotels and airports, venues
which already were well served prior to deregulation.'62 Hotels and air-
ports guarantee a patron if the driver is ....'illing to wait at the increasingly
lengthy queues.163 A driver need not invest in a radio dispatch system to
serve hotels and airports.
The cabstand market quickly became saturated. forcing the estab.
lished companies to focus on the radio dispatch telephone order market,
which has relatively higher entry costs in terms of dispatching equipment,
facilities and personnel, and requires a sufficiently large /leet to provide
city-wide service. I"" Thus, the deregulated taxi industry divided into two
sub.industries-a large number of independent owner-operators serving
the cab stands, and a small number of larger companies focusing on the
159. PRICE WATERHOUSE, supra note 153. a: 11. Su also PARATRA....SIT Sr.RVICr;:S. be., THe
EXPERJENCES OF U.S. CmES WITII TAXICAB OPEN E:"'TRY 29 (1983); U.S. DCP'T or TRANSP..
TAX: REGULA.TORY REVISIO~' ~ OA~ND AND BERKELEY, C\.LIFORNIA 49 (1983)
("fUJnchecked gro\lrlh could eventually lead to incrcasec financial difficulties for the
companies. ").
160. U.S. DEP'T OF TRANSP., URBAN TRANSPORTATION DERI:.GL'LATlON IN ARIZONA VII
(19~): ROGER TEAL. E1' AL.. URDAN TRA",SPORTATION DEREGUL^"IO:-'; IN ARIZONA S (1983).
161. FRANKEN A & PA'-''TUR, supra note 9. at 144: ML.'LTIPUCA1'IO:-:S. be.. DECO~IROL A:-:O
RCCO.....TROL: ATLANTA'S EXPERIENCE: WITIl TAXI REGL.'1..J\1'IO:'o I (1982) (Prepared for the In.
ternational Taxicab Association). The follo\.\in~ chan pro\ides data on the number of ta)l(j per-
mits in selected cities before and after entry deregulation:
T AXICAn PERMITS BI::FORE A:-:O AFTI::R OPI::S E:'oTR)
Cit~. Before After
Atlanta 7(X' (1965' 1.53X (19831
Fresno 7U (1979) 45 (1983)
Indianapolis 502 (1972) 466 (1974)
Milwaukee 308 (1979) 3S1 (1983)
Phoenix. 300 (1981) 425 (1983)
Sacramento 110 (19S2) 16,' (1983)
San Diego 4091197RI 91S (1983)
Seattle 12Y (1979) 230 (1983)
Spokane I()() (19SOJ RO (1983)
FR,\:'o[o;,C:">A &. P"CTLCR, supra nOle Y. at 1~~
162, TL,\L & BERGLl:!';1). supra note 151. at oS: PAKA1KA:,,>sn SERVICE:s.l:-oc.. supra note ISY,
at ..13
163 Su Teal & Berglund. supra note .:. at .W
I~ TCAL & BERGLL":'oO. supra note 151. at Z~
104
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
telephone order market.'65
Because the oversaturation of the market caused inadequate profit-
ability (resulting from more taxis serving the same, or a declining.
number of patrons), taxi companies have suffered a very high turnover
rate.1OO For example. 40% of the new taxi companies serving the Phoenix
airpon failed during the first fifteen months of deregulation.167 Within
eighteen months of an entry moratorium in San Diego. a third of taxi
firms not affiliated with the two largest companies left the industl)',16s
Nonetheless. a large number of potential entrants are ignorant of
marketing conditions. and/or willing to accept subsistence earnings in or-
der to be self-employed.'69 Entering the taxi business is one of the few
opponunities for self-employment by indi,iduals \\ith minimum skills
and little capital.170 Inadequate profitability has also dissuaded invest-
ment in large taxi firms. so that most of the new entry has been at the
owner-operator level. again, satiating an oversaturated cabstand market.
Except in Phoenix, in the fully deregulated cities. no new taxi companies
have emerged with more than twenty-five cabs.'7!
Deregulation produced relatively small structural changes in the ra-
dio dispatch segment of the industl)'. reflecting the relatively higher entry
costs associated \\ith the purchase of radio equipment. dispatch person-
165 Id. a. 30.
166 Id. at 28-29.
167 Id. at 9; TEAL & BERGLL':"'O, supra nOle 151. at':l
168 TEAL &. BERGLUSD, supra note 151. at 41.
16<; Teal &. Berglund, supra note 4. at 29: G1LnE::RI l:. S''-''!L'CLS. supra nOle 10, at 149
170. Tne taxicab business. however. docs have its risks. According to a repon by the Na.
tionallnst:tute for Occupational SafelY and Health. cab cr:.\'ers ha'/e the highest homicide victim
rale among several professions. As the below chart shows. the fate is almost four urnes thaI of
pollee officers a~c almost twenty times th~ rate for firefig.hters.
"
Rate per l00JXIO .....orke~
21.7
!O7
61
54
55
3.5
3.3
0.1
2.3
:!.J
2.0
2.0
17
1.5
lJ
Occupation
TaXicab dnver-chaffeur
Sherifi-bailiff
Police anc deteclive
Gas statlor.. 2,ara2e worker
Secumy gua;d ~
Stock handler. bagger
Supervisor. proprietor-sales
Sales counter clerk
Baitender
Logging
Hotel Clerk
Salesperson. vehIcles
Salesperson. other
Butd:er. mea,CUlter
Firefighter
/';umber of Homicides
1.:0
36
86
II,
95
372
183
20
6
6
Ii
73
12
X
Laura .'-tedder. Jon Risks High {or Cahbl~s. Roc,"" 1\-11... l"t.....:.. July 9. lQ46. at 20A.
i'7j TeAL & BCRGLI"D. 5IInra note 151. al I'i
.
.
19%] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulalion 105
nel. marketing. and a fleet sufficiently large to pro\ide ubiquitous city-
wide service where there may be "economies of scope."l72 Thus. in most
cities in which entry has been deregulated. the large incumbent firms still
dominate the industry. although their market share has declined as the
new entrants have swarmed to dominate the cabstand markets.'73
The robust entry of new firms and entrepreneurs into the taxi indus-
try. accurately predicted by deregulation proponents. has been among the
most significant impediments to the achievement of consumer benefits
predicted to result from deregulation:
Low entT)' costs. an inherent characteristic of a totally deregulated
taxi industry. represent the factor which is probably of greatest signifi-
cance in preventing a more successful outcome to taxi deregulation. Be-
cause capital requirements to enter the deregulated industry are minimal.
vinually any self-motivated individual can become a taxi operator. Indi-
vidual operators cannot effectively compete in the telephone order mar-
ket. however. so they quickly oversubscribe the airport and cabstand
markets. causing full-service companies to abandon these markets except
for passenger drop-offs. TItis results in a reduction in economies of scope
for the full-service operators. \Vith demand for taxi service stagnant or
even declining, operator productivity inevitably declines with many more
operators in the market."4
B. OPERATIl"G EFFICIEl"CY AND PRODUCtIVITY.
Putting more taxis on the streets rarely produces more patrons. In
fact. most deregulated cities have faced stable or declining demand as
measured by the number of daily trips per cab or the trips per shift'75
Passenger demand declined significantly in the deregulated ciIies. falling
for example. 34% in Phoenix. 37% in San Diego, and 48% in Seattle.'7h
This is not at all surprising. given the higher prices and deteriorating
172. Teal & Berglund. supra note 4. at 49.
173. 1d. at 40. 47.
174. Roca::R TeAL. A.-.,; OVI:.RV113W or TilE; AMER1CA:-; EX'l'i:RII:.""CC WillI TAXI DI;RCCiLJL.A
TlO:-- 14 (1989).
175. P^R^TRA~SIT Si:RVICt:.S. he.. supra note 159. at 29. 33: TCAL & Br::RGLL'~D. su.pra note
151. at 16.27: TE.AL. ET AL.. supra note 151. at 13.
176. b.,.'L TAXICAB ASS'N, Docs TAxlcAn Dt:RI:.CCLATIO", MAKE SC!'ISC: l) (19~l. "By
any measure. the productlvlty of the Phoenix taxi industry has declined significantly since dereg-
ulauon. ITjhe number of passeng:er tnps per active taxi per day has declined,py about one-
thire for the ent;:e Indus:ry. while the number of trips pc:: shIft has decreased h.v one-Quane:
(the difference re!1ects lower utilizatIOn of taus h~' operators after derej!ulauon." Tc^L. Cl ^L..
supra nme 151. at 13-1J Ir: San DIego, the number of vehicles Increased by 30~u, whtit: each
vehIcle pro\'ldt::d onl~ 85%. as much ser\"lce per dJ~, In Seattle. deregulatIon produced more
than a 50~o Increase in the number of laXIS. but each vehicle w~s providmg: only 76~o as much
service. Staila:1s. supra note i. a: 5
106
Transporrarion Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
,
,
levels of service deregulation produced.l77
After deregulation, taxi productivity, measured by the number of
revenue trips per day or trips per shift, fell by at least one-third.178 As
Professor Teal observed, "The decline in taxi productivity after deregula-
tion is a natural consequence of an increase in the number of vehicles in
the industry. stable or declining taxi demand, and the lack of productiv-
ity-enhancing service innovations such as shared-ride taxi services. "179
Putting more taxis on the roads merely increases the number of
empty taxis and the length of the queues at the taxi stands.180 As noted
above, new entrants tend not to have radio dispatch equipment and gravi-
tate toward the already well served hotel and airport cabstands. compet-
ing for a constant or decreasing number of passengers.'"' As one source
observed, "When transportation demand is stable or declining and attrac-
tive substitutes to the deregulated modes exist. the impacts of deregula-
tion may be largely confined to increased competition within existing
industries with few or no corollary benefits to consumers and
providers. "IB2
That source went on to point out that. "Opportunities for productiv-
ity improvements in urban common carriage transportation are highly
limited by the basic economics of the industries inasmuch as costs for
most factor inputs can hardly be reduced. "IB' The one variable cost in
which there is some play is driver wages. which. as we shall see. have
plummeted (although not enough to offset the steep drop in driver pro-
ducti\ity caused by unlimited entry).
C. HIGHWAY CO:<GESTIO:<. ENERGY CO:<SUMPTIO:< &
Er<VIROr<MENTAL POLLUTIOS
Putting more. and emptier. cabs on the streets not only increases
highway congestion and wear and tear on the asphalt, it burns more gaso-
line and produces more carbon monoxide. ozone. and other pollutants.
For example. after Atlanta deregulated. 300-400 taxis lined up at airport
queues: waits of three to four hours were not uncommon. and waits of up
to six hours were reported.'''''
Given the Damocles Sword contained in federal Clean Air Act
177. GORM^l'O GIUJCRT. Ef"l'"ECT OF Op!:!": ESTRY AND VARIABl.e FARES 0... TIll::: COST OF
TAXICAB Sr;:RVlCr: TO RESlDE.....,.IAL AREAS 2 (1984).
178. Teal & Berglund. supra note 4, at 46.
17Q, ld. at 52,
ISO. Sa FRA"'KC""^ & PAL:TLCR. supra note 9. at X
18!. G:LBERT. SIJpra note li7. at 2.
182. TEAL. ET A1... supra note 15t. al 2'7
IR3. Id. at 13-1~
l~ ~1l'LTlrLlCATto"S. he, SUf1ra note 161. at 32. 37
.
.
1996] Taxi Industry. Regularion, Deregularion & Reregularion 107
Amendments of 1990. threatening draconian cuts in federal money for
states and communities which fail to meet the carbon monoxide, ozone,
paniculate and other pollutant standards, the problems of adding more,
but emptier, vehicles to city streets should be manifest. Thiny-two of the
thiny-five .busiest airpom in the United States are located in metropoli-
tan areas which have been designated non attainment for ozone and car-
bon monoxide. IS' The two means of transpon responsible for the most
vehicle miles traveled to airports, automobiles and taxis, are also the most
significant sources of pollution. ISo
D. PRICE
One would expect that excess capacity would drive prices down. as it
allegedly has. for example, in the deregulated airline industry.!R7 Para-
doxically, precisely the opposite has occurred in the deregulated taxi in.
dustry'. As Price Waterhouse observed, "prices rose following taxi
deregulation in every documented case. "1S8
Professor Roger Teal of the University of California studied pricing
at nine cities which deregulated (i.e.. Fresno, Kansas City. Oakland.
Phoenix. Sacramento, San Diego, Seattle. Tacoma. and Tucson). He con-
cluded. "In every city in this study taxi rates are now higher in real terms
than before deregulation. often by a substantial amount. "IR. Before de-
regulation, in none of these cities did rates rise as rapidly as the Con-
sumer Price Index [CPI]; after deregulation. price increases exceeded the
CPI in each of these cities.l90 Professor Teal concludes, "taxi rates may
have increased as much as 10 per cent more in the deregulated cities than
they would have done under continued regulation,"!.!
At San Diego. Seattle and Ponland. prices increased 35% during the
first 18-24 months of deregulation.!" One source summarized the results
185. Annalynn Lacombe. Ground Access to Airpom" Prospects for IntumodaiLsm. 48
TRANSP. Q. 381. 383 (1994).
186. Su ,d. at 383-84.
187. DI::MPSEY &: GOETZ. supra note 3. Actually. estimates of consumer savmgs resultmg
from airline deregulation have been grossly overstated. Jd. at 243-63. 281.95.
188. PRICE W ATERHOUSr.. supra note 153, at H.
189. Teal &: Berglund. supra note 4, at 37. 4:!. This contlnns his earlier research on the expe-
rience of deregulation in seven U.S. cities. TEAL & BEROLt.:SD, supra note 151. at 11. "The
imponan! policy lesson to be learned tram the Arizona e:ltpenence is that tavorable impacts do
not necessarily tallow the removal of institutional bame~ 10 competition in the transponation
industries." TeAL ET AL. supra note 160, at 27.
190. Teal &:. Berglund. supra note 4. at 37. 42: TCAL &:. BERGl.USO. supra note'IS!. <It 14-15
191. Teal & Berglund. supra note 4. at 37. 4..:
192. PAT GCLD, EARl.Y RcsPO:"sI:S TO TAXI RCCL'LATORY CIIAf"GCS 16 (19tH); S.B COL
MAS. Rr;;:cc~-r Dc.vc.LoPMcsTs I:" Tile RI:VISIO-'; or TAXI RI:GL:LATiOss ''''' SCA1TLI: A"D SA~
DII:co. TRAssP. RES. Rcc. 20 (19PoO): S~~ Paratransit Ser\'lces, Inc.. supra note 15Y, at 34 Pnces
rose 600,;, in San Diego. Stalians. supra not~ 7. at 1. Address belare the 5Uth Annual Cor:ventlon
108
Transponarion La... Journal
[Vol. 24:73
.
.
of higher taxi fares in Seattle: "[t]he high fares led to a large number of
cabs, long cab lines, refusals to serve short trips. and quarrels among driv-
ers concerning positions in the taxi queue, but did not lead to an above-
normal profit because of free entry."..3
Cabstand rate increases were even more pronounced.'.4 This is be-
cause there is, and can be, little comparative shopping at the cabstand
because of the formal and informal pressure patrons feel to take the next
taxi in the queue under the "first in. first out" rule.'.5 Because of the
overcapacity created by unlimited entry. queues lengthen, discouraging
drivers from competing on the basis of price.1OO Therefore, there is little
cffective competition. In an economic environment of declining produc-
tivity created by excessive entry and stable or declining demand, taxi op-
erators can survive only if they can increase the revenue derived from
each trip, which places upward pressure on taxi fares.'.7
Moreover, airport travelers and hotel patrons are frequently tourists
or out-of-town businessmen v,ith little information about local taxicab
regulatory practices or rates, and whose travel expcnses are often paid by
a third party v,ith pre-tax dollars.19R Further, some of the economics
literature reveals that much of passenger demand for taxi service is rela-
tively inelastic v,ith respect to fare changes.''''' Thus, most passengers
who need a taxi pay the rate. even if inflated.
One source described the impact of price increases on low-income
individuals:
Tne increase in taxicab fares in residential areas produces a particularly
bitter impact on low-income persons. A major and increasing proportion of
residential taxicab business originates in low-income or minority neighbor-
hoods. . . .[tJhis is not surprising since residents in these areas arc often de.
pendent on taxicab service for mobility. These trips are for essential
purposes. such as trips to grocery stores and medical facilities. In contrast,
the trips from airports and dO\\'l1tov,n hotel stands are made by persons who
are clearly more affluent businesspersons. \'acationcrs. and com,'entioneers.
of the f';ew Zealand Taxi Proprietors' Federation. \Vclhngton. f';ew Zealand. Aug. 3U. 19~. An.
other study found that partial deregulation produced no pnce or service innovations of signifi.
cance in Portland. while administrative costs increased. Su U.S. DOT URUM" MASS TRANSP.
AOMIS.. TAXI Rt::GULATORY Rt::VIS10N IN PORn.AND. OREGON: A CASC STUDY (1982).
193. FRANKENA &. PAI..'TLCR. supra note '). at 12').
194. TEAL & BERGLUND. supra note 151. at 16.
195. Gelb. supra note 192. at 17; TCAL &. BERGLUND. supra note 151. at 5. 23-4 (1986); TEAL.
CT AL. supra note 160. at 8.
196. PRICC WATERHouse. supra note 153. al 8: TCAL. Cl AL. supra note 160. at 24
197, h,'L TAXICAB Ass':-;. supra nOte 176. at 5.
198. Su U.S. Dep'T OF TRANS!'.. TAX] RCGULATORY RCV1SIO~ IN SA'~: DIEGO. CALlT'ORNIA
102 (1981)
199. FREDERJC FRAVI:L &. GORMA.'o; GILliERT. FAR.I: ELASTIC1TICS FOR EXCLUSIVE-RIDE
T A'" SERVICES (U.S. DOT. 1971\); Te<lJ &. Berglund. supra note 4. 011 50
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 109
Increasing fares to residential areas means that the impact of more taxicabs
is borne disproportionately by low-income persons. In other words. those
who can least afford /0 pay would be charged the most. . . .
Those who Collow the academic argument of "letting the market decide" tax-
icab fares are reatly "letting. the poor pay more. ,,200
.
.
Neither did deregulation result in lower fares in the telephone dis-
patch markets, and it appears to be correlated with somewhat higher
prices.20! This occurred because of the loss of cabstand business to new
entrants, and the resultant loss of economies of scope associated
therewith.
Even the local patron may refrain from price shopping. Forty per-
cent of all resident users take a taxi trip one or fewer times a month.202
Patrons employing taxi services so infrequently have linle incentive to
take the time to engage in comparative price shopping.20) Of course,
higher prices may force some low-income riders either to reduce the
number of their taxi trips, or decline spending their limited money
purchasing other necessities. as much taxi demand appears to be price
inelastic.2'"
Deregulated cities experienced growing complaints of price gouging
and overcharging, particularly at the cabstands,>05 A study of pricing in
Washington, D.C., in June, 1985, which then had open entry and more
taxi cabs per capita than any other city in the nation,206 revealed that taxi
drivers overcharge their patrons 36% of the time, and the average over-
charge was 22%.207 In Seanle, overcharging of up to 50% above the av-
erage fare was l'eponed208
Finns which have lowered prices generally have not stimulated lower
price responses by competitors, nor have their market shares appreciably
200. GORMA!'O GU.BIZRT, EFFECT or OPI:!'.' ENTRY AND VARJA1H..E FARES ON TIle CoST or
TAXICAB SERVlCE TO RE.sIDIZ:-O"TIAL AREAS 6-7 (1984) !emphasis in originalj.
201. Teal & Berglund. supra note 4. at 44: Ti:AL &. BERGLUND. supra note 151. at 15.
202. /d. at 23.
203. Teal & Berglund. supra note 4. at 50.
204. /d.
205. See PARATRA....SIT SE;RVICES. I!';c.. supra note 159. at 10.
206. One study performed in 1970 reViewed taxi entry re!!ulation by 30 cities with a popula-
tion of 325.000 or more. I: revealed that the number of licenses varied from 0.2 in Phoenix to
11.3 in Washington. D.C. (which had no entry restrictions). and that the number or licenses per
square mile ranged from 0.4 in Phoenix to 139.3 in Washington. D.C.: Utterback. A Summar;.' of
Recent Taxicab Studies 12 (City of Milwaukee. Legislative R~ference Bureau. 1975) i1l U.S. DOT
URBAN MASS TRANSP. ADMl:",. TilE ApPUCAT!o:" or THE F~D~RAL AsnTRL.'Sl L~WlO TO !'ok.
NICIPAL TAXICAB REGl:LATJO!'; 31. r..31 (1983).
207. Sheldon Shane. Callfn~ All Cabs, TKAVcL-HoLlDAY MAGAZl!';[! 46 (Feb. 1985): PARA
fRANSrr SERVICES. INC.. TH!: QUALITY OF RCSID!:!"'TIAL TAXICAD SeRVice '''' WASIIIl"GTO,-';.
D.C. 19 (1985).
208. GELB. supra nOle 192, at IS
110
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
increased.209
We have explored several reasons why excessive capacity in the taxi-
cab industry has not resulted in lower fares, as we would intuitively ex-
pect. Professor Roger Teal has succinctly summarized three supply
factors and four demand factors which militate against lower fares. The
supply factors are:
"Monopoly" profits earned under regulation were significantly less than
estimated:
Deregulation did Dot create a competiti....e industry structure in the tele-
phone order marker: and
There is no apparent cost basis v,.;th on which 10 predicate price
rcductions.ZlO
On the demand side. Professor Teal offered these explanations:
.
.
Demand for taxi service is characterized by imperfect information and
. strong name recognition;
The demand for taxi senice may be inelastic:
Per capita demand for taxi service is either stable or suffering from long-
term decline: and
Leasing panially insulates taxi firms from the passenger market.211
E. INCOME
In the deregulated cities. driver income decreased despite higher
fares. The fare increases imposed by taxis under deregulation have not
offset the sharp decline in productivity (the reduction of revenue trips per
day) caused by excessive en!!)..2"
The shift from employee drivers to owner-operator or lease drivers
results in a loss of minimum wage guarantees for taxi drivers.2l' Most
taxi drivers in deregulated cities earned less (often despite spending more
hours behind the wheel) than before deregulation.2l4
For example. under deregulation in Phoenix, drivers worked an aver-
age of 10-14 hours per day. six days a week. earning only about $2.00-
$4.00 per houL'" In San Diego. driver wages declined 30% from pre-
209. Teal & Ber~lund. supra nore 4, at 44.
210. [d.
211. Id. at 37, 48.
212. Su TEAL. ET AL... suprQ note 160. at 14: ROGER TEAL. T AXJCAB REGULATORY C11^"'Gt:
I!'o< SAN DIEGO. TAXICAB MANAGEME!N"[ 2~. 32 (Fall 1986): Teal &:. Berglund. supra nOle 4, a146.
213. Teal &. Berglund. supra note ~. al 46.
214. rAT GC:UL EFF[;Cl'S OF TAXI Rt!.Gt.:LATORY REVlSI0~ I~ S^~ DfE(,;o. CAUFORNt^
(u.s. Dep't of Transp.. 1983): PAl GeLD. Ef"'FLcrs or TAXI Rt:GULATORY Rr:;VISIOS I:'" SEATTLe..
WAHlISOTOS, (U.S. Dep't of Transp.. 1983): Tr::^L & BC;:RGLlJND. supra note 151 (unpublished
manuscript). at 17.1 It Teal &. Ber~lund. supra note 4. af 46
215. TEAL. El AL.. supra not~ 160. at 1J
.
.
1996] Taxi Indusrry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 111
deregulation levels, to only S135 a week.21. Such poor pay is for a job
which has the highest homicide rate of any profession.217
F. SERVICE
As we have seen, most of the new entry unleashed by deregulation
has been by small companies in the airpon and hotel cabstand market -
a market traditionally well served-in effect. "cream skimming" the least
costly market. The telephone dispatch market, upon which most local
residents rely, is generally left ";th the same, or poorer (and more highly
priced), service as before, since taxis in the larger firms are now dis-
suaded from entering the end of a longer queue at the cabstand market,
and forced to focus on the higher-cost radio dispatch market. The radio
dispatch firms have lost between 10% .to 25 % of their business because of
the need to abandon the cabstand markets. which were the least expen-
sive markets to serve (for it requires neither dispatching operations nor
equipment dead heading).218
As we have seen. excessive entry leads to declining productivity, and
because fare increases failed to keep pace. declining profitability. A car-
rier facing profit erosion can reduce costs by "lowering the quality of taxi
services (for example. employing a small or deteriorated vehicle, reducing
insurance coverl!ge, or driving recklessly)."219 Not only has deregulation
generated little service innovation,22O it is not unusual to see several ser-
vice problems arise when the regulatory system collapses, including:
Excessive fares:
Circuitous routing: and
Refused senice.221
Most cities which deregulated experienced a deterioration in servicc.
The taxi refusal and "no show" rates increased, panicularly in low income
areasp2 although there were many shon haul refusals at cabstands as
well (probably by drivers who had sat in the queue too long and needed a
long trip and a decent fare to compensate them for their inactivity}.'"
216. TI:...u... supra note :12. at 32; Teal & Berg.lund. supra note 4, at 42.
21i. D~alh On Iht Job. Tm: ECO"lOMIST Dec. 3. 19Y4. at 39.
218. Teal &: Berglund, supra nOle 4, at 5.1.
219. Gallick &: Sisko supra note 9. at 120.
220 "Exclusive ride taxi servIce remains [he only service offered in the dere~ulated cities."
Teal & Berg.lund. supra note 4. at 46. Su Tt.^L ET ^L.. supra note 160. at 13: Rosenbloom.
supra note 13.
221. ROBERT Rt;SSCLL. Rr:C~:-01 TAX1CAH DC\'~LOP."'1CSTS I'" Los ASGJ:'u:,s: t:-o PROCEJ::O
I....GS or TlIt:: CO~"F(.RE"'CE O~ TAXI::) AS PL:DLIC TRASSIT 65 rUm\'. of Californiu. 1978) (describ.
ing the illegal activlties of taxi "bandits" .....h:ch emergl:c after a major taxi compan~' fell mlO
bankruptcy). Su !:~naa!l.\.. Suzuki. supra note 2U. at 129.
::: See PARATRA",sn SERVIces. I."c.. suara note 207, at 24
::3. See PRIcr: WATCRIIOl"Se. supra note 153. at 15
III
Transportation Law Journal
[Vol. 24:73
The "no show" rate at Seattle increased 35 % after deregulation; the "no
show" rate at San Diego increased from 5% in 1976 to 18% in 1979.224
The oversupply of cabs reduced the earning potential of drivers,
causing a decline in the quality of the drivers, and leading them to engage
in overcharging and discouneous behavior20' Indianapolis. among the
first cities to deregulate entry in the ta.xi industr)', experienced the follow-
ing problems:
After the first \\i.nter the independent operators found they had no money to
maintain or repair their vchicles. Insurance cancellation notices received hy
the City. . . increased from "one or two" per month [Q "about Doe hundred
liil)''' per month. Complaints to the City about cab service "tripled" . . . .
Added to these difficulties was a reported rise in the amount of crime by taxi
drivers and operators. . . {tJne reponed rapes and robberies commiucd by
taxi drivers also increased.226
Reviewing the Indianapolis experience, the U.S. Urban Mass Trans-
ponation Administration concluded, "adding new owners into a highly
competitive supply-rich market is beneficial neither to the public nor to
the taxi operators. "027
Customer complaints in Fresno, California (where deregulation
lasted only eighteen months), tripled, and they ranged from price gouging
to the poor 'upkeep of the vehicles.22. In San Diego, many drivers re-
fused shon trips, and drivers at the end of the queue sometimes sought to
serye passengers at the head of the line - often generating physical alter-
cations'"OY In Phoenix and San Diego, the visitor and convention bureaus
pushed for re-regulation'"'o The Washington state legislator who led the
successful fight for taxi re-rcgulation said. "taxicab riders have been get-
ting 'raped' by poor ser.;ce and expensive fares ever since Seattle area
taxicabs were deregulated. . . . "031 Another source summarized the Seat-
tle community's response to the problems created by taxicab
deregulation:
:!24. TeAL &. Bl:RGLl'SD. supra note 151. at 10.
225. ML:LTIPLIC^TIO.....S. he.. :Jupra note Ibl. at 40.
226. U.S. DOT URUM.. ~I^ss TR^~SI'. ADMl....... TilE INDI..../'.;APOLIS EXP[;'Rll!SCc WITII OPE~
E~'RY l:"i TIlE T^XI ISDUSTRY 9-10 (19&.1). Drug and prostitution rings were also operated by
the unregulated ta:os. [d.
Taxi drivers also ohen are ,,'ictims of crime. Statistically. taxi drivers and chauffeurs suffer
the highest homicide rate of any profeSSion. even higher than polieemen. Death On th~ Job.
supra note 217. at 39
227. Id. at 15.
22S. Sa PARATRASS1T Sr:RVICI3S. INC. supra note 159. at 10
:29 Rosenbloom. supra note 13.
230. S~~ Shane. supra no:e 207. at 46: P,'\KATRASStT SERVIC7CS. I....e.. supra nOle 159. at 23
23i. Doug Uncel"\l.ooc.. Ta.ri R~~ufarlOn /s Back tn Lap.f of Loco! Govunmnm. SC,'\T.u:
TI....IES. Feb 26. 191'>-1. a: 52
.
.
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 113
The troubles in the cab lines-large increases in fares. substantial varia.
tion in fares among taxis. much longer taxi lines. refusals by dri\'ers to carry
passengers short distances. and minor \iolence--<:onvioced area officials. ho.
tels. and the tourist industry that this market was Dot suited to full-scale
decontro1.232
After deregulation, both Washington, D.C., and Atlanta, Georgia,
experienced increasing problems with drivers who had a language prob-
lem and poor knowledge of city streets, were overcharging customers,
and were dishonest by not taking the most direct route,233 Service quality
deterioration under deregulation also prompted calls for entry regulation
by Congressional and media leaders in Washington, D.C.'3. The Wash-
ington Post recently had this to say about taxi service in the de facIO der-
egulated District of Columbia market (one out of four D.C. cabs operates
v,;th an illegal permit. and bribes for the issuance of inspection stickers
and operating permits were under criminal investigation):
[TJhe District's cab fleet averaged 10 accidents a day last year - around
3.800 annually. That's more crashes than there afe cabs in Los Angeles.
Philadelphia. San Diego and San Antonio combined. . . .
[D }rivers routi..'1ely overcharge passengers. bribe their way throu!;h safety in-
spections, swap cars and drive v.ithout insurance. . . .
Though ours is' the nation's 19th largest city. \Vashington harbors at least
three times the number of cabs of any other city in America except New
York and Chicago. (Only one. New York. has more cabs-11.500.) Since
this massive oversupply means fewer fares per driver. many cabbies make
ends meet by cutting corners-for instance. refusing trips to out-of-the-way
places. overcharging or skimping. on repairs.235
Atlanta suffered many of the same problems under deregulation:
The taxi industry. . . has historically been criticized by city visitors for the
poor condition of its vehicle fleet. the sloppy appearance of drivers and their
negative attitudes, apparent driver lack oi knowledge of the city. and fre-
quent instances of overcharging. Officials of local commerce and trade orga-
nizations consistently complained that the industry was an embarrassment to
232, Richard Zerbe. Jr.. Seattlt Taxis: Dut.~ulaljon Hits Q Pothole. REGULATI01'\:. Nov.lDec.
1983. at 43. 47. At the Seattle Amtrak station, "There were reports of physical intimidation. of
drivers who lied about the availability of bus service. who were slovenl)'. vulgar. and rude _ and
so on." Jd. at 46. "The Sea-Tac airpon has had even worse problems in its cab lines.. .. Many
/drive:s) retused shan-haul customers.." Dnvers were less k.nowledgeable. cabs d!nier." Jd. at
46.
233. PARATR^~SIT SeRVices. he.. supra note 207, at 14.20: Ml1LTIPLlCATlO:-;S. he., supra
not~ 161. at 1l:~.19.
23":. U.S, DEP'l or TRA.'o;SP.. supra note 4. a: 13U
235. Christopher Georges. D.C's Chtcktred Cahs Hih\' Washin.i:'wn's Ta.xis Are Amtrlca's
lVors!. WASIl. POST. Ma~, 21. 1993. a: Cl. c:
114
Transportation La... Journal
[Vol. 24:73
the city and lobbied strongly for reform.236
As a result, in 1981, Atlanta reimposed entry contro]s.m
Poor profitability made it impossible for many taxi companies to in-
vest in new cabs, causing the average age of vehicles to grow238 For ex-
ample, Washington, D.C, "~th the most taxis per capita of any city in the
nation."9 also suffers from the oldest fteet.2<O Seattle's average fleet age
increased 50% during the first three years of deregulation24I Charges of
inadequate equipment maintenance, lack of cleanliness, and poor appear-
ance also have been levied.
The taxi operator is the first introduction to the city that a com'en.
tion, vacation or business traveler has, and the last impression he has
prior to depanure. Consequently, the convention and hotel industries
often lead the charge for re-regulating the taxi industry.
G. AO\llSISTRATIVE COSTS
.
.
Although one would intuitively expect government administrative
costs to fall under regulation, in fact. the U.S. Depanment of Transpona-
tion case studies reveal that such costs either did not change or in.
creased242 In several instances. consumer complaints led to enhanced
governmental sCTUtiny of the industry. and correspondingly increased ad.
ministrative 'costs. For example. under deregulation, Seattle estimated it
spent more money that it ever had in enforcing the remaining vehicle
regulations.243
VIII. SUMMARY OF THE E\rPIRICAL RESULTS OF
TAXI DEREGUL"nOS
After concluding several exhaustive studies of thc empirical results
of taxicab deregulation. Professor Roger Teal concluded:
Taxicab deregulation cannot be demonstrated to have produced. in most
cases. the benefits its proponents expected. Prices do not usually fall. im-
provements in sen;ce tire difficult to detect. and new price-senice combina-
tions have not been developed. There is little e.....idence that either
236. MULTIPLICATIONS. h.c.. supra nOte 161. at 34.
237. Rosenbloom. supra note 13.
238. PRICE W ATERHOCSE. supra note 153. at 15.
239. A 1979 telephone survey reyealed thaI Washington. D.C.. had fiYe times the number of
. taxicabs per capita as the next highest city. Atlanta. Washington had 14.7 per UXXJ residents.
while Atlanta had 2.K U.S. DCP'T Ol" TRA~SI'.. supra note 4. at 61.6:.
240. PARATRA:SSIT SCRVtCI:S. I:-;c.. supra nOte 207. at 11.
Z.t!. Rosenbloom. supra note 13.
24:::. PRICE \\."ATERIlOL"Sl:. supra note !53. at 16: PAR^TRA:SSrT SCRVICCS. he.. supra note
159. at 45.
243. Roscnbioom. supra nOle 13
1996] Taxi Industr)' Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulalion 11.5
consumers or producers are better off. Tne one important exception is new
entrants to the industry. who now have an opportunity to serve a market to
which they were prc\iously denied access. Even for them. however, deregu-
lation is a mixed blessing. Many bave been unable to survive in tbe more
competitive unregulated enviroc.ment. and those who have sunivcd are ap.
parently obtaining lo\\' earnings.244
A more recent study by Price Waterhouse of twenty-one cities which
deregulated reached similar conclusions:
[TJhe benefits of deregulation were devaluated by unanticipated and unat.
tractive side effects:
,
.
Although the supply of taxi services expanded dramatically. only marginal
service improvements were experienced by consumers. Within a year of de.
regulation. the supply of taxi services increased an average of 23%. Because
most new entrants were independent operators and small fleet O\l.11er5 with
limited capability to serve the telephone-based market. most new service
was concentrated at already well-served locations-such as airports and ma.
jor cabstands. Customer wait times at these locations. already short. were
reduced further. Response times in the telephone market were similar to
pre-deregulation performance. Trip refusals and no-shows. however. in-
creased significantly.
Prices rose in ever:')' instance. Paradoxically, the infllLX of new entrants did
DO[ invoke tbe price competition typically experienced in other newly-der-
egulated industries. Prices rose an average of 29% iD the year followi.ng
deregulation. There appear to be tv.'o sources of this unexpected event.
Hrst. fare increases prior to deregulation bad consistently lagged cost in-
creases. Veteran operators thus corrected prices at the first opportunity.
Second. new entrants generally charged higher fares than veteran operators.
The cabstand markets on which tbese operators focused their senices are
generally price insensitive and. because of the first.in first-out nature of the
taxi queues. comparison shopping is discouraged. For these reasons. the new
entrants had no incentive to introduce price competition.
Sen.'ice quality declined. Trip refusals. a decline in vehicle age and condition,
and aggressive passenger solicitation associated \\ith an over.supply of taxis
are characteristic of a worsening in service quality follo\\ing deregulation.245
Given the failure of deregulation to produce consumer pricing and
service benefits. coupled ....ith its propensity to injure carrier productivity
and profitability, most communities which have experimented with dereg-
ulation have rejected it. and re-regulated. in whole or pan. their taxi in-
dustry. Of the twenty-o!)e cities which deregulated prior to 1993, the
cxperience with deregulation was so poor that only four of th~ smallest
cities in the group (i.e.. Berkeley. California. Spokane. Washington. Ta.
2~. Teal & Berglund. supra note 4. at 54: Su a[su TE:^L & Bi:RGLUNO. supra note 151. at 30.
31.
2~5. PRICr. \\'ATJ:RIIOUSI:. supra note IS}. at II-III [emphasis in ori~ir.alJ.
116
Transportalion La... Journal
[Yol. 24:73
coma. Washington. and Sprill'gfield. Illinois) retained a fully unregulated
system.246
Cities which continued to embrace deregulation tended to have one
of the followlng characteristics: (I) a relatively smaller population; (2)
less reliant on airport acthlty; or (3) had implemented other measures
which created barriers to market entry.'47 In contrast. "[eJities wbich had
a relatively large population. a high level of airport acti\lty. and condi-
tions conducive to low-cost market entry tended to have a negative expe-
rience wlth deregulation. As a result. these cities either fully or partially
fe-regulated taxi services. . . . "2.1'-; The wave of re.regulation was led by
the largest cities \\lth the most airport activity among the group that had
d"regulated.'4.
IX. THE 1"EED FOR GOVER:":MENTAL PLANKIl"G & OVERSIGHT
.
.
Taxicabs are an essential pan of the urban transportation infrastruc-
ture. and some would argue, in the nature of a public utility."o As we
have seen. the unregulated taxi market suners from the absence of a com-
petitive market. imperfect information. significant transactions costs. ex-
ternalities. cream skimming. the loss of economies of scale and scope. and
destructive or excessive competition. collectively producing. demonstrable
deleterious economic and social consequences. While deregulation pro-
duces a significant increase in new entrants. it appears to cause declining
operational efficiency and productivity. an increase in highway conges-
tion. energy consumption and environmental pollution. a decline in driver
income. a deterioration in service. and paradoxically. an increase in pas-
senger rates. with little or no improvement in administrative costs. Any
objective assessment of the empirical evidence would conclude that the
costs of taxicab deregulation outweigh its benefits. Virtually every major
246 fd. a: 1-1II. 19
2~'7 Id. at 0
24S Id, at S
:4~ Id at 1'7
~5U One source pro....ided a comprehensive rationale for economic re~ulauorl of the taxicab
industry:
Government regulation is deemed necessary because taxicabs supply a sen-ice
which is considered publicly indispensable and because taxicab tirms often operate as
monopolies or oligopolies. Moreover. in theory. government re~ulallon of monopolies
can keep prices at a reasonable level. Early common law established that cenain busi-
nesses could harm those .....ho wanted or needed service b\' refusine. to serve them or b\'
charging exorbitant prices. therehy justifymg public regu'latlon o{ such businesses .
TaXicabs. as public utilitles. are reqUired to ser.'e ever.- customer In their ser-.ice
area at reasonable rates and Without unJust dlscnm:natlon. Publtc utilLt1c~'.are also pro.
hiblted from entenng a new market. surpl~in!; a new ser.'lce. orabandomng <1:'1 eXisting
market ....ithout the consent of a public authon!~ The "puhllc mteresthls the determl;J-
mg f::c:or i~ t':'10St govemmentai riecisiOns lr:\'olvtn!; public u!llitlcS
BARKeR & BEARe:>. supra nOle 8. a: 3]
1996] Taxi Industry Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 117
city which has tasted economic deregulation of the taxi industry has lived
to regret it, and reversed course.
The fundamental question is not whether taxis should be regulated,
but how they might best be regulated. That requires careful oversight by
the regulatory body to assure the appropriate ratio of taxis to passellgers
to ellsure prompt, safe, and reasonably priced service for the public. whi/e
allowing efficient and well managed firms to earn a reasonable return on
investment.251 Too few taxicabs results in excessive waiting times (and
opporttmity costs) for passengers. Too many taxicabs results in lower
productivity and lower profitability for service providers, despite higher
fares for consumers.
If there is a legitimate criticism to be levied at regulators. it is that
they too often skirt this difficult task. As one commentator said of the
New York medallion system:
,
.
The main deficiency of the New ):'ork system of price/entry regulation was
the total lack of any planning. Neither the fares nor the number of medal.
lions issued was determined on the basis of what was needed to achieve eco-
nomic efficiency in city transport. . . . The shortcomings of the l'ew York
City system of price/entry regulation IS a result of poor administration. and
not of any inherent deficiencies of a system of regulation.25:!
Generally speaking. taxi demand is a function of two major variables
- the overall economic activity in the market (including population, em-
ployment and income), and the relative price and quality of service of
taxis ,is-a-vis alternatives modes of transport (automobiles and public
transportation). The appropriate level of taxis per thousand citizens
should bc determined in light of the unique transportation needs of each
city. ascertained on the basis of the density of its population.2S3 street
congestion. air pollution. and perhaps such factors as the price and availa-
bility of dov>'Iltmm parking.". the number of automobiles per capita. the
251. Sa generally. DBIPSCY. s:Jpra note 2. at 220.~7"
252. Shreiber. supra note 90. at 278.79.
253. The following: chan pro\'ldes data on population densities in selected cities'
POPL'L^TIO"'- PCR SOL ARE f'.1ILE 1...- SCLECTeD CITICS
City
Chicae:o
Denver
Los Aneeles
Philadefphia
Phoenix
San Francisco
San Dieeo
Seattle.
Amencan Almanac ( 1993.9-1 )
25-1. The following chan pro\"ldes dat<l. on the number of parking spaces per t:mp!o~'ees for
selected cities'
Population/Square Mile
12.251
3.051
7.426
Il.73..!
:.3~2
Land Area (Sq.
227.2
IS3.3
469.3
135.1
411J.9
4~.7
)j4.0
83.9
Miles)
15.502
3.":28
0.!5.!
118
Transportation La... Journal
[Yolo 24:73
number of hotel rooms. the distance of the airpon from downtO\\11,255 the
volume of passenger traffic derived therefrom. and the economic health
of existing taxi firms.256
For example, in the mid-1970s, taxis carried a million passengers a
day (one fifth as many passengers as the subways) in a huge urban city
like 1\ew York, with its rush hour grid lock.257 Cities like 1\ew York,
Boston, Philadelphia, Detroit or Chicago are densely concentrated urban
centers where streets are congested and private automobile parking is ex-
pensive. Many residents do not 0\\11 an automobile, nor need they, given
the weU developed public urban transit systems. Taxi service consump-
tion would likely be at a mueh higher level in an Eastern city (built for
the horse and carriage) than in a Western city (built for the automobile),
like Denver. Salt Lake City. or DaUas. with their suburban sprawl, rela-
tively uncongested streets, and relatively plentiful and inexpensive
RATIO Of PARKING SPAcESlEMPLOYEt:.S rN SELECI"1:.0 CITIES
Parking Spaces Emplovees Ratio of Spaces/Employees
36.000 50.000 IliA
77.034 117.000 1/1.5
33.200 102.000 113.1
62.500 140.000 1/22
22.669 24.000 1/1.0
43.914 94.000 112.1
27.500 58.000 112.1
48.557 156.000 113.2
.
.
City
Charlotte
Dallas
Denver
Minneapolis
Phoenix
Portland
Salt Lake City
Seattle
Denver Dowmo\\'T\ Partnership, Inc.
255. The following. are the approximate dri...ing distance of the airPon from dO";''T\town in
selected cities:
AIRPORT D1ST^:-'<CC FROM DO\l,~'Towr-; I~ SEU:.crt.D CITICS
(in miles)
City Served
Washington. D.C
Denver
Haustor.
Dallas
Kansas City
New York
Distance to Downto\1r'T\
~
Dulles
Denver Interna:ional
Houston Interconcinent3l
DFW Inte:national
h.C. International
John F. Kennedy
26.5
2"
'"
I,
I,
15
256. In assessing the economic health of existing finns. the following data provide some indi-
cation of national industry average performance:
Ss.u::cn:o N^TIONAL T AXICAD PCRfOKM^_o,,;cr DAI^ (1993)
Average Annual Miles Per Taxi 51224
Average Paid Miles Per Trip 6.3 .
Average Annual Trips Per Taxi 8.359
Average Annu31 Passengers Per Taxi 13.883
Average Cost Per Mile SO.943
Industr;.. Sources.
257. Shreiber. supra note 90. at 278_
.
.
1996J Taxi Industr)' Regulation, Deregulation & Reregulation 119
parking258
New entry should be modest. measured and monitored. In deciding
which among several applicants should be allowed to operate in the mar-
ket, a prudent regulatory authority might choose the applicant which, for
example, has a sound financial base and a seasoned and experienced
managerial team. a minimum fleet size with centroJized radio dispatch to
serve the entire conununity adequately,259 trained and experienced driv-
ers, adequate insurance, and a young. safe and environmentally sound
fleet of cabs. On the last point, there is significant concern as to whether
a number of cities will bc able to comply v.ith Federal Clean Air Stan-
dards. If not, they stand t" lose hundreds of millions of dollars in Federal
grants.
The regulatory authority might also phase-in additional taxicabs over
a period of years. regularly monitoring their impact upon the public in
terms of price, safety and service (including customer complaints, service
response times, and such), and upon the health of the industry. If the
regulatory authority found that the problems of destructive competition.
described above. were emerging. it might well reduce the number of taxi-
cabs to be licensed during the prescribed fonhcoming period. Thus. the
regulatory authority must be careful to expand entry on a phased-in basis
only very gradually. and monitor the results closely.
In the final analysis, the suitability of taxicab service and pricing is a
258. The fOllo....ing chart pro\ides data O~ the cistrib~llon of veh:des-to.population of a sam.
ple of i41 cities:
DISTRlBt..'TIO:" or Tift:: Ci\BS-TO-POPL:L,\TIO~ RATTO. IY70
Proponion of
Sample Junsdictions ~o
Cah licenses per thousand population
Under 0.2
0.2 to under 0.4
0.4 to under 0.6
0.6 to under 0.8
o.~ (0 under 1.0
1.0 !O under 1.2
1.2 to under 2,0
2.U and over
1\1edian licenses per thousand = 0.57
III
2U
23
16
10
S
4
;
J.D. WELLS & F.f. SELOVE::R. CltAKACTERJSnCS or TilE UR!:lA:-' TAXICAII TKN'.srT INDUSTRY
(1972)
259. The city officials of Indianapolis. which expenmemed y,ith open entry in the early
I 970s. concluded that "they should have reqUired a mlmmum of ten ...chicles per O\lo.'T1er and
radios in each cab'" U.S. DOT LiRll/\~ f\.lAss TR^!"oISf'. ADMl..... supra note 126. at Q.IU An.
olher source concluded. "alllax.icabs should be required to be affillal~d wnh a fteetJar!!C' enough
to ser....e all parts of the Cil~' 24 hours a day (e.g...25 vehiciesl and thaI every taxicao he required
to have a two-way radiO and meter Gene Slailar.::.. supra note i. at ] 1. Address bdore the 50th
Annual Convemion of th~ ~ew Zealand Taxi Propnetors' Federauon Wt:llmglOn. f\;e...... Zealand.
Aug. 3U. 1988
uo
Transportation La... Journal
[Vel. 24:73
peculiarly lecal issue, best tailored by local governments based on the,r
unique populations, spatial densities, road congestion, air pollution, and
ai'1'on and hotel traffic. For that reason, whatever the national ideologi-
cal infatuation \\ith comprehensive infrastructure deregulation, Congress
should instead embrace an alternative national political movement-one
which champions devolution, or reversing the 20th Century megatrend of
power fio\\ing from the states to Washington-in favor of lo;:al con-
tro1.260 In this area, the state and local governments should be left alone
to foster the unique local public and private transportation system that
suits them best.
260. ~1jchael Barone. Power 10 ,}u Sla[~s. U.S. lSI!wS & \VORLO Rr:.r.. JJn. 23. 1995. at 40.
'.